Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The hidden cost of investment: the impact of adjustment costs on firm performance measurement and regulation

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Regulatory Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this study, we address a major problem in the measurement of firm performance and the regulation of natural monopolies, namely the intertemporal character of long-term investment decisions. Specifically, we focus on the impact of adjustment costs of investments on estimates of firms’ technical and cost inefficiency. We make use of a nonparametric dynamic data envelopment analysis to investigate the dynamic inefficiency of electricity distribution and transmission companies in the US during the years 2004–2011. These results are compared to their static counterparts. Our empirical findings reveal that ignoring long-term investments and their corresponding adjustment costs significantly distorts both firm-specific and industrial inefficiency estimates and may thus create misleading incentives for the regulated firms to cut investments.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for example, Joskow (2008) for a review on incentive-based regulation in electricity networks.

  2. CEPA et al. (2010) estimate the economic lifetime of capital assets in the electricity transmission and distribution industry to vary between 10 and 140 years. The weighted average is calculated to be around 50 years for electricity transmission and around 70 years for electricity distribution. In contrast, a typical regulatory period within incentive-based regulation schemes comprises three to 8 years (EYGM Limited 2013).

  3. In regulatory practice, quality enhancing and capacity expanding investments are usually excluded from the pure benchmarking exercise and considered separately, e.g. via an additional quality and/or expansion factor in the price- or revenue-cap formula (see Eq. 1).

  4. Obtaining reliable estimates for shadow values of quasi-fixed factors is methodologically challenging. This is because each shadow value represents a scarcity indicator for the respective quasi-fixed factor and thus depends on the initial capital stock vector, output quantities and input prices. This endogeneity calls for a simultaneous determination of optimal firm-specific input quantities and firm-specific shadow values of quasi-fixed factors (Oude Lansink and Silva 2013). However, a simultaneous determination translates into a nonlinear problem with severe numerical difficulties. For this reason, we use an alternative sequential approach to determine the shadow value of the quasi-fixed factor within our empirical application (see Sect. 6).

  5. For a detailed discussion on the duality between the dynamic directional distance function and the current value of the optimal value function of the intertemporal cost minimization problem, see Oude Lansink and Silva (2013).

  6. The index is calculated from the average annual pay data obtained from the Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages, which is published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics: http://www.bls.gov/cew/cewind.htm#year=2010&qtr=1&own=5&ind=10&size=0.

  7. Obtained from the Bureau of Labor Statistics: http://data.bls.gov/timeseries/PCU221122221122.

  8. Obtained from the Bureau of Labor Statistics: http://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm.

  9. A detailed description of the parametric approximation of the firm-specific shadow values of capital is provided in the Appendix.

  10. For a limited number of observations, we find dynamic cost inefficiency values greater than one. This is the case when actual and optimal investments show a huge difference. Considering these observations as extreme cases, we denote them as outliers and do not include them in our further analysis.

  11. Since we use only one variable input measured in monetary terms (OPEX) in our empirical application, the obtained results on the static technical inefficiency can also be interpreted as a static cost inefficiency measure, that is, inefficiency due to over-usage in cost.

References

  • Averch, H., & Johnson, L. L. (1962). Behavior of the firm under regulatory constraint. The American Economic Review, 52(5), 1052–1069.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besanko, D., & Spulber, D. (1992). Sequential-equilibrium investment by regulated firms. The RAND Journal of Economics, 23(2), 153–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biglaiser, G., & Riordan, M. (2000). Dynamics of price regulation. The RAND Journal of Economics, 31(4), 744–767.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burger, A., & Geymüller, P. (2007). Assessing the effects of quality regulation in Norway with a quality regulated version of dynamic DEA. Working Paper 2007.4, Research Institute for Regulatory Economics, WU Vienna University of Economics and Business.

  • Cambini, C., & Rondi, L. (2010). Incentive regulation and investment: Evidence from european energy utilities. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 38(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cambridge Economic Policy Associates (CEPA), Sinclair Knight Merz (SKM), and GL Noble Dentom (2010). The economic lives of energy network assets. UK: Ofgem.

  • Dobbs, I. (2004). Intertemporal price cap regulation under uncertainty. The Economic Journal, 114(495), 421–440.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • EYGM Limited (2013). Mapping power and utilities regulation in Europe. http://www.ey.com/Publication/vwLUAssets/Mapping_power_and_utilities_regulation_in_Europe/$File/Mapping_power_and_utilities_regulation_in_Europe_DX0181.pdf. Accessed July 2015.

  • Evans, L., & Guthrie, G. (2012). Price-cap regulation and the scale and timing of investment. The RAND Journal of Economics, 43(3), 537–561.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fallah-Fini, S., Triantis, K., & Johnson, A. L. (2013). Reviewing the literature on non-parametric dynamic efficiency measurement: State-of-the-art. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 41(1), 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe, R., & Grosskopf, S. (1997). Efficiency and productivity in rich and poor countries. In B. Jensen & K. Wong (Eds.), Dynamics, economic growth, and international trade (pp. 243–263). Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe, R., & Primont, D. (1995). Multi-output production and duality: Theory and applications. Boston: Kluwer Academic.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Geymüller, P. (2007). The efficiency of european transmission system operators. An application of dynamic dea. Working Paper 2007.3, Research Institute for Regulatory Economics, WU Vienna University of Economics and Business.

  • Guthrie, G. (2006). Regulating infrastructure: The impact on risk and investment. Journal of Economic Literature, 44(4), 925–972.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jamasb, T., & Pollitt, M. (2001). Benchmarking and regulation: International electricity experience. Utilities Policy, 9, 107–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jamasb, T., & Pollitt, M. (2007). Incentive regulation of electricity distribution networks: Lessons of experience from britain. Energy Policy, 35, 6163–6178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joskow, P. (2008). Incentive regulation and its application to electricity networks. Review of Network Economics, 7(4), 547–560.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joskow, P. (2011). Incentive regulation in theory and practice—Electricity distribution and transmission networks. Nber chapters, National Bureau of Economic Research Inc.

  • Kwoka, J. (2009). Investment adequacy under incentive regulation. Boston: Northeast University. September.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leland, H. (1974). Regulation of natural monopolies and the fair rate of return. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5, 3–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lyon, T., & Mayo, J. (2005). Regulatory opportunism and investment behavior: Evidence from the U.S. electric utility industry. The RAND Journal of Economics, 36(3), 628–644.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nagel, T., & Rammerstorfer, M. (2009). Modeling investment behavior under price cap regulation. Central European Journal of Operations Research, 17(2), 111–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nemoto, J., & Goto, N. (1999). Dynamic data envelopment analysis: Modelling intertemporal behavior of a firm in the presence of productive inefficiencies. Economic Letters, 64, 51–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nemoto, J., & Goto, N. (2003). Measurement of dynamic efficiency in production: An application of data envelopment analysis to japanese electric utilities. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 19, 191–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nillesen, P., & Pollitt, M. (2010). Using regulatory benchmarking techniques to set company performance targets: the case of us electricity. Competition & Regulation in Network Industries, 11, 50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oude Lansink, A. & Silva, E. (2013). Dynamic efficiency measurement: A directional distance function approach. cef.up working paper series 7/2013, Center for Economics and Finance at the University of Porto.

  • Roques, F. A., & Savva, N. (2009). Investment under uncertainty with price ceilings in oligopolies. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 33(2), 507–524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sengupta, J. K. (1994). Evaluating dynamic efficiency by optimal control. International journal of systems science, 25(8), 1337–1353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sengupta, J. K. (1999). A dynamic efficiency model using data envelopment analysis. International Journal of Production Economics, 62(3), 209–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A. (1985). Theory of yardstick competition. The RAND Journal of Economics, 16, 319–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silva, E., & Oude Lansink, A. (2009). Dynamic efficiency measurement: A directional distance function approach. Wageningen: Wageningen University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silva, E., & Stefanou, S. (2003). Nonparametric dynamic production analysis and the theory of cost. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 19, 5–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silva, E., & Stefanou, S. (2007). Nonparametric dynamic efficiency measurement: Theory and application. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 89, 389–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, A. L. (1969). The allocation problem in financial accounting theory. Evanston: American Accounting Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vogelsang, I. (2010). Incentive regulation, investments and technological change. CESifo Working Paper 2964, München.

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank Christian Growitsch, Felix Höffler, Alfons Oude Lansink and Spiro Stefanou for helpful comments and suggestions as well as Julia Bellenbaum for excellent research assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sebastian Nick.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Parametric approximation of firm-specific shadow values of capital

The dynamic cost function in a quadratic functional form is given by

$$\begin{aligned} W_{it}= & {} \alpha _0 + \alpha _{QE}\,QE_{it} + \alpha _{QC}\,QC_{it} + \alpha _{K}\,K_{it} + \alpha _{w}\,w_{it} + \alpha _{c}\,c_{it}\nonumber \\&+\, \frac{1}{2} \alpha _{QE,QE}\,QE_{it}\,QE_{it} + \frac{1}{2} \alpha _{QC,QC}\,QC_{it}\,QC_{it}+ \frac{1}{2} \alpha _{K,K}\,K_{it}\,K_{it}\nonumber \\&+\, \frac{1}{2} \alpha _{w,w}\,w_{it}\,w_{it} + \frac{1}{2} \alpha _{c,c}\,c_{it} \,c_{it} + \alpha _{QE,QC}\,QE_{it}\,QC_{it} + \alpha _{QE,K}\,QE_{it}\,K_{it} \nonumber \\&+\, \alpha _{QE,w}\,QE_{it}\,w_{it} + \alpha _{QE,c}\,QE_{it}\,c_{it} + \alpha _{QC,K}\,QC_{it}\,K_{it} + \alpha _{QC,w}\,QC_{it}\,w_{it} \nonumber \\&+ \,\alpha _{QC,c}\,QC_{it}\,c_{it} + \alpha _{K,w}\,K_{it}\,w_{it}\nonumber \\&+\, \alpha _{K,c}\,K_{it}\,c_{it} + \alpha _{w,c}\,w_{it}\,c_{it} + \alpha _{t}\,t_{t} + \frac{1}{2} \alpha _{t,t}\,t^2_{t}, \end{aligned}$$
(12)

where the subscripts i and t denote the firm and year, respectively; W represents long-run costs; QE is the flow of electricity; QC is the number of customers; K is the capital stock; t is a time trend; and c and w are the price of capital and the price of the variable input, respectively.

Representing the dynamic cost function by \(g(\cdot )\), we estimate the parameters of Eq. 12 by solving the following minimization problem:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}&min \sum _{t=1}^T \sum _{i=1}^N \epsilon _{it}^2 \\ s.t. \;&W_{it}= g(\cdot ) + \epsilon _{it}&\quad \forall i,t,&(i) \\&\partial \, g(\cdot ) / \partial \, QE_{it}&\ge 0&\quad \forall i,t,&(ii) \\&\partial \, g(\cdot ) / \partial \, QC_{it}&\ge 0&\quad \forall i,t,&(iii) \\&\partial \, g(\cdot ) / \partial \, w_{it}&\ge 0&\quad \forall i,t,&(iv) \\&\partial \, g(\cdot ) / \partial \, c_{it}&\ge 0&\quad \forall i,t,&(v) \\&\partial \, g(\cdot ) / \partial \, K_{it}&\le 0&\quad \forall i,t,&(vi) \\ \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(13)

The problem minimizes the sum of squared residuals of the quadratic dynamic cost function subject to a set of inequality constraints that impose monotonicity required by economic theory. The shadow value of capital is then approximated by the first derivative of the cost function with respect to the capital stock:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \, g(\cdot ) }{\partial \, K_{it}}&= \alpha _{K} + \alpha _{K,K}\,K_{it} + \alpha _{QE,K}\,QE_{it} + \alpha _{QC,K}\,QC_{it} + \alpha _{K,w}\,w_{it} + \alpha _{K,c}\,c_{it}. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(14)

Appendix 2

See Table 4.

Table 4 Data sources

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Nick, S., Wetzel, H. The hidden cost of investment: the impact of adjustment costs on firm performance measurement and regulation. J Regul Econ 49, 33–55 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-015-9285-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-015-9285-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation