Skip to main content
Log in

Aggregate idiosyncratic volatility, dynamic aspects of loss aversion, and narrow framing

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We test the dynamic aspects of the loss aversion feature of Kahneman and Tversky (Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47:263–291, 1979) and find that idiosyncratic volatility is negatively associated with unrealized gains of stock returns. Moreover, we show that this negative relationship is stronger for stocks with high individual investors’ holdings. Finally, we show that controlling for firm age as defined by Fink et al. (What drove the increase in idiosyncratic volatility during the internet boom? J Financ Quant Anal 45:1253–1278, 2010) eliminates the significance of retail trading proportions as a driver of idiosyncratic volatility. These findings are robust to price, sentiment, and IPO dates. Bivariate vector auto-regression confirms the causality of unrealized gains of stock returns on idiosyncratic volatility.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Examples of such studies include Malkiel and Xu (2003), Bennett and Sias (2006), Brown and Kapadia (2007), Wei and Zhang (2006), Ang et al. (2006), Bali and Cakici (2008), Fu (2009), Bekaert et al. (2010), Brandt et al. (2010), Fink et al. (2010), Bali et al. (2011), Peterson and Smedema (2011) and Berrada and Hugonnier (2013).

  2. Please see page 1249 in Barberis and Huang (2001) for more elaborate explanation.

  3. According to Barberis and Huang (2001), investors in the economy of individual stock accounting (portfolio accounting) get utility from the gains and losses in the value of individual stocks (overall portfolio of stocks) they own.

  4. This data can be found at the following address: http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/.

  5. Institutional Ownership is the sum of the shares held by all institutions at the end of every quarter divided by the total outstanding shares in Thomson Financial 13-F filing data.

  6. The authors show that Max defined as the average of the five highest returns of the month exhibits better properties consistent with lottery preferences.

  7. This data can be found at the following address: http://bear.warrington.ufl.edu/ritter/ipodata.htm.

  8. In Grinblatt and Han (2005) model, the reference price for a stock is obtained as the turnover weighted average of past stock price and past reference price. That is, \( RP_{i,t} = V_{i,t - 1} P_{i,t - 1} + (1 - V_{i,t - 1} )RP_{i,t - 1} \). The recursive substitution of past reference prices on the right hand side of the above equation leads to Eq. (3) with the exception that the summation is over infinite periods. For empirical implementation, we sum over the number of trading days in recent 3 years. Grinblatt and Han (2005), however, find robust results using 3, 5, or 7 years of data.

  9. Barberis and Huang (2001) considers two economies to study equilibrium firm-level stock returns. The first economy is one in which investors get direct utility not only from consumption but also from gains and losses in the value of their overall portfolio of stocks. The second economy is one in which investors which investors get direct utility not only from consumption but also from gains and losses in the value of individual stocks they own. They find that individual stock accounting can explain high mean and excess volatility.

  10. Computed as the product of daily idiosyncratic volatility and the square root of the number of trading days in the month.

  11. The investor sentiment (Sent) data is from Baker and Wurgler (2006) and downloaded from Wurgler’s website.

  12. We only report results based on equal-weighted idiosyncratic volatility from here on as they prove to be similar to those based on value-weighted idiosyncratic volatility.

  13. Fink et al. (2010) also suggest that this bias is particularly severe with the inclusion of Nasdaq firms in the CRSP database in the early 1970 s, several of which are included in Brandt et al. (2010) sample.

  14. We deeply appreciate the insightful comment from the anonymous referee on this.

  15. See Brandt et al. (2010).

  16. For brevity, we only report results pertaining to the lowest and highest portfolios.

References

  • Ang A, Hodrick R, Xing Y, Zhang X (2006) The cross-section of volatility and expected returns. J Financ 61:259–299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker M, Wurgler J (2006) Investor sentiment and the cross-section of stock returns. J Financ 61:1645–1680

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bali TG, Cakici N (2008) Idiosyncratic risk and the cross section of expected returns. J Financ Quant Anal 43:29–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bali TG, Cakici N, Whitelaw RF (2011) Maxing out: stocks as lotteries and the cross-section of expected returns. J Financ Econ 99:427–446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bali TG, Brown S, Murray S, Tang Y (2015) Betting against beta or demand for lottery? Working paper

  • Barberis N, Huang M (2001) Mental accounting, loss aversion, and individual stock returns. J Financ 57(4):1247–1292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barberis N, Huang M (2008) Stocks as lotteries: the implications of probability weighting for security prices. Am Econ Rev 98:2066–2100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bekaert G, Hodrick RJ, Zhang X (2010) Aggregate idiosyncratic volatility. Working paper 16058, NBER

  • Bennett JA, Sias RW (2006) Why company-specific risk changes over time. Financ Anal J 62(5):89–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bennett JA, Sias RW, Starks LT (2003) Greener pastures and the impact of dynamic institutional preferences. Rev Financ Stud 16:1203–1238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berrada T, Hugonnier J (2013) Incomplete information idiosyncratic volatility and stock returns. J Bank Financ 37:448–462

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhootra A, Hur J (2014) High idiosyncratic volatility and low returns: a prospect theory based explanation. Forthcoming in financial management

  • Boyer B, Mitton T, Vorkink K (2010) Expected idiosyncratic skewness. Rev Financ Stud 23:169–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandt MA, Brav J Graham, Kumar A (2010) The idiosyncratic volatility puzzle: time trend or speculative episodes? Rev Financ Stud 23:863–899

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown G, Kapadia N (2007) Firm-specific risk and equity market development. J Financ Econ 84:358–388

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell JY, Lettau M, Malkiel BG, Xu Y (2001) Have individual stocks become more volatile? An empirical exploration of idiosyncratic risk. J Financ 56:1–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French KR (1993) Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. J Financ Econ 33:3–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French KR (1996) Multifactor explanations of asset pricing anomalies. J Financ 51:55–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, MacBeth J (1973) Risk, return and equilibrium: empirical tests. J Polit Econ 81:607–636

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fink J, Fink KW, Grullon G, Weston JP (2010) What drove the increase in idiosyncratic volatility during the internet boom? J Financ Quant Anal 45:1253–1278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frazzini A (2006) The disposition effect and underreaction to news. J Financ 61:2017–2046

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fu F (2009) Idiosyncratic Risk and the Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns. J Financ Econ 91:24–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grinblatt M, Han B (2005) Prospect theory, mental accounting, and momentum. J Financ Econ 78:311–339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harvey CR, Siddique A (2000) Conditional skewness in asset pricing tests. J Financ 55:1263–1295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hur J, Pritamani M, Singh V (2010) Momentum and disposition effect: the role of individual investors. Financ Manage 39(2010):1155–1176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovich B, Rousseau P (2001) Why wait? A century of life before IPO. Am Econ Rev 91:336–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47:263–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar A (2009) Who gambles in the stock market? J Financ 64:1889–1933

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malkiel B, Xu Y (2003) Investigating the behavior of idiosyncratic volatility. J Bus 76:613–644

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1974) On the pricing of corporate debt: the risk structure of interest rates. J Financ 29:449–470

    Google Scholar 

  • Newey W, West K (1987) A simple positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica 55:703–708

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pastor L, Veronesi P (2003) Stock valuation and learning about profitability. J Financ 58:1749–1789

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peterson D, Smedema AR (2011) The return impact of realized and expected idiosyncratic volatility. J Bank Financ 35:2547–2558

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei SX, Zhang C (2006) Why did individual stocks become more volatile? J Bus 79:259–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xu Y, Malkiel BG (2003) Investigating the behavior of idiosyncratic volatility. J Bus 76:613–644

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jungshik Hur.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hur, J., Luma, C.M. Aggregate idiosyncratic volatility, dynamic aspects of loss aversion, and narrow framing. Rev Quant Finan Acc 49, 407–433 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-016-0595-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-016-0595-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation