Skip to main content
Log in

Risk-adjusted option-implied moments

  • Published:
Review of Derivatives Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper provides a new way of converting risk-neutral moments into the corresponding physical moments, which are required for many applications. The main theoretical result is a new analytical representation of the expected payoffs of put and call options under the physical measure in terms of current option prices and a representative investor’s preferences. This representation is then used to derive analytical expressions for a variety of ex-ante physical return moments, showing explicitly how moment premiums depend on current option prices and preferences. As an empirical application of our theoretical results, we provide option-implied estimates of the representative stock market investor’s disappointment aversion using S&P 500 index option prices. We find that disappointment aversion has a procyclical pattern. It is high in times of high index levels and declines when the index falls. We confirm the view that investors with high risk aversion and disappointment aversion leave the stock market during times of turbulence and reenter it after a period of high returns.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, the volatility index VIX uses a model-free approach similar to the one proposed in Britten-Jones and Neuberger (2000) and serves itself as the underlying of a fast-growing derivatives market (Drimus and Farkas 2013).

  2. These papers use a representative investor with a specific utility function. Ross (2015) develops an alternative method by imposing restrictions on the dynamics of the stochastic discount factor. However, Borovicka et al. (2015) point out that the latter approach suffers from identification problems.

  3. See Theorem 2 of Bakshi et al. (2003).

  4. See Theorem 1 of Bakshi and Madan (2006).

  5. As Bliss and Panigirtzoglou (2004), p. 409, state, “the origins of the development of this result have proven difficult to trace.” A derivation of the result can be found, for example, in Aït-Sahalia and Lo (2000), p. 13ff.

  6. The utility function has to satisfy only mild conditions. It must be twice continuously differentiable with \(U'>0\) and \(U''<0\), a condition fulfilled by many common utility functions, such as the class discussed by Brockett and Golden (1987) and the hyperbolic absolute risk aversion (HARA) class.

  7. The corresponding risk-neutral model-free implied moments are given in Kozhan et al. (2013).

  8. See Christoffersen et al. (2012) for a presentation of the corresponding risk-neutral model-free implied moments.

  9. See Jiang and Tian (2005) for the corresponding result under the risk-neutral measure.

  10. See the survey articles by Poon and Granger (2003) and Christoffersen et al. (2012).

  11. For the standard definition of skewness, it is unclear what a reasonable realized moment would be.

  12. Digital options on the S&P 500 index trade on the CBOE since July 2008. These digital options, however, are very illiquid.

  13. It is important to note that, at this point, we still do not have to assume any particular option pricing model, such as the Black–Scholes model. Given that our volatility curve is continuously differentiable, the prices obtained from a duplication strategy consisting of k long call options with strike price K and k short call options with strike price \(K+(1/k)\) will converge to the prices we use for \(k\rightarrow \infty \).

  14. See Kozhan et al. (2013) for details.

  15. The utility function with disappointment aversion is not differentiable at \(W=F_{t,t+\tau }\), which violates the requirements of Proposition 1. It is no problem, however, to approximate the utility function in a small interval around \(F_{t,t+\tau }\) with a twice continuously differentiable function. That is how we proceed.

  16. In general, the reference point is the implicitly defined certainty-equivalent wealth at time \(t+\tau \) that depends on the endogenously determined portfolio of the investor. Since the representative investor holds the market, the certainty equivalent equals the forward price.

  17. The main results of increasing call payoffs with larger risk aversion and disappointment aversion as well as decreasing put payoffs with larger risk aversion are also stable over time and do not only reflect the particular situation on January 20, 2004. Moreover, the effects are generally stronger for at-the-money options than for out-of-the-money options.

  18. Mehra and Prescott (1985), p. 154, cite a number of papers arguing that relative risk aversion falls in the range between 1 and 2. However, they allow for values of up to 10 in their own study and a more recent paper by Azar (2006) estimates a value of 4.5. Ang et al. (2005) vary the coefficient of relative risk averison between 2 and 10 and consider disappointment aversion coefficients between 1.0 and 0.6. We allow for an even broader range of parameters in our optimization to be on the safe side.

  19. See Proposition 19.13 of Alsmeyer (2003). Special cases of this result in which \(\mu \) is a probability measure and f is a random variable can be found in many textbooks, such as Lemma 6.1. of Feller (1971).

References

  • Aït-Sahalia, Y., & Brandt, M. W. (2008) Consumption and portfolio choice with option-implied state prices. Working paper NBER.

  • Aït-Sahalia, Y., & Lo, A. W. (2000). Nonparametric risk management and implied risk aversion. Journal of Econometrics, 94, 9–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alsmeyer, G. (2003). Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie, 3. Auflage (Skripten zur Mathematischen Statistik Nr. 30, Münster).

  • An, B.-J., Ang, A., Bali, T. G., & Cakici, N. (2014). The joint cross section of stocks and options. Journal of Finance, 69, 2279–2337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ang, A., Bekaert, G., & Liu, J. (2005). Why stocks may disappoint. Journal of Financial Economics, 76, 471–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azar, S. A. (2006). Measuring relative risk aversion. Applied Financial Economics Letters, 2, 341–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Babiak, P. (2016) Generalized disappointment aversion, learning and variance premium. Working paper, Charles University Prague.

  • Bakshi, G., & Kapadia, N. (2003). Delta-hedged gains and the negative market volatility risk premium. Review of Financial Studies, 16, 527–566.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakshi, G., Kapadia, N., & Madan, D. (2003). Stock return characteristics, skew laws, and the differential pricing of individual equity options. Review of Financial Studies, 16, 101–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakshi, G., & Madan, D. (2000). Spanning and derivative security valuation. Journal of Financial Economics, 55, 205–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakshi, G., & Madan, D. (2006). A theory of volatility spreads. Management Science, 52, 1945–1956.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baule, R., Korn, O., & Saßning, S. (2016). Which beta is best? On the information content of option-implied betas. European Financial Management, 22, 450–483.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bekaert, G., Hoerova, M., & Duca, M. L. (2013). Risk, uncertainty and monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 60, 771–788.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bliss, R. R., & Panigirtzoglou, N. (2002). Testing the stability of implied probability density functions. Journal of Banking & Finance, 26, 381–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bliss, R. R., & Panigirtzoglou, N. (2004). Option-implied risk aversion estimates. Journal of Finance, 59, 407–446.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borovicka, J., Hansen, L. P., & Scheinkman, J. A. (2015) Misspecified recovery. Working paper, New York University.

  • Britten-Jones, M., & Neuberger, A. (2000). Option prices, implied price processes, and stochastic volatility. Journal of Finance, 55, 839–866.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brockett, P. L., & Golden, L. L. (1987). A class of utility functions containing all the common utility functions. Management Science, 33, 955–964.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buss, A., & Vilkov, G. (2012). Measuring equity risk with option-implied correlations. Review of Financial Studies, 25, 3113–3140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carr, P., & Madan, D. (2001). Optimal positioning in derivative securities. Quantitative Finance, 1, 19–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carr, P., & Wu, L. (2009). Variance risk premiums. Review of Financial Studies, 22, 1311–1341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, B.-Y., Christoffersen, P., Jacobs, K., & Vainberg, G. (2012). Option-implied measures of equity risk. Review of Finance, 16, 385–428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christoffersen, P., Jacobs, K., & Chang, B.-Y. (2012). Forecasting with option implied information. In G. Elliott & A. Timmermann (Eds.), Handbook of economic forecasting (pp. 581–656). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Conrad, J., Dittmar, R. F., & Ghysels, E. (2013). Ex ante skewness and expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 68, 85–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coval, J. D., & Shumway, T. (2001). Expected option returns. Journal of Finance, 56, 983–1009.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeMiguel, V., Plyakha, Y., Uppal, R., & Vilkov, G. (2013). Improving portfolio selection using option-implied volatility and skewness. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 48, 1813–1845.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Driessen, J., & Maenhout, P. (2007). An empirical portfolio perspective on option pricing anomalies. Review of Finance, 11, 561–603.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drimus, G., & Farkas, W. (2013). Local volatility of volatility for the VIX market. Review of Derivatives Research, 16, 267–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duan, J.-C., & Zhang, W. (2014). Forward-looking market risk premium. Management Science, 60, 521–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feller, W. (1971). An introduction to probability theory and its applications (2nd ed., Vol. II). New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giamouridis, D., & Skiadopoulos, G. (2012). The informational content of financial options for quantitative asset management. In B. Scherer & G. Winston (Eds.), Handbook of quantitative asset management (pp. 243–265). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

  • Gul, F. (1991). A theory of disappointment aversion. Econometrica, 59, 667–686.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hollstein, F., & Prokopczup, M. (2016). Estimating beta. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 51, 1437–1466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackwerth, J. C. (2000). Recovering risk aversion from option prices and realized returns. Review of Financial Studies, 13, 433–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jiang, G. J., & Tian, Y. S. (2005). The model-free implied volatility and its information content. Review of Financial Studies, 18, 1305–1342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kempf, A., Korn, O., & Saßning, S. (2015). Portfolio optimization using forward-looking information. Review of Finance, 19, 467–490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kostakis, A., Panigirtzoglou, N., & Skiadopoulos, G. (2011). Market timing with option-implied distributions: A forward-looking approach. Management Science, 57, 1231–1249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kozhan, R., Neuberger, A., & Schneider, P. (2013). The skew risk premium in the equity index market. Review of Financial Studies, 26, 2174–2203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Latané, H. A., & Rendleman, R. J. (1976). Standard deviations of stock price ratios implied in option prices. Journal of Finance, 31, 369–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehra, R., & Prescott, E. C. (1985). The equity premium: A puzzle. Journal of Monetary Economics, 15, 145–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neuberger, A. (2012). Realized skewness. Review of Financial Studies, 25, 3423–3455.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newey, W. K., & West, K. D. (1987). A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica, 55, 703–708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poon, S.-H., & Granger, C. W. J. (2003). Forecasting volatility in financial markets: A review. Journal of Economic Literature, 41, 478–539.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S. A. (2015). The recovery theorem. Journal of Finance, 70, 615–648.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein, M. (1994). Implied binomial trees. Journal of Finance, 49, 771–818.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sasaki, H. (2016). The skewness risk premium in equilibrium and stock return predictability. Annals of Finance, 12, 95–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, P. (2015). Generalized risk premia. Journal of Financial Economics, 116, 487–504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schreindorfer, D. (2014). Tails, fears, and equilibrium option prices. Working paper, Arizona State University.

  • Siriopoulos, C., & Fassas, A. (2013). Dynamic relations of uncertainty expectations: A conditional assessment of implied volatility indices. Review of Derivatives Research, 16, 233–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Olaf Korn.

Additional information

We would like to thank an anonymous referee, Sanjiv Das, Alexander Kempf, Paolo Krischak, Marco Menner, Sven Saßning, Marliese Uhrig-Homburg, David Volkmann, Stefan Weisheit, and participants of the 2016 Conference of the Swiss Society for Financial Market Research (SGF), Zürich and the 2016 Meetings of the German Finance Association (DGF), Bonn, for their helpful comments and suggestions. The opinions expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Deutsche Bundesbank or its staff.

Appendix

Appendix

To prove Proposition 1, we use Eq. (1) and the following result from measure theoryFootnote 19:

Let \((\Omega ,\mathcal {A},\mu )\) be a finite measure space, f a non-negative, real-valued measurable function, and \(\varphi :[0,\infty ) \rightarrow [0,\infty )\) a continuously differentiable and monotonically increasing function with \(\varphi (0)=0\). Then,

$$\begin{aligned} \int \varphi \circ f \, d\mu \; = \; \int \limits _{0}^{\infty } \varphi '(x) \, \mu (f>x) \, dx. \end{aligned}$$
(16)

Since U is twice continuously differentiable, the function \(\frac{1}{U'(x)}\), \(x\in [0,\infty )\), has the following properties:

  1. (i)

    \(\frac{1}{U'(x)}\) is continuously differentiable, since it is a composition of continuously differentiable functions;

  2. (ii)

    \(\frac{1}{U'(x)}\) increases monotonically for all \(x>0\), since \(\left( \frac{1}{U'(x)}\right) '=\frac{-U''(x)}{U'(x)^2}>0\);

  3. (iii)

    for \(x \rightarrow 0\), \(\frac{1}{U'(x)}\) reaches its minimum and converges to a non-negative value. Therefore, \(\frac{1}{U'(x)}\) is a non-negative function.

It follows that \(\frac{1}{U'(x)}-\frac{1}{U'(0)}\) satisfies all conditions required for \(\varphi \), where \(\frac{1}{U'(0)}\) stands for \(\lim \limits _{x \rightarrow 0} \,\, \frac{1}{U'(x)}\).

The discounted expected payoff of a call option under the physical measure equals

$$\begin{aligned} C^{P}(t,\tau ,K)&= E^P \left[ e^{-r\tau } (S_{t+\tau } -K)^+ \right] \\&= \int \limits _{0}^{\infty } e^{-r\tau } (S_{t+\tau }-K)^+ P(dS_{t+\tau }). \end{aligned}$$

Using the relation between physical and risk-neutral measures from Eq. (1) yields

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{1}{c} \cdot \int \limits _{0}^{\infty } e^{-r\tau } (S_{t+\tau }-K)^+ \frac{1}{U'(S_{t+\tau })} Q(dS_{t+\tau }) \\&\quad = \frac{1}{c} \cdot \int \limits _{0}^{\infty } \left\{ \frac{1}{U'(S_{t+\tau })} - \frac{1}{U'(0)} + \frac{1}{U'(0)}\right\} \underbrace{e^{-r\tau } (S_{t+\tau }-K)^+ Q(dS_{t+\tau })}_{\equiv \mu _C(dS_{t+\tau })}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\mu _C\) defines a measure. We can now apply the above result from measure theory, which leads to

$$\begin{aligned} C^{P}(t,\tau ,K)&= \frac{1}{c} \cdot \int \limits _{0}^{\infty } \frac{-U''(x)}{U'(x)^2} \mu _{C}\{S_{t+\tau }>x\} dx + \frac{C(t,\tau ,K)}{c \cdot U'(0)} \\&= \frac{1}{c} \cdot \int \limits _{0}^{\infty } \frac{-U''(x)}{U'(x)^2} \left\{ \int \limits _{x}^{\infty } e^{-r\tau } (S_{t+\tau }-K)^+ Q(dS_{t+\tau })\right\} dx \\&\quad +\frac{C(t,\tau ,K)}{c \cdot U'(0)} . \end{aligned}$$

For \(x<K\), the inner integral \(\int \limits _{x}^{\infty } e^{-r\tau } (S_{t+\tau }-K)^+ Q(dS_{t+\tau })\) equals the value of a plain-vanilla call option with strike price K. For \(x > K\), it follows that

$$\begin{aligned}&\int \limits _{x}^{\infty } e^{-r\tau } \underbrace{(S_{t+\tau }-K)^+}_{> 0} Q(dS_{t+\tau }) \\&\quad = \int \limits _{x}^{\infty } e^{-r\tau } (S_{t+\tau }-x) Q(dS_{t+\tau }) +\int \limits _{x}^{\infty } e^{-r\tau } (x-K) Q(dS_{t+\tau })\\&\quad = C(t,\tau ,x) + (x-K) e^{-r\tau } Q\{S_{t+\tau }>x\} \\&\quad = C(t,\tau ,x) + (x-K) D(t,\tau ,x), \end{aligned}$$

where \(D(t,\tau ,x)\) denotes the price of a digital option that pays $1 if \(S_{t+\tau }>x\).

Finally, we obtain the following expression:

$$\begin{aligned} C^P(t,\tau ,K)= & {} \frac{1}{c} \cdot \int \limits _{0}^{\infty } \frac{-U''(x)}{U'(x)^2} C(t,\tau ,K)1_{\{x < K \}} dx + \frac{C(t,\tau ,K)}{c \cdot U'(0)} \\&+ \frac{1}{c} \cdot \int \limits _{0}^{\infty } \frac{-U''(x)}{U'(x)^2} \left\{ C(t,\tau ,x) + (x-K) D(t,\tau ,x) \right\} 1_{\{x > K \}} dx \\= & {} \frac{1}{c} \cdot C(t,\tau ,K) \left\{ \frac{1}{U'(K)}-\frac{1}{U'(0)}\right\} + \frac{C(t,\tau ,K)}{c \cdot U'(0)} \\&+ \frac{1}{c} \cdot \int \limits _{K}^{\infty } \frac{-U''(x)}{U'(x)^2} \left\{ C(t,\tau ,x) + (x-K) D(t,\tau ,x) \right\} dx . \end{aligned}$$

The expression for the constant c can be derived similarly:

$$\begin{aligned} c = \int \limits _{0}^{\infty } \left\{ \frac{1}{U'(S_{t+\tau })} - \frac{1}{U'(0)} + \frac{1}{U'(0)}\right\} Q(dS_{t+\tau }). \end{aligned}$$

Applying the above result from measure theory to the measure Q yields

$$\begin{aligned} c&= \int \limits _{0}^{\infty } \frac{-U''(x)}{U'(x)^2} \Bigg \{ \int \limits _{x}^{\infty } Q(dS_{t+\tau }) \Bigg \} dx + \frac{1}{U'(0)}\\&= \int \limits _{0}^{\infty } \frac{-U''(x)}{U'(x)^2} e^{r\tau } D(t,\tau ,x) dx + \frac{1}{U'(0)}. \end{aligned}$$

The proof for the expected discounted payoff of a put option proceeds similarly. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Brinkmann, F., Korn, O. Risk-adjusted option-implied moments. Rev Deriv Res 21, 149–173 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11147-017-9136-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11147-017-9136-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation