Skip to main content
Log in

The effects of the Chilean divorce law on women’s first birth decisions

  • Published:
Review of Economics of the Household Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In 2004 a new law in Chile allowed couples to divorce for the first time. The law also established compensation in case of divorce where one spouse sacrifices professional development or advancement for the good of the household. Using birth histories constructed from the Chilean Social Security Survey (Encuesta de Prevision Social–EPS) Panel 2002–2009, we investigate the effect of the divorce law on a woman’s decision of when to have a first child. We find that the divorce law increases the hazard rate of having the first child by 61 % for more educated women, controlling for socioeconomic characteristics, length of marriage and the negative trend in fertility rates observed in Chile since the mid-1960s. We also find that a given percentage increase in a woman’s potential income will increase the hazard rate by a greater percentage increase after the passage of the law.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The amount of compensation is determined by a court, which takes into account the beneficiary’s age, level of education, length of marriage, and number of children, as well as other socio-demographic characteristics.

  2. Chilean Library of Congress. http://www.bcn.cl/carpeta_temas/temas_portada.2005-10-27.7388460505.

  3. Separation provided a woman with a food pension, but there is evidence that these pensions are frequently not paid: administrative data shows that 80 % of petitions to the courts concerning children’s issues are related to nonpayment of a food pension. See Senate of Chile, Records of Session 12 (15 July 2003).

  4. We would like to thank an anonymous referee for this argument.

  5. These figures are provided by the National Institute of Statistics of Chile (INE). The INE produces the Vital Statistics Report (Reporte de Estadísticas Vitales) annually, using administrative information on births, marriages and other variables collected from birth registry offices. In Fig. 1 the number of marriages for the years 2001, 2002 and 2004 is estimated using the annualized growth rate of first marriages for the periods 2000–2003 and 2003–2005, respectively. The number of first births for the years 2001 and 2002 is also estimated using the annualized growth rate of the number of first births for the period 2000–2003.

  6. The administrative data do not distinguish the average ages at first marriage of women who have children and women who do not.

  7. In general, between 1998 and 2009, the 15 countries of the Eurozone decreased by 0.8 %. http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat.

  8. In 2013, a benefit scheme was introduced to provide financial support to couples with more than two children.

  9. In 2005, new domestic violence legislation was introduced. However, there is no clear evidence of the effect of domestic violence on fertility decisions. Moreover, to our understanding, there are no exclusive social programs targeting single mothers.

  10. Peters (1986, 1992), Allen (1992), Zelder (1993), Weiss and Willis (1997), Friedberg (1998) and Wolfers (2006) analyze the effects of divorce laws on divorce rates. Regarding the relationship between divorce laws and women's labor supply, the literature focuses on the response of women's labor supply after divorce: Johnson and Skinner (1986), Gray (1998) and Stevenson (2007). Regarding human capital accumulation, King (1982) and Stevenson (2007) analyze the effect of divorce laws on couples’ investments in the education of spouses and children, as well as household specialization.

  11. Gruber (2004) provides a summary of when these laws were implemented in each state.

  12. CIA World Factbook. https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/ci.html.

  13. To our knowledge, the only study that examines the Chilean DL is Heggeness (2009), which analyzes the law’s effect on educational enrollment using a difference-in-difference approach.

  14. To see this, we compute the difference between the share of first births for more educated women (those with more than 12 years of education) and the share for women with 10–12 years of education for each year after the DL was passed in 2004. We compare these differences with the corresponding difference for the year 2003, which is one year before the DL was passed. The formula is \(DD_{13}^{y} = \left( {f_{13}^{y} - f_{10\,to\,12}^{y} } \right) - \left( {f_{13}^{03} - f_{10\,to\,12}^{03} } \right)\) for y from 2005 to 2008. The difference-in-differences increases from 0.77 % in 2005 to 3.06 % in 2008 (see Fig. 2). The result is unchanged if women 19 or younger are excluded from the analysis.

  15. The original sample was collected in 2002. The 2004 wave added around 3000 new individuals to the sample, while the 2006 and 2009 waves update the individuals' information.

  16. The results are conditional on not having conceived before the age of 18. In the administrative data, the percentage of women conceiving their first child at age 18 or before is very small. The calculations presented in the text are based on administrative data. According to the Ministry of Health of Chile (2013) the percentage of conceptions for women under the age of 19 has remained relatively flat from 2004 to 2011 at 15.5 % (there are no figures for first conceptions alone). In the administrative data there were substantially fewer first conceptions for this age group, and their exclusion did not significantly affect the difference-in-difference analysis, and the average age at first birth in Fig. 2.

  17. Less than 3 % of women in the sample are married or cohabitating before reaching 18 years of age. In such cases, we assume that their relationship started at age 18. Before 2009 the survey does not collect information on the timing of the current marriage or cohabitation. Therefore the exact duration of a marriage or cohabitating relationship may be mismeasured when more than one occurs. Less than 18 % of the women in the sample report having terminated a first marriage or cohabitating relationship, and only 11.5 % of non-single women report more than one marital or cohabitating relationship.

  18. The variables in W are the level of education level of the woman’s father and mother, an indicator variable for whether the woman married before 2004, and a set of indicator variables to control for the region of residence of the woman when first interviewed.

  19. The actual final level of education is not available in the EPS.

  20. Specifically we assume the following: (a) women who last report primary or secondary education will complete that education level; and (b) women who last report enrollment in the final year of secondary education or who report attending post-secondary education in every wave of the EPS will complete the corresponding track of post-secondary studies.

  21. We would like to thank an anonymous referee for suggesting these robustness checks.

  22. To test for anticipation effects, we substitute the time-varying covariate that goes from 0 to 1 to indicate the implementation of the DL in November 2004, for a duration spline. This duration spline enters the hazard in 1999, when the DL was presented to the congress. We also include nodes in May and November of 2004 for the approval and implementation of the DL. The results (not shown in the paper) suggest that the DL has no anticipation effect on the hazard of having a first child. Indeed, this result is not surprising, given that the DL is the last of multiple attempts to introduce divorce in Chile. Moreover, none of the results in this study change substantively when the indicators for region of residence are replaced with the woman’s region of birth.

  23. Ermisch and Pronzato (2010) show that an additional year of parent’s education increases their children’s education by at least one tenth of a year.

  24. We have also included a piece-wise linear time trends with knots at every 10 years after the start of the sample. The knot at 1990 is critical since it represents the start of the post Pinochet period. The knot at 2000 coincides with a presidential election. Moving the knot from the year 2000 to non-election years increase the variability of the estimate associated with the DL, and hurts our significance levels in the regression where the highest education level is some university experience, but not in the case where the highest education level is university degree.

  25. See Heckman (1979).

  26. The standard errors for the estimates of the interaction of the DL variable with the woman’s potential income have not been adjusted to take into account the fact that the woman’s potential income is a generated regressor.

  27. Column (3) of Table 6 shows the full set of results for Eq. (3).

  28. As an alternative specification, we include in Eq. (3) the interaction of DL with the woman's expected education (E·DL(t)). The estimates from this specification corroborate the negative effect of the woman’s potential income on the hazard of having a first child.

  29. Our regressions do not control for general economic conditions. A sustained economic growth in Chile starting in 1982 has resulted in low levels of unemployment and improvement in women’s educational attainment, which we do control for. Therefore it is unlikely that fertility decisions are negatively affected by deteriorating economic conditions.

  30. We use a Mincerian equation to estimate the partner’s expected income. Using the EPS 2004 male sample, we regress the natural logarithm of hourly income in 2004 on education, labor force experience, and its square. The equation is used to predict log hourly income at age 25. The EPS provides information about the partner’s education only in the marriage histories updated after the EPS 2006 (in earlier waves this information is not collected). However, for a marriage or cohabiting relationship starting before 2004, it is still possible to recover the partner’s education from the household members’ demographic characteristics if a married woman reports only one marriage (58 % of the sample). We mean-fill by woman’s education in the case of missing values.

References

  • Alesina, A., & Giuliano, P. (2007). Divorce, fertility and the value of marriage. Harvard Institute of Economic Research, discussion paper no. 2136.

  • Allen, D. (1992). Marriage and divorce: Comment. The American Economic Review, 82(3), 679–685.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1974). A theory of marriage: Part II. Journal of Political Economy, 82(2), S11–S26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bellido, H., & Marcen, M. (2014). Divorce laws and fertility. Labour Economics, 27, 56–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drewianka, S. (2008). Divorce law and family formation. Journal of Population Economics, 21, 485–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ECLAC, INE. (2002). Chile: Proyección y Estimaciones de Poblacion. Total País. 1950–2050 (Chile: Population Forecast and Estimates. Total Country. 1950–2050).

  • Ekert-Jaffe, O., & Grossbard, S. (2008). Does community property discourage unpartnered births? European Journal of Political Economy, 24(1), 25–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ermisch, J., & Pronzato, C. (2010). Causal effects of parent’s education on children’s education. Institute for Social and Economic Research. ISER working papers series no. 2010-16.

  • Friedberg, L. (1998). Did unilateral divorce raise divorce rates? Evidence from panel data. The American Economic Review, 88(3), 608–627.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gray, J. (1998). Divorce-law changes, household bargaining, and married women’s labor supply. The American Economic Review, 88(3), 628–642.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gruber, J. (2004). Is making divorce easier bad for children? The long-run implications of unilateral divorce. Journal of Labor Economics, 22(4), 799–833.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica, 47(1), 153–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heggeness, M. (2009). Evidence of shifts in intra-household allocation under exogenous changes in family policy and administrative procedures: The case of school enrollment in Chile. Agricultural and Applied Economics Association, Annual Meeting, July 26–28.

  • Johnson, W. R., & Skinner, J. (1986). Labor supply and marital separation. American Economic Review, 76(3), 455–469.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, A. (1982). Human capital and the risk of divorce: An asset in search of a property right. Southern Economic Journal, 49(2), 536–541.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kravdal, Ø. (2001). The high fertility of college-educated women in Norway. Demographic Research, 5(6), 187–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larrañaga, O. (2004). Participación Laboral de la Mujer en Chile: 1958–2003 (Women’s Labor Force Participation in Chile: 1958–2003). Chile: Department of Economics, Universidad de Chile.

    Google Scholar 

  • Larrañaga, O. (2006). Comportamientos Reproductivos y Natalidad: 1960–2003 (Reproductive behavior and fertility: 1960–2003). In J. S. Valenzuela, E. Tironi, & T. Scully (Eds.), El Eslabón Perdido: Familia, modernización y bienestar en Chile. Santiago de chile, Editorial Tauros.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, L., & Choe, M. K. (1997). A mixture model for duration data: Analysis of second births in China. Demography, 34(2), 189–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lillard, L., & C. Panis (2003) aML multilevel multiprocess statistical software, version 2.0. Los Angeles, CA: EconWare.

  • Ministry of Health, Government of Chile. (2013). Situación Actual del Embarazo Adolescente en Chile (Current state of adolescent pregnancy in Chile).

  • Molina, M., et al. (2004). Embarazo en la Adolescencia y su Relación con la Deserción Escolar (Adolescent pregnancy and its relationship to schooling dropout). Revista Médica de Chile, 132, 65–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman, J., & McCulloch, C. (1984). A hazard rate approach to the timing of births. Econometrica, 52(4), 939–961.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palma, I. (2006). Transformaciones de la fecundidad en la sociedad chilena. http://www.pasa.cl/index.php?option=com_docman&task=doc_download&gid=153.

  • Peters, H. E. (1986). Marriage and divorce: Informational constraints and private contracting. The American Economic Review, 76(3), 437–454.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peters, H. E. (1992). Marriage and divorce: Reply. The American Economic Review, 82(3), 686–693.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rossetti, J. (1993). Hacia un perfil de la familia actual en Latinoamérica y el Caribe (Towards a profile of the current family in Latin America and the Caribbean). In Cambios en el perfil de las familias: la experiencia regional, Libros de la CEPAL, No. 36 (LC/G.1761-P), Santiago de Chile, Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (Comisión Económica para América Latina y el Caribe–CEPAL).

  • Salinas, V. (2008). Matrimonio y Convivencia a la Luz de la Encuesta Bicentenario (Marriage and cohabitation in the bicentennial survey). Institute of Sociology, Bicentennial Survey Seminar 2008 (Instituto de Sociología, Seminario Encuesta Bicentenario 2008).

  • Social Security Subsecretary (Subsecretaría de Previsión Social). Chile. (2002). Primera Encuesta de Protección Social (First survey of social security). www.proteccionsocial.cl.

  • Stevenson, B. (2007). The impact of divorce laws on marriage-specific capital. Journal of Labor Economics, 25(1), 75–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weiss, Y., & Willis, R. J. (1997). Match quality, new information, and marital dissolution, Part 2: Essays in Honor of Yoram Ben-Porath. Journal of Labor Economics, 15(1), S293–S329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wolfers, J. (2006). Did unilateral divorce laws raise divorce rates? A reconciliation and new results. American Economic Review, 96(5), 1802–1820.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diaz, S. (Year unknown). Información Sobre la Situación de la Planificación Familiar en Chile (Information on the Situation of Family Planning in Chile). Instituto Chileno de Salud Reproductiva. http://www.icmer.org/documentos/anticoncepcion_de_emergencia/inf_situac_planific_familiar_chile.pdf.

  • Zelder, M. (1993). Inefficient dissolutions as a consequence of public goods: The case of no-fault divorce. The Journal of Legal Studies, 22(2), 503–520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Susan Gensemer, Alfonso Flores-Lagunes, Pieter Serneels, two anonymous referees for their useful comments and the Subsecretary of Social Security of Chile for providing the data. We are also thankful to the participants at the Gender Economics session at the 2012 Meeting of the Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association. All errors are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jose V. Gallegos.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gallegos, J.V., Ondrich, J.I. The effects of the Chilean divorce law on women’s first birth decisions. Rev Econ Household 15, 857–877 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-015-9307-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-015-9307-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation