Skip to main content
Log in

Corporate Real Estate Holding and Stock Returns: Testing Alternative Theories with International Listed Firms

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study examines the relationship between corporate real estate (CRE) holdings and stock returns before and after the Global Financial Crisis (GFC). We find that (1) the United States and the United Kingdom show a negative relationship before the GFC and positive after the GFC. (2) Firms that pay positive tax or have positive R&D investments are not systematically different from the full sample. This finding cannot support the "scarce capital" theory or the tax incentive explanation, but it is consistent with the “empire building” theory. After the GFC, financial constraints tightened, and both CRE holding and stock returns dropped. (3) European (excluding the United Kingdom) sample shows a positive relationship in the pre-crisis period. This finding is compatible with the "illiquidity premium" theory. However, the association becomes inconclusive in the post-crisis period. (3) The Japanese sample shows a negative association between CRE and stock returns in the pre-crisis period, like the United States and the United Kingdom. However, the relationship becomes statistically insignificant in the post-crisis period, consistent with the theory of financial constraint tightening after the GFC.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For instance, in the United States, Zeckhauser and Silverman (1983) report that at least 25% of the total assets of corporations in the U.S. were corporate properties in the 1980s. From 1984 to 2011, Zhao and Sing (2016) report that the average CRE controlled by listed firms in the U.S. was about 10% of the total assets. In Europe, a report conducted by DTZ (2003) shows that the full value of the CRE in Germany, France, and the U.K. was 1 trillion, 0.7 trillion, and 0.71 trillion euros, respectively, in 2002. In Asia, Liow (1999) reports that over 1987-1996, CRE held by a sample of Singapore non-real estate firms was about S$ 35.9 billion and comprised about 29% of the firms' total tangible assets. Brounen and Eichholtz (2005) study an international sample of nine countries whose CRE as a percentage of total assets ranges from 17% in Germany to 41% in Canada in 2000. See also Riddiough (2022).

  2. Several papers compare competing theories on housing and commercial real estate, such as Kwan et al. (2015), Leung et al. (2002), Leung and Feng (2005), among others.

  3. For example, in 2000, the average CRE ratio for the sample countries was 0.13 for the business service industry and 0.63 for mining companies.

  4. The appendix presents a simple model of corporate investment, where the trade-off between investing in CRE and R&D depends on the probability of success in R&D, which may vary across firms.

  5. Some authors also argue that the U.S. dollar has an "exorbitant privilege" (Eichengreen, 2011). Some investors are willing to accept a lower return for U.S. assets (Forbes, 2010). Therefore, it is beneficial to verify whether the "stylized facts" in the U.S. market also hold in other markets.

  6. Among others, see Chang and Leung (2022), Green (2022), Leung and Ng (2019), Ng (2022), Van Eyden et al. (2022).

  7. We also conduct the same analysis for an Asia pacific sample (excluding Japan). Unfortunately, the results do not pass the specification tests (the Arellano-Bond and the Hansen test).

  8. Notice that some financial firms can take deposits or premiums from customers, and hence their cost of capital will be very different from non-financial firms. Some financial firms are also subject to various regulations than non-financial firms. In addition, real estate firms may need real estate as input, and thus, their motives for CRE holding may differ from non-real estate firms.

    We compare the pre-crisis and post-crisis periods, and we employ data starting from 2001 to balance the pre-crisis (2001–2006) and post-crisis (2010–2015) samples.

  9. Different measures of CRE employed in the previous literature are provided in the appendix.

  10. Note that period t covers the 12-month from July in year t to June in year t + 1. The Fama-French three factors are calculated at a monthly frequency. MKT represents the market excess return, SMB represents the return of the portfolio that is long in small firms and short in big firms, and HML stands for the return of the portfolio that is long in high B/M firms and short in low B/M firms. Finally, Carhart (1997) momentum factor (MOM) is constructed at a monthly frequency. It captures the return of the trading strategy that is long in short-term winners and short in short-term losers. $${\alpha }_{i,t}$$ absorbs all the abnormal returns that are not captured by the four factors.

  11. Furthermore, the endogeneity problem caused by selection bias is a common concern (e.g., see Dang et al. (2015) and the reference therein). In the current context, the entry and exit of firms could potentially create a selection bias (Guo and Leung, 2021; Hopenhayn, 1992; Jovanovic, 1982). Fortunately, through analyzing the dynamic panel data models with sample selection, Al-Sadoon et al. (2019) recently found that the inconsistency of the System GMM estimator is tiny and hardly induces bias in the estimator, even and especially in small samples.

  12. Moreover, firm-level variables such as leverage may be influenced by corporate governance variables. For more discussion, see Morellec et al. (2012) and the reference therein, among others,

  13. We receive an additional suggestion during the GFC, capital flow to the USA for flight-to-liquidity (FTL) or flight-to-safety (FTS) considerations. Hence, the results that hold in the U.S. do not necessarily hold internationally. Considering the impact of international capital flows on CRE holding would be beyond the scope of this paper. The literature on FTL and FTS is also abundant. See Baele et al. (2019), Beber et al. (2008), Longstaff (2004), and the references therein, among others.

  14. Although corporate tax policies vary among different economies, to be consistent, we compare the subsample of tax-paying firms with the entire sample in each region.

  15. There are different definitions of “zombie firms” used in the literature. However, a prevalent practice is to include firms which “were not able to cover their interest expenses out of their pretax earnings.” See Acharya et al., (2019a, b), among others, for more details.

  16. To further simplify the analysis, we can assume that the rental rate for the CRE, i.e. \({R}_{h}\) is pre-determined in period \(0\).

References

  • Abad, L. A., & Khalifa, K. (2015). What are stylized facts? Journal of Economic Methodology, 22(2), 143–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acharya, V., Crosignani, M., Eisert, T. and Eufinger, C. (2019a). Zombie credit and (dis-) inflation in Europe, NYU, mimeo.

  • Acharya, V., Eisert, T., Eufinger, C., & Hirsch, C. W. (2019b). Whatever it takes: The real effects of unconventional monetary policy. Review of Financial Studies, 32(9), 3366–3411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Al-Sadoon, M. M., Jiménez-Martín, S. and Labeaga, J. M. (2019). Simple methods for consistent estimation of dynamic panel data sample selection models. Economics Working Papers 1631, Department of Economics and Business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra.

  • Andrews, D., & Petroulakis, F. (2019). Breaking the shackles: Zombie firms, weak banks and depressed restructuring in Europe, ECB, mimeo.

  • Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 29–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baele, L., Bekaert, G., Inghelbrecht, K., & Wei, M. (2019). Flights to safety. The Review of Financial Studies. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhz055

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beber, A., Brandt, M. W., & Kavajecz, K. A. (2008). Flight-to-quality or flight-to-liquidity? Evidence from the euro-area bond market. Review of Financial Studies, 22(3), 925–957.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B., & Gertler, M. (1989). Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations. American Economic Review, 79(1), 14–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B., & Gertler, M. (1990). Financial fragility and economic performance. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(1), 87–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brounen, D., & Eichholtz, P. M. (2005). Corporate real estate ownership implications: International performance evidence. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 30(4), 429–445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, J. R., Fazzari, S. M., & Petersen, B. C. (2009). Financing innovation and growth: Cash flow, external equity, and the 1990s R&D boom. Journal of Finance, 64(1), 151–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carhart, M. M. (1997). On persistence in mutual fund performance. Journal of Finance, 52(1), 57–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan, S. H., Martin, J. D., & Kensinger, J. W. (1990). Corporate research and development expenditures and share value. Journal of Financial Economics, 26(2), 255–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaney, T., Sraer, D., & Thesmar, D. (2012). The collateral channel: How real estate shocks affect corporate investment. American Economic Review, 102(6), 2381–2409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, K. L. & Leung, C. K. Y. (2022). How did the asset markets change after the Global Financial Crisis? chpt 12. In C. K. Y. Leung (Ed.), Handbook of Real Estate and Macroeconomics, Northampton, M.A., USA.

  • Chen, N. K., & Leung, C. K. Y. (2008). Asset price spillover, collateral and crises: With an application to property market policy. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 37, 351–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, N. K., & Wang, H. J. (2007). The procyclical leverage effect of collateral value on bank loans-evidence from the transaction data of Taiwan. Economic Inquiry, 45(2), 395–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheong, K., & Kim, C. (1997). Corporate real estate holdings and the value of the firm in Korea. Journal of Real Estate Research, 13(3), 273–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, J. H. (2011). Presidential address: Discount rates. Journal of Finance, 66(4), 1047–1108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coles, J. L., Daniel, N. D., & Naveen, L. (2006). Managerial incentives and risk-taking. Journal of Financial Economics, 79(2), 431–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooley, T. (Ed.). (1995). Frontiers of business cycle research. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dang, V. A., Kim, M., & Shin, Y. (2015). In search of robust methods for dynamic panel data models in empirical corporate finance. Journal of Banking and Finance, 53(C), 84–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deng, Y., & Gyourko, J. (1999). Real estate ownership by non-real estate firms: An estimate of the impact on firm returns. Mimeo, Wharton School.

  • Dong, Y., Leung, C. K. Y., & Cai, D. (2012). What drives fixed asset holding and risk-adjusted performance of corporate in China? An empirical analysis. International Real Estate Review, 15(2), 141–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dresdow, G., & Tryce, R. (1988). Today’s corporate real estate demands better management. National Real Estate Investor, 30(10), 87–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • DTZ. (2003). Money into property Europe. The Netherlands: Amsterdam.

  • Du, J., Leung, C. K. Y., & Chu, D. (2014). Return enhancing, cash-rich or simply empire-building? An empirical investigation of corporate real estate holdings. International Real Estate Review, 17(3), 301–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eberhart, A. C., Maxwell, W. F., & Siddique, A. R. (2004). An examination of long term abnormal stock returns and operating performance following R&D increases. Journal of Finance, 59(2), 623–650.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eberly, J., Rebelo, S., & Vincent, N. (2012). What explains the lagged-investment effect? Journal of Monetary Economics, 59(4), 370–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, B. (2011). Exorbitant Privilege: The rise and fall of the Dollar and the future of the international monetary system. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Eyden, R., Gupta, R., Andre, C. & Sheng, X. (2022). The effect of macroeconomic uncertainty on housing returns and volatility: evidence from US state-level data, chpt 8. In C. K. Y. Leung (Ed.), Handbook of real estate and macroeconomics. Northampton, M.A., USA.

  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1992). The cross-section of expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 47(2), 427–465.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1993). Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics, 33(1), 3–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forbes, K. J. (2010). Why do foreigners invest in the United States? Journal of International Economics, 80(1), 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1953). The methodology of positive economics. In M. Friedman (Ed.), Essays in positive economics. University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gan, J. (2007a). Collateral, debt capacity, and corporate investment: Evidence from a natural experiment. Journal of Financial Economics, 85(3), 709–734.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gan, J. (2007b). The real effects of asset market bubbles: Loan-and firm-level evidence of a lending channel. Review of Financial Studies, 20(6), 1941–1973.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gompers, P., Ishii, J., & Metrick, A. (2003). Corporate governance and equity prices. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1), 107–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gort, M., Greenwood, J., & Rupert, P. (1999). Measuring the rate of technological progress in structures. Review of Economic Dynamics, 2(1), 207–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, R. (2022). Is housing still the business cycles? Perhaps not. In C. K. Y. Leung (Ed.), Handbook of real estate and macroeconomics, Northampton, M.A., USA.

  • Gregory, A., Tharayan, R., & Christidis, A. (2013). Constructing and testing alternative versions of the Fama-French and Carhart Models in the UK. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 40(1–2), 172–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gu, L. (2016). Product market competition, R&D investment, and stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 119(2), 441–455.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guo, N., & Leung, C. K. Y. (2021). Do elite colleges matter? The impact on entrepreneurship decisions and career dynamics. Quantitative Economics, 12, 1347–1397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hopenhayn, H. A. (1992). Entry, exit, and firm dynamics in long run equilibrium. Econometrica, 60(5), 1127–1150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jin, Y., Leung, C. K. Y., & Zeng, Z. (2012). Real estate, the external finance premium and business investment: A quantitative dynamic general equilibrium analysis. Real Estate Economics, 40(1), 167–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, L., & Keasler, T. (1993). An industry profile of corporate real estate. Journal of Real Estate Research, 8(4), 455–473.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic, B. (1982). Selection and the evolution of industry. Econometrica, 50(3), 649–670.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kan, K., Kwong, S. K. S., & Leung, C. K. Y. (2004). The dynamics and volatility of commercial and residential property prices: Theory and evidence. Journal of Regional Science, 44(1), 95–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaymak, B., & Schott, I. (2019). Loss-offset provisions in the corporate tax code and misallocation of capital. Journal of Monetary Economics, 105, 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiyotaki, N., & Moore, J. (1997). Credit cycles. Journal of Political Economy, 105(2), 211–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krumm, P. J., & Linneman, P. (2001). Corporate real estate management. Wharton Working Paper.

  • Kwan, Y. K., Leung, C. K. Y., & Dong, J. (2015). Comparing consumption-based asset pricing models: The case of an Asian city. Journal of Housing Economics, 28, 18–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leung, C. K. Y., & Feng, D. (2005). What drives the property price-trading volume correlation: Evidence from a commercial real estate market. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 31(2), 241–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leung, C. K. Y., & Tse, C. Y. (2017). Flipping in the housing market. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 76(C), 232–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leung, C. K. Y., Lau, G. C. K., & Leong, Y. C. F. (2002). Testing alternative theories of the property price-trading volume correlation. Journal of Real Estate Research, 23(3), 253–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leung, C. K. Y., & Ng, J. C. Y. (2019). Macroeconomic aspects of housing. In J. H. Hamilton, A. Dixit, S. Edwards, & K. Judd (Ed.), Oxford research encyclopedia of economics and finance. Oxford University Press. https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.294

  • Li, D. (2011). Financial constraints, R&D investment, and stock returns. Review of Financial Studies, 24(9), 2974–3007.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Linneman, P. (1998). The coming disposal of corporate real estate, Zell/Lurie real estate center at Wharton Working Paper, No. 302. University of Pennsylvania.

  • Liow, K. H. (1999). Corporate investment and ownership of real estate in Singapore – some empirical evidence. Journal of Corporate Real Estate, 1(4), 329–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liow, K. H., & Ooi, J. T. (2004). Does corporate real estate create wealth for shareholders? Journal of Property Investment & Finance, 22(5), 386–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Longstaff, F. (2004). The flight-to-liquidity premium in U.S. treasury bond prices. Journal of Business, 77(3), 511–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGowan, M. A., Dan Andrews, D., Millot, V., & Beck, T. (2018). The walking dead? Zombie firms and productivity performance in OECD countries. Economic Policy, 33(96), 685–736.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morellec, E., Nikolov, B., & Schürhoff, N. (2012). Corporate governance and capital structure dynamics. Journal of Finance, 67, 803–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ng, J. C. Y. (2022). international macroeconomic aspects of housing, chpt 11. In C. K. Y. Leung (Ed.), Handbook of real estate and macroeconomics. Northampton, M.A., USA.

  • Ogawa, K., & Suzuki, K. (1998). Land value and corporate investment: Evidence from Japanese panel data. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 12(3), 232–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ogawa, K., Kitasaka, S. I., Yamaoka, H., & Iwata, Y. (1996). Borrowing constraints and the role of land asset in Japanese corporate investment decision. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 10(2), 122–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riddiough, T. (2022). Pension funds and private equity real estate: History, performance, pathologies, risks, chpt 15. In C. K. Y. Leung (Ed.), Handbook of real estate and macroeconomics. Northampton, M.A., USA.

  • Roodman, D. (2009a). A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71(1), 135–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roodman, D. (2009b). How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference and system GMM in Stata. Stata Journal, 9(1), 86–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roulac, S. (2003). Corporate-owned real estate represents a substantial investment universe. Journal of Real Estate Portfolio Management, 9(2), 167–178.

  • Schmidt, C., Schneider, Y., Steffen, S., & Streitz, D. (2020). Capital mis-allocation and innovation, mimeo.

  • Seiler, M. J., Chatrath, A., & Webb, J. R. (2001). Real asset ownership and the risk and return to stockholders. Journal of Real Estate Research, 22(1–2), 199–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sing, T. F., & Sirmans, C. F. (2008). Does real estate ownership matter in corporate governance? Journal of Property Research, 25(1), 23–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sirmans, C. F. (1999). Governance issues in real estate investing: The case of REITs. RICS research conference, the cutting edge. University of Cambridge.

  • Sundaram, A. K., John, T. A., & John, K. (1996). An empirical analysis of strategic competition and firm values the case of R&D competition. Journal of Financial Economics, 40(3), 459–486.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tuzel, S. (2010). Corporate real estate holdings and the cross-section of stock returns. Review of Financial Studies, 23(6), 2268–2302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Windmeijer, F. (2005). A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. Journal of Econometrics, 126(1), 25–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zeckhauser S., & Silverman, R. (1983) Rediscover your company’s real estate. Harvard Business Review, January-February, 111–117.

  • Zhao, D., & Sing, T. F. (2016). Corporate real estate ownership and productivity uncertainty. Real Estate Economics, 44(2), 521–547.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank K. W. Chau, Been-Lon Chen, Yuen Long Chow, Julan Du, Gangzhi Fang, Chinmoy Ghosh, Ake Gunnelin, Rosane Hungria Gunnelin, Yuichiro Kawaguchi, Fred Kwan, Shian-Yu Liao, Seow Eng Ong, Chihiro Shimizu, Bertram Steininger, Isabel Yan, Fengting Zhang, an anonymous referee, seminar participants of APRER Symposium (Guangzhou), AsRES-AREUEA meeting, KTH Royal Institute of Technology, Taiwan Economic Association (Taipei) for helpful comments and the City University of Hong Kong for financial support. Part of the research is conducted when Leung visits the Hoover Institution; Ng visits the Virginia Tech through a Junior Fulbright Scholarship. The hospitality of these institutions is gratefully acknowledged. Leung's travel has been supported by the Higher Education Sprout Project from the Ministry of Education (Grant No. 110L900201) and the Ministry of Science and Technology (MOST 110-2634-F-002-045-) in Taiwan, and from ISER in Osaka University through JSPS KAKENHI Grant Number JP 20H05631. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding authors

Correspondence to Joe Cho Yiu Ng or Charles Ka Yui Leung.

Additional information

Publisher's note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A

This appendix mainly discusses two strands of the literature: the motives to own CRE and the relationship between CRE holdings and firm performance.

Motives to Own CRE

In the main text, we indicate that there are different motives to own CRE beyond production needs. Each purpose could result in another nexus between CRE holdings and returns. The first motivation for CRE holding is "empire building." Due to weak corporate governance, firms may over-invest in CRE and make less investment, and R & D. It leads to a negative correlation in CRE holding and stock return. Based on Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs) data in the U.S., Sirmans (1999) hypothesizes that specific sets of corporate governance mechanisms are needed for firms with substantial real estate holding. Sing and Sirmans (2008) employ a sample of 228 stocks listed in Singapore and formally reject the hypothesis that corporate governance mechanisms are independent of a firm's real estate ownership. Thus, the result is consistent with Sirmans (1999). Coles et al. (2006) show a strong causal relationship between management incentives and firms' behavior on investment policy, debt policy, and risk-taking. Employing a sample of U.S. listed corporations, Du et al. (2014) find no evidence for a return-enhancing role for CRE holdings, suggesting that CRE holdings are a form of managerial "empire building." In firms with weak governance, over-investment in the CRE is more likely to occur, and higher CRE holdings are associated with lower returns to shareholders. Dong et al. (2012) employ the Listed Chinese firms and find that corporate governance, state ownership, and preferential tax policy explain the CRE holding.

The second motive is related to CRE's collateral channel effect, which will lead to a positive nexus between CRE holdings and returns. Firms use CRE as inputs of production and collaterals to raise debt for investment, and firms could benefit from the appreciation of CRE holdings (Bernanke & Gertler, 1989, 1990; Chaney et al., 2012; Gan, 2007a, 2007b; Kiyotaki & Moore, 1997). For instance, Ogawa et al. (1996) and Ogawa and Suzuki (1998) find that the land price fluctuations in Japan would affect corporate investment behaviors. Gan (2007a) finds that, during the early 1990s, the investment rate of an average firm in Japan drops by 0.8 percentage points resulting from a 10% drop in land value. Chaney et al. (2012) also find that firms' investments in the U.S. are substantially affected by the shocks to the value of real estate holdings. For example, during 1993–1997, a $1 increase in collateral value leads the representative U.S. corporation to raise its investment by $0.06.

Relationship between CRE Holdings and Firm Performance

After discussing the motives to own CRE, we review the literature on the relationship between CRE holdings and firm performance. The first strand of research employs the idiosyncratic return (Alpha) and systematic risk component (Beta) to measure firm performance. Table 11 provides a summary of their main findings. For example, in the case of the United States, Deng and Gyourko (1999) employ firm-level data for 717 companies from 57 different non-real estate industries in the U.S. in 1984–1993 and find that firms with high degrees of real estate concentration and high Beta experience lower returns. However, employing a similar sample period (1985–1994), Seiler et al. (2001) find no relationship between CRE holdings and systematic risk and excess return.

On the other hand, Tuzel (2010) finds that CRE holdings positively affect abnormal returns in non-real estate firms in the U.S. from 1963 to 2003. In the case of other economies, Brounen and Eichholtz (2005) explores international CRE effects using samples from 18 industries and nine countries in the year 1992, 1995, 1998, and 2000, and find a significantly negative relationship between CRE holdings and systematic risk, while no association between CRE holdings and idiosyncratic risk. Finally, Cheong and Kim (1997) find that a listed manufacturing firm's CRE holdings had no significant effect upon the return-on-investment in its stocks from 1987 to 1991 in Korea.

On the other hand, Liow and Ooi (2004) use entirely different measures of firm performance. They evaluate stock return by two value-based metrics: economic value added (EVA), and market value added (MVA). Based on the data of listed non-real estate firms in Singapore from 1997 to 2001, the authors find that CRE hurts non-real estate firms' EVA and MVA. Based on the data of listed non-real estate firms in Singapore from 1997 to 2001, the authors find that CRE hurts non-real estate firms' EVA and MVA.

Another strand of literature explores the impact of CRE holding on other aspects of a firm's operation. For instance, Zhao and Sing (2016) empirically test the relationship between CRE holdings and the production risk of firms, which is measured by the volatility of the output per unit of capital. The publicly listed U.S. firms' data from 1984 to 2011 prove that CRE holding is significantly and negatively correlated with a firm's productivity risks. As a result, firms with high productivity risk (more volatile firms) hold a relatively lower level of the CRE.

Table 11 Previous literature on the relationship between CRE holdings and returns

Appendix B

This section presents a simple model of a firm, which can engage in R&D investment and corporate real estate (CRE) investment.

There are two periods, \(t=\mathrm{0,1}\). At time 0, a risk-neutral firm endowed with an amount of initial capital K and a linear technology to produce can choose to invest in R&D investment, which would boost productivity and invest in CRE, whose valuation in time 1 can be different. For simplicity, we assume that all these investment decisions are discrete. More specifically, the firm which invests \(D\) units of capital, \(0<D<K\) has a probability \(p\) to be successful, \(p\in [\mathrm{0,1}]\), and its productivity would increase from \(A\) to \(Ag\), \(A>0,g>1\). If the firm fails, the productivity remains to be \(A\). On the other hand, the firm can also acquire 1 unit of CRE, which costs \({P}_{h}\) units of capital in period \(0\), \({P}_{h}>0\). In period 1, the valuation of the CRE would become \({P}_{h}\varepsilon\), where \(\varepsilon\) represents an idiosyncratic valuation shock. The shock has finite and positive support, \(\varepsilon \in \left[{\varepsilon }_{L},{\varepsilon }_{H}\right], 0<{\varepsilon }_{L}<{\varepsilon }_{H}<\infty\). We assume that the first moment is also finite, \(0<E\left(\varepsilon \right)<\infty\). We assume that the valuation shock is independent of the risk involved in the R&D if R&D efforts are ever be made. Alternatively, the firm may rent CRE from the market at a rate \({R}_{h}\), \({0<R}_{h}<{P}_{h}\).Footnote 16 And to produce in period 1, the firm needs to pre-install capital in period \(0\). To simplify the analysis, we assume that \(K-D-{P}_{h}>0\). We introduce two indicator functions to represent the firm's R&D and CRE investment decisions. Formally,

$$I^R=\begin{Bmatrix}1&firm\;invests\;in\;R\&D\\0&otherwise\end{Bmatrix},$$
$${I}^{H}=\left\{\begin{array}{cc}1& firm\ invests\ in\ CRE\\ 0& otherwise\end{array}\right\}.$$

Thus, the firm which maximizes the expected value of the profit is

$$max.E\left(\pi \right)$$

where \(E\left[\pi \left({I}^{R},{I}^{H}\right)\right]=\left\{\left[pAg+\left(1-p\right)A\right]{I}^{R}+\left(1-{I}^{R}\right)A\right\}*\left[K-{I}^{R}D-{I}^{H}{P}_{h}-\left(1-{I}^{H}\right){R}_{h}\right]+{I}^{H}{P}_{h}\varepsilon\). This formula looks more complicated than it is. For instance, the profit for a firm engaging in both R&D and CRE investment is simply

$$E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{1,1}\right)\right]=\left\{\left[pAg+\left(1-p\right)A\right]\right\}*\left[K-D-{P}_{h}\right]+{P}_{h}E\left(\varepsilon \right).$$

Similarly, the profit for a firm engaging in R&D but not CRE investment is simply

$$E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{1,0}\right)\right]=\left\{\left[pAg+\left(1-p\right)A\right]\right\}*\left[K-D-{R}_{h}\right].$$

The profit for a firm engaging in CRE but not R&D investment is simply

$$E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{0,1}\right)\right]=A*\left[K-{P}_{h}\right]+{P}_{h}E\left(\varepsilon \right).$$

The profit for a firm engaging in neither R&D nor CRE investment is simply

$$E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{0,0}\right)\right]=A*\left[K-{R}_{h}\right].$$

Since the investment decisions are discrete, we simply compare different options pairwise.

Lemma 1. If \(\frac{1}{g-1}*\left[\frac{E\left(\varepsilon \right)}{A\left(1-\frac{{R}_{h}}{{P}_{h}}\right)}-1\right]>0,\) \(E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{1,0}\right)\right]>E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{1,1}\right)\right]\) if and only if \(p\) is sufficiently large.

Proof. The proof is straightforward. Observe that

$$\begin{array}{l}E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{1,0}\right)\right]-E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{1,1}\right)\right]\\ =\left\{\left[pAg+\left(1-p\right)A\right]\right\}*\left[K-D-{R}_{h}\right]-\left\{\left[pAg+\left(1-p\right)A\right]\right\}*\left[K-D-{P}_{h}\right]-{P}_{h}E\left(\varepsilon \right)\\ =\left\{\left[pAg+\left(1-p\right)A\right]\right\}*\left({P}_{h}-{R}_{h}\right)-{P}_{h}E\left(\varepsilon \right)\end{array}$$

>\(0\) if and only if \(p>{p}_{1}^{*}\), where \({p}_{1}^{*}=\frac{1}{g-1}*\left[\frac{E\left(\varepsilon \right)}{A\left(1-\frac{{R}_{h}}{{P}_{h}}\right)}-1\right]\). Since \(\frac{1}{g-1}*\left[\frac{E\left(\varepsilon \right)}{A\left(1-\frac{{R}_{h}}{{P}_{h}}\right)}-1\right]>0\), \({p}_{1}^{*}>0.\)

Notice further that in practice, \(\frac{{R}_{h}}{{P}_{h}}\) is very small. Hence, if \(\left(\varepsilon \right)>A\), then it is likely that\(\frac{1}{g-1}*\left[\frac{E\left(\varepsilon \right)}{A\left(1-\frac{{R}_{h}}{{P}_{h}}\right)}-1\right]>0\).

Notice further that if our condition is violated, for instance, \(E\left(\varepsilon \right)<A\left(1-\frac{{R}_{h}}{{P}_{h}}\right)\). In that case, it means that every firm which satisfies the stated assumption would find it better to invest in R&D only, rather than both R&D and CRE investment.

Lemma 2. If \(\left[\frac{A\left[D+{R}_{h}\right]-{P}_{h}\left(A-E\left(\varepsilon \right)\right)}{A\left(K-D-{R}_{h}\right)}\right]>0,\) \(E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{1,0}\right)\right]>E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{0,1}\right)\right]\) if and only if \(p\) is sufficiently large.

Proof. The proof is again straightforward. Observe that

$$\begin{array}{l}E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{1,0}\right)\right]-E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{0,1}\right)\right]=\left\{\left[pAg+\left(1-p\right)A\right]\right\}*\left[K-D-{R}_{h}\right]-\left\{A*\left[K-{P}_{h}\right]+{P}_{h}E\left(\varepsilon \right)\right\}\\ =p\left(g-1\right)AK-\left\{\left[pAg+\left(1-p\right)A\right]\right\}*\left[D+{R}_{h}\right]+{P}_{h}\left(A-E\left(\varepsilon \right)\right)\\ =p\left(g-1\right)A\left[K-D-{R}_{h}\right]-A\left[D+{R}_{h}\right]+{P}_{h}\left(A-E\left(\varepsilon \right)\right)\end{array}$$

\(>0\) if and only if \(p>{p}_{2}^{*}\), where \({p}_{2}^{*}=\frac{1}{\left(g-1\right)}*\left[\frac{A\left[D+{R}_{h}\right]-{P}_{h}\left(A-E\left(\varepsilon \right)\right)}{A\left(K-D-{R}_{h}\right)}\right]\). Since \(\left[\frac{A\left[D+{R}_{h}\right]-{P}_{h}\left(A-E\left(\varepsilon \right)\right)}{A\left(K-D-{R}_{h}\right)}\right]>0\),\({p}_{2}^{*}>0.\)

First, notice that \(A\left(K-D-{R}_{h}\right)>0,\) and \(\left(g-1\right)>0\) by assumption. Hence, it suffices to study the term \(A\left[D+{R}_{h}\right]-{P}_{h}\left(A-E\left(\varepsilon \right)\right)\). And \(A\left[D+{R}_{h}\right]-{P}_{h}\left(A-E\left(\varepsilon \right)\right)>0\) iff \({P}_{h}E\left(\varepsilon \right)<A{P}_{h}-A{R}_{h}-AD\). Notice also that

PhE(ε):

return from investing in CRE.

APh:

addition return from investing in R&D only.

ARh:

loss from investing in R&D only.

AD:

return from investing in R&D.

Thus, the RHS \(A{P}_{h}-A{R}_{h}-AD\) is the net return from R&D only, while the LHS \({P}_{h}E\left(\varepsilon \right)\) is net return from investing in CRE. If LHS < RHS, then the firm will invest in R&D only when the probability of success in R&D is sufficiently high.

Lemma 3. \(E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{1,0}\right)\right]>E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{0,0}\right)\right]\) if and only if \(p\) is sufficiently large.

Proof. The proof is again straightforward. Observe that

$$\begin{array}{l}E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{1,0}\right)\right]-E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{0,0}\right)\right]=\left\{\left[pAg+\left(1-p\right)A\right]\right\}*\left[K-D-{R}_{h}\right]-A*\left[K-{R}_{h}\right]\\ =p\left(g-1\right)A\left[K-{R}_{h}\right]-\left\{\left[pAg+\left(1-p\right)A\right]\right\}D\\ =p\left(g-1\right)A\left[K-D-{R}_{h}\right]-AD\end{array}$$

\(>0\) if and only if \(p>{p}_{3}^{*}\), where \({p}_{3}^{*}=\frac{1}{\left(g-1\right)}*\left[\frac{D}{\left(K-D-{R}_{h}\right)}\right]\). Notice that \({p}_{3}^{*}>0\). It means that some firms would find it optimal not to make any investment, should they inherit a probability of success low enough.

Based on the three lemmas, we can define a new quantity \({p}_{1}^{**}=max\left\{{{p}_{1}^{*},{p}_{2}^{*},p}_{3}^{*}\right\}.\) And for \(p>{p}_{1}^{**}\), it is necessary that \(E\left[\pi \left(\mathrm{1,0}\right)\right]=argmax\left\{E\left[\pi \left({I}^{R},{I}^{H}\right)\right]\right\}\). In other words, it means that investing in R&D but not in CRE is the best strategy if the probability of success in R&D is sufficiently high.

Appendix C

Tables 12, 13

Table 12 Different measures of CRE in the previous literature
Table 13 Panel regression with the corporate governance index

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ng, J.C.Y., Leung, C.K.Y. & Chen, S. Corporate Real Estate Holding and Stock Returns: Testing Alternative Theories with International Listed Firms. J Real Estate Finan Econ 68, 74–102 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-022-09931-y

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-022-09931-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation