Skip to main content
Log in

Commission Splits in Real Estate Transactions

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine commission splits between listing and selling agents in real estate transactions. We construct a theoretical model to show that agency problems arise when a listing agent attempts to maximize his or her payoff while setting the commission split. Mitigation to these agency problems can be achieved through the imposition of a limited duration on listing contracts. Our model produces several testable hypotheses, which are supported by empirical evidence. We find property listings with higher list prices and quick sales are associated with lower commission splits. Commission split is more likely to be higher when the listed property has a high degree of atypicality and/or is overpriced. Additionally, agent-owned properties pay higher commission splits.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Because real estate agents usually possess superior information about market values of properties, sellers often consult their agents on setting list prices and on accepting offers. Although real estate agents may not set prices directly, they can persuade sellers to underpriced a property when listing the property and/or attempt to convince sellers to accept low-price offers.

  2. Miceli (1991) suggests that commission splits are unlikely determined solely by sellers. If it were the case, Miceli (1991) shows it would be optimal to give the entire commission to whoever finds a buyer. This solution apparently deviates from current industry practices.

  3. Previous studies adopting a similar bargaining structure include Miceli (1989, 1991) and Rutherford et al. (2005).

  4. We assume that β offered is high enough such that at least one cooperating agent’s participation constraint is satisfied.

  5. To keep the analysis tractable, when modeling the choice of commission split, we treat listing agent’s effort level as given. We acknowledge that the listing agent’s optimal effort choice, in reality, can vary by property, and the chosen effort level may depend on many factors. For example, Rutherford et al. (2005) shows that agents contribute more effort to sell their own properties. Bian et al. (2015) find that greater agent listing inventory dilutes efforts contributed to each listing. Our view is that the listing agent takes into account all relevant factors and first determines the expected effort level, and the expected effort level then serves as the basis for the agent to further choose the level of commission split. In other words, the determination of the optimal effort level is outside the scope of our model.

  6. Through this paper, we use a subscript to denote the derivative with respect to the subscript variable.

  7. Commission splits are certainly affected by many factors other than what we included in our model. For example, if cooperative sale is a repeated game and a listing agent expects to serve as a selling agent in the future, reciprocity may motivate the listing agent to follow the industry norm and offer a commission split that everyone else offers. We have no doubt that reciprocity is influential in determining commission splits. However, reciprocity tends to push commission splits to be homogeneous. Motivated by the observed variation of commission splits observed in our data, we choose to construct a theoretical framework to explain this variation. This is why we omit reciprocity in our model and focus on factors that can explain the variation of commission splits.

  8. We do not explicitly model competition among listing agents in terms of strategically setting the commission split to attract cooperating agents’ attention. We assume effects from such competition are embedded in λ S(β). When the commission split offered is not competitive, λ S is reduced as a result of the lack of interest from cooperating agents.

  9. We do not have exact acreage of lot size in the data. However, when entering data on the MLS, brokers indicate whether or not the lot size is less than or equal to one acre or greater than one acre. Given our sample includes a significant number of properties on farmland, presumably with abnormally large lot sizes, we only include observations with a lot size less than or equal to one acre. Over 65 % of our observations have a lot size less than or equal to one acre.

  10. Commission splits at levels other than 2.5 or 3 % may be associated with non-conventional brokerage arrangements (e.g., discount brokerage). As a robustness check, we estimate an ordinary least square (OLS) model using observations with commission rates at all levels. Our OLS results tell a story very similar to the logit results.

  11. As a robustness check, we also computed the over-pricing measure introduced in Yavas and Yang (1995). Overpricing is captured by the logarithm of the ratio of the predicted sale price to the listing price. This measure is highly correlated with our DOP measure. Our empirical results show similar patterns when it is used instead of DOP.

  12. The Consumer Sentiment Index is developed from the Survey of Consumers, a national survey based on telephonic household interviews. We obtain our CSI data series from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis: http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/UMCSENT.

  13. As a robustness check, we substitute broker fixed effect with agent fixed effect and re-estimate the OLS model. Our results remain qualitatively unchanged.

  14. One possible explanation is that it is harder to sell a property when the owner is a male, and this induces listing agents to offer higher commission splits for male-owned properties.

References

  • Anglin, P. M., & Arnott, R. (1991). Residential real estate brokerage as a principal–agent problem. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 4(2), 99–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, M. A. (1992). The principal–agent relationship in real estate brokerage services. Real Estate Economics, 20(1), 89–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bian, X., Waller, B. D., Turnbull, G. K., & Wentland, S. A. (2015). How many listings are too many? Agent inventory externalities and the residential housing market. Journal of Housing Economics, 28(C), 130–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brastow, R., & Waller, B. D. (2013). Dual agency representation: incentive conflicts or efficiencies? Journal of Real Estate Research, 35(2), 199–222.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clauretie, T. M., & Daneshvary, N. (2008). Principal-agent conflict and broker effort near listing contract expiration: the case of residential properties. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 37(2), 147–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crockett, J. H. (1982). Competition and efficiency in transacting: the case of residential real estate brokerage. Real Estate Economics, 10(2), 209–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, L., & Yavas, A. (2010). A case for percentage commission contracts: the impact of a “Race” among agents. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 40(1), 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gardiner, J., Heisler, H., Kallberg, J. G., & Liu, C. H. (2007). The impact of dual agency. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 35(1), 39–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geltner, D., Kluger, B. D., & Miller, N. G. (1991). Optimal price and selling effort from the perspectives of the broker and seller. Real Estate Economics, 19(1), 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jares, T. E., Larsen, J. E., & Zorn, T. S. (2000). An optimal incentive system for real estate agents. Journal of Real Estate Research, 20(1–2), 44–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S. D., & Syverson, C. (2008). Market distortions when agents are better informed: the value of information in real estate transactions. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(4), 599–611.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levmore, S. (1993). Commissions and conflicts in agency arrangements: lawyers, real estate brokers, underwriters, and other agents’ rewards. Journal of Law and Economics, 36(1), 503–539.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miceli, T. J. (1989). The optimal duration of real estate listing contracts. Real Estate Economics, 17(3), 267–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miceli, T. J. (1991). The multiple listing service, commission splits and broker effort. Real Estate Economics, 19(4), 548–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rutherford, R. C., Springer, T. M., & Yavas, A. (2005). Conflicts between principals and agents: evidence from real estate brokerage. Journal of Financial Economics, 76(3), 627–665.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rutherford, R. C., Springer, T. M., & Yavas, A. (2007). Evidence of information asymmetries in the market for residential condominiums. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 35(1), 22–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Springer, T. M. (1996). Single-family housing transactions: seller motivations, price, and market time. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 13(3), 237–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sykes, A. O. (1993). Some thoughts on the real estate puzzle: comments on levmore, “commissions and conflicts in agency arrangements: lawyers, real estate brokers, underwriters, and other agents’ rewards. Journal of Law and Economics, 36(1993), 541–551.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waller, B. D., Brastow, R., & Johnson, K. H. (2010). Listing contract length and listing contract duration. Journal of Real Estate Research, 32(3), 271–288.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, J. (1998). Agency and brokerage of real estate assets in competitive equilibrium. Review of Financial Studies, 11(2), 239–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yavas, A. (2001). Impossibility of competitive equilibrium in the real estate brokerage industry. Journal of Real Estate Research, 21(3), 187–201.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yavas, A., & Yang, S. (1995). The strategic role of listing prices in marketing real estate: theory and evidence. Real Estate Economics, 23(3), 347–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zorn, T. S., & Larsen, J. E. (1986). The incentive effects of flat-fee and percentage commissions for real estate brokers. Real Estate Economics, 14(1), 24–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Richard Buttimer, Ken Johnson and participants at the American Real Estate Society (ARES) 2012 annual meeting and at the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association (AREUEA) 2013 annual meeting for their helpful comments. Special thanks to the anonymous reviewer who provided constructive and insightful comments that led to significant improvements of our work.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Xun Bian.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bian, X., Waller, B.D. & Yavas, A. Commission Splits in Real Estate Transactions. J Real Estate Finan Econ 54, 165–187 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-015-9541-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-015-9541-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation