Skip to main content
Log in

Non-uniform implementation of uniform standards

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Regulatory Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Regulations are frequently based on a uniform standard, which applies to all facilities within a single industry. However, implementation of many of these regulations does not lead to uniform limits due to considerations of local conditions in real policy settings. In this paper, we theoretically examine the relationships among the stringency of effluent limits imposed on individual polluting facilities by permit writers, environmental protection agencies’ monitoring decisions, and the ambient quality of the local environment. In particular, we explore the establishment of effluent limits when (1) the national emission standard represents only an upper bound on the local issuance of limits and (2) negotiation efforts expended by regulated polluting facilities and environmentally concerned citizens play a role. We find that the negotiated discharge limit depends on the political weight enjoyed and the negotiation effort costs faced by both citizens and the regulated facility, along with the stringency of the national standard and local ambient quality conditions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Since the passage of the 1972 Federal Water Pollution Control Act, which preceded the Clean Water Act, the EPA has developed industry-specific Effluent Limitation Guidelines based on the degree of pollution reduction attainable by facilities in a given industry.

  2. This depiction indicates that permitted effluent limit levels are determined by Effluent Limitation Guidelines, which apply uniformly across all facilities within a particular industry, or ambient water quality concerns, which do not relate to an individual facility’s ability to control discharges.

  3. Upper Blackstone Water Pollution Abatement District vs EPA, 690 F.3d 9 (1st Circuit 2011).

  4. Cities of Annandale and Maple Lake NPDES/SDS Permit Issuance for the Discharge of Treated Wastewater, 731 N.W.2d 502 (Minnesota 2007).

  5. Recent theoretical studies explore the interaction between state and federal governments in the environmental regulatory realm (see, for instance, Revesz and Stavins 2007; Goulder and Stavins 2011, 2012; Banzhaf and Chupp 2012; Williams 2012).

  6. Political economy models are used by many studies to explore various environmental policy settings, such as those relating to climate protection and trade. Several of these studies explore the effects of institutional changes on the stringency of environmental regulation, with some studies considering the role of lobbying, such as Fredriksson (1997), Damania et al. (2003), Binder and Neumayer (2005), Markussen and Svendsen (2005), and Gullberg (2008). However, these papers all assume full compliance and ignore the role played by the enforcement policy.

  7. In the concluding section, we assess the implications of a convex fine structure.

  8. The choice of the objective function of the inspection agency has already been the subject of debate. Cohen (2000), Firestone (2002, 2003) and Heyes and Kapur (2009) provide extensive summaries of the different arguments and assumptions made in various studies. Overall, evidence seems to support the conclusion that national environmental inspection agencies are mainly concerned with deterrence and less concerned with the compliance cost burden placed on the regulated industry. However, at the local level, the enforcing authorities might have different priorities that emphasize the economic concerns of the local community over compliance with nationally imposed regulations.

  9. Keeler (1995) introduces this same parameter \(\psi \). If \(0<\psi <1\), abatement costs matter but enjoy a lower priority than environmental damages and monitoring costs. If \(\psi >1\), then the agency’s concerns about facilities’ abatement costs dominate the other concerns.

  10. One way to interpret citizens’ negotiation effort is to assume that citizens act as a collective environmental advocacy group. In this capacity, citizens aim to minimize the sum of expected environmental damages and the costs of their negotiation effort. Thus, citizens’ objective is captured as \({\min }_{\{\hbox {g}\}}\left[ d_{j}\left( \hbox {e}_{\mathrm{ij}} \left( \hbox {e}_{\mathrm{ij}}^{\mathrm{w}} (\hbox {g})\right) \right) +\hbox {ug}\right] \).

  11. One way to interpret the facility’s negotiation effort is to assume that the facility minimizes the sum of abatement costs, expected fines for non-compliance, and its own negotiation costs. Thus, the facility’s objective is captured as follows: \({\min }_{\{\hbox {h}\}} \left[ c_{i} \left( \hbox {e}_{\mathrm{ij}} \right) +\hbox {p}_{\mathrm{ij}} \hbox {fmax}\left\{ 0, \hbox {e}_{\mathrm{ij}} -\hbox {e}_{\mathrm{ij}}^{\mathrm{w}} (\hbox {h})\right\} +\hbox {vh}\right] \).

  12. We do not explicitly model the standard and fine setting decisions of the national regulator. However, we allow the stringency of the discharge limit to be endogenously determined by the permit writer in negotiation with the regulated facility and concerned citizens.

  13. In a static model with deterministic discharges such as ours, the facility never chooses to reduce its discharge level strictly below the limit. This reduction merely increases abatement costs without any fine savings.

  14. Consult Fredriksson et al. (2011) as an example of a study exploring how elected officials can alter budgets for local environmental agencies. As another example, Jones and Scotchmer (1990) used the size of the budget allocated to the agency to influence monitoring strategies. However, in contrast to our study, the standard is exogenous in their model.

  15. For simplicity, we assume that fine payments are welfare-neutral transfers; consequently, these policy changes do not affect consumer surplus.

References

  • Arguedas, C. (2008). To comply or not to comply? Pollution standard setting under costly monitoring and sanctioning. Environmental and Resource Economics, 41(2), 155–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arguedas, C., & Rousseau, S. (2015). Emission standards and monitoring strategies in a hierarchical setting. Environmental & Resource Economics, 60(3), 395–412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banzhaf, H. S., & Chupp, B. A. (2012). Fiscal federalism and interjurisdictional externalities: New results and an application to US air pollution. Journal of Public Economics, 96, 449–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binder, S., & Neumayer, E. (2005). Environmental pressure group strength and air pollution: An empirical analysis. Ecological Economics, 55, 527–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheng, C.-C., & Lai, Y.-B. (2012). Does a stricter enforcement policy protect the environment? A political economy perspective. Resource and Energy Economics, 34, 431–441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, M. A. (2000). Monitoring and enforcement of environmental policy. In T. Tietenberg & H. Folmer (Eds.), International yearbook of environmental and resource economics (Vol. III). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dal Bo, E. (2006). Regulatory capture: A review. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 22(2), 203–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Damania, R., Fredriksson, P. G., & List, J. A. (2003). Trade liberalization, corruption, and environmental policy formation: Theory and evidence. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 46, 490–512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Decker, C. S. (2007). Flexible enforcement and fine adjustement. Regulation & Governance, 1, 312–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donohue and Associates. (2014). Wastewater planning and permit negotiation. http://www.donohue-associates.com/projects/wastewater-case-studies/wastewater-planning-and-permit-negotiations. Last viewed on 21 May 2014.

  • Dubois, M. (2013). Economic instruments for European waste management. Doctoral thesis, Faculty of Business and Economics, KU Leuven.

  • Earnhart, D., & Glicksman, R. (2010). Pollution limits and polluters’ efforts to comply: The role of government monitoring and enforcement. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • EPA. (1990). A primer on the office of water enforcement and permits and its programs. Washington, DC: Environmental Protection Agency.

    Google Scholar 

  • EPA (n.d.). What is a CAG?. http://www.epa.gov/superfund/community/cag/whatis.htm.

  • Firestone, J. (2002). Agency governance and enforcement: The influence of mission on environmental decision making. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 21(3), 409–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Firestone, J. (2003). Enforcement of pollution laws and regulations: An analysis of forum choice. Harvard Environmental Law Review, 27, 105–176.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson, P. G. (1997). The political economy of pollution taxes in a small open economy. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 33, 44–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson, P. G., Wang, L., & Mamun, K. A. (2011). Are politicians office or policy motivated? The case of US governors’ environmental policies. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 62(2), 241–253.

  • Garoupa, N., & Klerman, D. M. (2010). Corruption and private law enforcement: Theory and history. Review of Law and Economics, 6(1), 75–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garvie, D., & Keeler, A. (1994). Incomplete enforcement with endogenous regulatory choice. Journal of Public Economics, 55, 141–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goulder, L. H., & Stavins, R. N. (2011). Challenges from state–federal interactions in US climate change policy. American Economic Review, 101(3), 253–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goulder, L. H., & Stavins, R. N. (2012). Interactions between State and Federal climate change policies. In D. Fullerton & C. Wolfram (Eds.), The design and implementation of US climate policy (pp. 109–121). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Greenstone, M. (2002). The impacts of environmental regulations on industrial activity: Evidence from the 1970 and 1977 Clean Air Act Amendments and the census of manufactures. Journal of Political Economy, 110(6), 1175–1219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenstone, M. (2004). Did the Clean Air Act cause the remarkable decline in sulfur dioxide concentrations? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 47, 585–611.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gullberg, A. T. (2008). Rational lobbying and EU climate policy. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 8, 161–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harford, J., & Harrington, W. (1991). A reconsideration of enforcement leverage when penalties are restricted. Journal of Public Economics, 45, 391–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrington, W. (1988). Enforcement leverage when penalties are restricted. Journal of Public Economics, 37, 29–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heyes, A., & Kapur, S. (2009). Enforcement missions: Targets vs. budgets. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 58(2), 129–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hunter, S., & Waterman, R. (1996). Enforcing the law: The case of the Clean Water Acts. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, C. A. (1989). Standard setting with incomplete enforcement revisited. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 8(1), 72–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, C. A., & Scotchmer, S. (1990). The social cost of uniform regulatory standards in a hierarchical government. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 19, 61–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keeler, A. (1995). Regulatory objectives and enforcement behavior. Environmental and Resource Economics, 6, 73–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lavrysen, L. (2009). Cursus milieurecht (“Syllabus Environmental Law”). Gent: Ghent University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luyet, V., Schlaepfer, R., Parlange, M. B., & Buttler, A. (2012). A framework to implement stakeholder participation in environmental projects. Journal of Environmental Management, 111, 213–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Makowsky, M. D., & Stratmann, T. (2009). Political economy at any speed: What determines traffic citations? American Economic Review, 99(1), 509–527.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markussen, P., & Svendsen, G. T. (2005). Industry lobbying and the political economy of GHG trade in the EU. Energy Policy, 33(2), 245–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • May, P. J., & Winter, S. (1999). Regulatory enforcement and compliance: Examining danish Agro-Environmental Policy. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 18(4), 625–651.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ovaere, L., Proost, S., & Rousseau, S. (2013). The choice of environmental regulatory enforcement by Lobby groups. Journal of Environmental Economics and Policy, 2(3), 328–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Revesz, R. L., & Stavins, R. N. (2007). Environmental law. In Polinsky, A. M., & Shavell, S. (Eds.),Handbook of law and economics, Vol. 1, No. 27, Handbooks in Economics, New York: Elsevier, 499–589.

  • Saha, A., & Poole, G. (2000). The economics of crime and punishment: An analysis of optimal penalty. Economics Letters, 68, 191–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stafford, S. (2012). The role of enforcement in improving the performance of pipelines in the US. working paper, College of William and Mary.

  • Troutman Sanders. (2014). Water and wastewater. http://www.troutmansanders.com/environmental_waterquality. Last viewed on 21 May 2014.

  • Veljanovski, C. G. (1984). The economics of regulatory enforcement. In K. Hawkins & J. M. Thomas (Eds.), Enforcing regulation. Boston, MA: Kluwer-Nijhoff Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Videira, N., Antunes, P., Santos, R., & Lobo, G. (2006). Public and stakeholder participation in European Water Policy: A critical review of project evaluation processes. European Environment, 16, 19–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wesselink, A., Paavola, J., Fritsch, O., & Renn, O. (2011). Rationales for public participation in environmental policy and governance: Practitioners’ perspectives. Environment and Planning A, 43, 2688–2704.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • West Yost Associates. (2014). Easterly wastewater treatment plant NPDES permitting. http://www.westyost.com/project/easterly-wastewater-treatment-plant-npdes-permitting. Last viewed on 21 May 2014.

  • Williams, R. C, I. I. I. (2012). Growing State–Federal conflicts in environmental policy: The role of market-based regulation. Journal of Public Economics, 96, 1092–1099.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zinn, M. D. (2002). Policing environmental regulatory enforcement: Cooperation, capture, and citizen suits. Stanford Environmental Law Journal, 21, 81–174.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We wish to thank Mitchell Polinsky, Daniel Klerman, Jun Jie Wu, the participants of the 2014 World Congress of Environmental and Resource Economists, the 2015 Conference of the Society of Environmental Law and Economics, the 2016 Annual Conference of the European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, and two anonymous referees for their comments and suggestions on earlier drafts. Carmen Arguedas and Sandra Rousseau also acknowledge financial support from the Spanish Government under research projects ECO2011-25349 and ECO2014-52372-P.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Carmen Arguedas.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Arguedas, C., Earnhart, D. & Rousseau, S. Non-uniform implementation of uniform standards. J Regul Econ 51, 159–183 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-017-9321-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-017-9321-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation