Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

How Much Do Cartel Overcharge?

  • Published:
Review of Industrial Organization Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Connor and Lande (Issues in competition law and policy, pp 2203–2218, 2008) conducted a survey of cartels and found a mean overcharge estimate in the range of 31–49 %. By examining more sources, Connor (Price-fixing overcharges, 2nd edn. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1610262, 2010) finds a mean of 50.4 % for successful cartels. However, the data that are used in those studies are estimates that are obtained from different methodologies, sources, and contexts rather than from direct observation. We conduct a meta-analysis of cartel overcharge estimates that provides a sound treatment of these matters and other data problems. We find a bias-corrected mean and median overcharge estimate of 15.47 and 16.01 %. Our results have significant antitrust policy implications.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The database actually describes cartel episodes. Each episode is treated as a different observation. There is no formal proof or admission of guilt for approximately one-third of the observations. Hence, the data include convicted cartels as well as alleged ones. We sincerely thank Professor John Connor for generously making his database available to us.

  2. Source: "The EU competition Rules on Cartels," document published by the law firm Slaughter and May in 2012. Publically available on the website of the company.

  3. Boyer (2013) discusses this recent literature.

  4. The methodology that was used in Boyer and Kotchoni (2011, 2012) predicts a bias-corrected OE of 13.62 % for cartels with raw OEs that lie in the range (0–50 %).

  5. Connor (2014) finds a long-run median overcharge of 23.0 % and a mean of at least 49.0 % for all cartels of all times. The skewness problem is pointed out by Connor and Lande (2008) and Connor (2010). It should be emphasized that Connor has been conservative in recording some of the OE, notably by tagging and excluding peak estimates from the sample (see Connor 2010, pp. 48 and following).

  6. Ehmer and Rosati (2009) point out that many of the estimates that are in Connor’s sample are obtained from “a simple calculation of the difference between prices charged during the operation of the cartel and in other periods or other markets that are believed to be competitive. By completely neglecting all other factors that can cause prices to change, the authors of these estimates simplistically attribute the entire price variation to the effects of the cartel”.

  7. In addition to Y1 through Y5, the vector Y contains the interactions of the US geographical market with the periods P1, P2, and P3.

  8. An overcharge calculation approach that is based on the Lerner index can fall within the family of econometric methods or cost-based methods, depending on how this index is estimated.

  9. Table 2 of the appendix to Connor (2010) provides a “Summary of Price-Fixing Damages, Social-Science Studies”. The table presents 280 cartels, their OEs, and a description of the estimation method. Of the 280 OEs, 51 have been obtained by conversion of a Lerner index. Connor (2014) reports Lerner indices as OEs without conversion, thereby subject to upward biases.

  10. For instance, see White (2001) for a critique of the before-and-after methods that were employed by Connor (1997) in the ADM-lysine case.

  11. We choose not to go beyond θ = 70 % as our previous analysis concluded that the overall data quality is low for the range OE > 65 %.

  12. That is, unconditionally on the truncation \( {\hat{\uptheta }}_{\text{i}} \in \left( {0,\uptheta} \right] \). As zero overcharges are excluded from the sample, the results are still conditional on \( {\hat{\uptheta }}_{\text{i}} > 0 \).

  13. Note that a cartel can fail at raising its price while being effective along other competitive dimensions (e.g., entry, capacity, innovation, advertizing, credit terms, etc.). The database that is available to us does not permit us to address such issues.

  14. The link between the overcharge and the optimal fine is also studied by Nieberding (2006), Houba et al. (2014), Ginsburg and Wright (2010) and Harrington (2010, 2014).

References

  • Adler, H., & Laing, D. J. (1997). Explosion of international criminal antitrust enforcement. The Corporate Counsellor, 11, 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adler, H., & Laing, D. J. (1999). As corporate fines skyrocket. Business Crimes Bulletin, 6, 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allain, M.-L., Boyer, M., Kotchoni, R., & Ponssard, J.-P. (2015). Are cartel fines optimal? Theory and evidence from the European Union. International Review of Law and Economics, 42, 38–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allain, M.-L., Boyer, M., & Ponssard, J.-P. (2011). The determination of optimal fines in cartel cases: Theory and practice. ConcurrencesCompetition Law Journal 4-2011, 32–40 (Best Academic Economics Article2012 Antitrust Writing Awards, Institute of Competition Law, New York, and George Washington University Law School, Washington).

  • Becker, G. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 76, 169–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyer, M. (2013). The fining of cartels. ConcurrencesCompetition Law Journal 1-2013, 27–33.

  • Boyer, M., & Kotchoni, R. (2011). The econometrics of cartel overcharge. CIRANO WP 2011s-35.

  • Boyer, M., & Kotchoni, R. (2012). How Much Do Cartel Typically Overcharge? CIRANO WP 2012s-15.

  • Cohen, M. A., & Scheffman, D. T. (1989). The antitrust sentencing guideline: Is the punishment worth the costs? American Criminal Law Review, 27, 331–366.

    Google Scholar 

  • Combe, E., & Monnier, C. (2011). Fines against hard core cartels in Europe: The myth of over-enforcement. Antitrust Bulletin, 56, 235–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Combe, E., & Monnier, C. (2013). Quelle est l’ampleur de la sous-dissuasion des cartels en Europe ? Compléments sur nos résultats. ConcurrencesCompetition Law Journal 1-2013, 16–26.

  • Connor, J. M. (1997). The global lysine price-fixing conspiracy of 1992–1995. Review of Agricultural Economics, 19(2), 412–427.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connor, J. M. (2010). Price-fixing overcharges (2nd ed.) http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1610262

  • Connor, J. M. (2014). Price-fixing overcharges. The Law and Economics of Class Actions: Research in Law and Economics, 26, 249–387.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connor, J. M., & Bolotova, Y. (2006). A meta-analysis of cartel overcharges. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24, 1109–1137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connor, J. M., & Lande, R. H. (2008). Cartel overcharges and optimal cartel fines. In S.W. Waller (Ed.), Issues in competition law and policy, Volume 3, AMA Section of Antitrust Law, chapter 88 (pp. 2203–2218).

  • Denger, M. L. (2003). Too Much or Too Little, a summary of discussion. American Bar Association’s Antitrust Remedies Forum, Washington, DC. April.

  • Ehmer, C., & Rosati, F. (2009). Science, myth, and fines: Do cartels typically raise prices by 25%? ConcurrencesCompetition Law Journal No. 4-2009.

  • Ginsburg, D. H., & Wright, J. D. (2010). Antitrust sanctions. Competition Policy International, 6(2), 3–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R. E. (1988). The relation between price and marginal cost in US industry. Journal of Political Economy, 96, 921–947.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrington, J. E. (2010). Comment on ‘Antitrust Sanctions’ by Douglas Ginsburg and Joshua Wright. Competition Policy International, 6(2), 41–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrington, J. E. (2014). Penalties and the deterrence of unlawful collusion. Economic Letters, 124(2014), 33–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica, 47, 153–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houba, H., Motchenkova, E., & Wen, Q. (2014). The role of legal principles in the economic analysis of competition policy. In M. Peitz & Y. Spiegel (Eds.), Analysis of competition policy and sectoral regulation (pp. 389–422). Boston-Delft: Now.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hunter, J., & Schmidt, F. (2004). Methods of meta-analysis: Correcting error and bias in research findings (2nd ed.). Sage: Thousand Oaks.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katsoulacos, Y., & Ulph, D. (2013). Antitrust penalties and the implications of empirical evidence on cartel overcharges. The Economic Journal, 123(572), F558–F581.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kearney, E. (2009). The Competition Bureau ‘20 percent solution’: Does the punishment fit the crime? The Marker, CBA National Competition Law Section, March.

  • Kovacic, W. E., & Shapiro, C. (2000). Antitrust policy: A century of economic and legal thinking. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(1), 43–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kullback, S., & Leibler, R. A. (1951). On information and sufficiency. The Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 22(1), 1–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landes, W. H. (1983). Optimal sanctions for antitrust violations. University of Chicago Law Review, 50, 652–678.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levenstein, M. C., & Suslow, V. Y. (2003). Contemporary international cartels and developing countries: Economic effects and implications for competition policy. Antitrust Law Journal, 71, 801–852.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morrison, C. J. (1990). Market power, economic profitability, and productivity growth measurement: An integrated structural approach, NBER Working Paper No. 3355.

  • Nieberding, J. F. (2006). Estimating overcharges in antitrust cases using a reduced-form approach: Methods and issues. Journal of Applied Economics, IX(2), 361–380.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, J. L. (2001). Lysine and price fixing: How long? How severe? Review of Industrial Organization, 18, 23–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are very grateful to the Editor (Lawrence White) for his patience as well as for his generous and challenging comments and suggestions. We also benefited from remarks by Jimmy Royer and René Garcia and by two anonymous referees. We remain solely responsible for its content.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rachidi Kotchoni.

Additional information

Preliminary versions of this paper circulated as working papers under the titles “The Econometrics of Cartel Overcharge” and “How Much Do Cartels Typically Overcharge?”

Appendix: Summary Statistics of the Database

Appendix: Summary Statistics of the Database

See Tables 13 and 14.

Table 13 Cartels with raw OE in the interval (0, 49 %]
Table 14 Cartels with raw OEs = 0 % and OEs > 49 %

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Boyer, M., Kotchoni, R. How Much Do Cartel Overcharge?. Rev Ind Organ 47, 119–153 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-015-9472-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-015-9472-1

Keywords

Navigation