1 Introduction

Starting with Jensen and Meckling (1976), a very large literature documents the agency costs of public ownership. One of the less emphasized of these costs is fraud. To enrich themselves, managers who own a relatively small fraction of the stock might be willing to break the law, even when the cost of breaking the law from the company’s point of view exceeds its benefits. Is corporate fraud a major component of the agency costs of public ownership? Should regulation do something to reduce this cost?

Before we even try to answer these questions, we need to establish how pervasive corporate fraud is. Is the fraud we observe the whole iceberg or just its visible tip? The answer to this question requires an estimate of the ratio of the exposed tip to the submerged portion, also known as the detection likelihood. Thus far in the literature, approaches to estimating the detection likelihood (and by implication the hidden prevalence of fraud) have included (i) accounting misconduct prediction models (Beneish 1999; Dechow et al. 2011), (ii) corporate surveys (Dichev et al. 2013), and (iii) structural, partial-observability approaches (Wang 2013; Wang  et al. 2010; Hahn et al. 2016; Zakolyukina 2018). In this paper, we introduce a fourth approach, which relies on a natural experiment: the 2001 demise of Arthur Andersen (AA).

The simple idea is that after the AA demise, former AA clients were subject to vastly increased scrutiny. They found themselves in the spotlight of the media, investment intermediaries, short-sellers, and their internal gatekeepers. In addition, they were forced to seek a different audit firm. Given the extreme cloud of suspicion that was covering AA clients immediately after the Enron scandal exploded (Chaney and Philipich 2002; Krishnamurthy et al. 2006), the new auditors, as well as all other fraud detectors, had strong incentives to uncover any fraud committed by former AA clients. Even if this increased scrutiny does not reveal all the existing fraud, the Kolmogorov axiom of conditional probability allows us to derive an upper-bound (and thereby conservative) estimate of the detection likelihood, which in turn provides us with a lower-bound estimate of the pervasiveness of corporate fraud.

As we explain in Section 2, we use the term “fraud” loosely, since what we measure is some form of misconduct or alleged fraud. To estimate the detection likelihood, we use several different measures. The first measure is auditor-detected securities fraud from Dyck et al. (2010) (hereafter “DMZ”). The second is SEC Accounting and Auditing Enforcement Releases (AAERs) from Dechow et al. (2011). The third is financial misreporting not due to simple clerical errors. The last one is all securities fraud under SEC section 10b-5.

We find that the detection likelihood varies depending on the measure used: 0.29 for auditor-detected securities fraud, 0.34 for accounting restatements, 0.47 for securities fraud at large, and 0.52 for AAERs. All of the estimates are statistically significant and robust to a host of potential omitted differences between the firms audited by Arthur Andersen and the rest (e.g., industry focus, regional variation, and importance of IPOs). Our estimates represent an upper bound of the detection likelihood, which implies that our estimates of unobserved fraud are conservatively low. The best estimate of the detection likelihood is 0.33, with a 95% confidence interval between 0.24 and 0.45.Footnote 1 Fraud is indeed like an iceberg with significant undetected fraud beneath the surface.

With our estimates of the detection likelihood, we can calculate the pervasiveness of corporate fraud as a function of the definition of fraud we adopt. Accounting violations are widespread: in an average year, 41% of companies misrepresent their financial reports, even when we ignore simple clerical errors. Fortunately, securities fraud is less pervasive. In an average year, 10% of all large public corporations commit (alleged) securities fraud, with a 95% confidence interval between 7 and 14%.

Having estimated the pervasiveness of fraud, we can calculate the losses produced by fraud using cost estimates from the prior literature. For detected frauds, we use the decline in equity value at the revelation of the fraud as estimated by Karpoff et al. (2008) (henceforth “KLM”). For undetected frauds, we apply the average value lost due to cover-up, as estimated by Beneish et al. (2013). Combining these detected and undetected fraud losses – 25% and 11% of the equity value, respectively – to the proportion of frauds detected (0.33) and undetected (0.67) results in an average fraud cost of 16% of equity value. Putting together our estimate of the pervasiveness of fraud (10%) with the per-firm cost of fraud (16%), we arrive to an expected annual cost of fraud of 1.6% of the total equity value of US public firms (with a 95% interval between 1.2% and 2.2%). Hence, the annual cost of fraud among US corporations at the end of our sample period (2004) is $254 billion or – bringing our cost calculation forward to 2021 – $830 billion. If we compare the 2004 expected cost of fraud with the $19.9 billion of annual SOX compliance cost (as estimated by Hochberg et al. (2009)), for the benefits of SOX to exceed its costs, SOX would have to reduce the probability of fraud initiation by 1 percentage point (equal to 10% of the baseline probability).

Our paper builds on a large literature seeking to understand the incidence of undetected corporate fraud or misconduct. Beneish (1999) and Dechow et al. (2011) estimate the likelihood of accounting misconduct through patterns in financial disclosure. Wang (2013) uses a bivariate probit to identify factors affecting the propensity to commit fraud and the vulnerability of fraud to detection. Hahn et al. (2016) integrate Wang’s bivariate probit with a flexible Bayesian prior. Finally, Zakolyukina (2018) uses a structural model of earnings manipulation. Instead of relying on statistical or economic models, our approach is based on a natural experiment, with all the pluses and minuses of natural experiments.

Our paper complements Krishnan et al. (2007), who document how after AA’s demise Big Four auditors were more likely to issue a going concern qualification when they audited large former AA clients than when they audited similar non-AA clients. They do not find a similar result for small firms, likely due to a greater rejection of small AA clients with dubious accounting by Big Four auditors. We find that when we look at all auditors (not just Big Four), the revelation of misconduct is more likely in small former AA clients than in similar-sized non-AA clients.

Finally, our paper also builds off the literature seeking to understand the costs associated with corporate fraud, both in direct reputation effects (Karpoff and Lott 1993; KLM) and in cover-up costs of avoidance (Beneish et al. 2013).

The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the data and presents summary statistics on caught frauds. Section 3 explains our methodology. Section 4 presents the detection likelihood and the pervasiveness of corporate fraud results. Section 5 provides estimates of the cost of such fraud, and Sect. 6 concludes.

2 Observed corporate fraud measures and incidence

We start by defining corporate fraud. As one court observed, “The law does not define fraud; it needs no definition; it is as old as falsehood and as versatile as human ingenuity.”Footnote 2 In a similar vein, the Fourth Circuit noted that “fraud is a broad term, which includes false representations, dishonesty and deceit.”Footnote 3 Thus, it is not easy to define corporate fraud precisely. Securities law defines securities fraud as “to make any untrue statement of a material fact or to omit to state a material fact necessary in order to make the statements made, in the light of the circumstances under which they were made, not misleading.”Footnote 4 Since our primary measure derives from securities class actions, we assume that definition and regard corporate fraud primarily as misrepresentation.

In spite of this ambiguity, the established legal practice requires the presence of three elements to label an act of misconduct fraud: misrepresentation, materiality, and intent. As we will explain below, all our measures of misconduct contain an element of misrepresentation. We do our best to set a minimum threshold to ensure materiality. Where we cannot deliver is on intent. Intent can only be proven in court, and all these alleged fraud cases are settled before they reach the final verdict, since directors’ and officers’ insurance does not indemnify executives if they are convicted in court (see, for example, the data and discussion in Black et al. (2006)). As a result, all the corporate fraud we discuss is alleged fraud that was settled out of court.

To capture alleged fraud we resort to four different measures. The first measure is financial misrepresentations exposed by auditors. To construct “auditor-detected fraud,” we start with SEC Rule 10b-5 securities fraud from DMZ’s dataset of class actions suits. To ensure comprehensiveness, DMZ focus on large firms (those with over $750 million in assets) so that a potential payoff from a suit would be sufficiently attractive to mobilize monitoring by legal actors.Footnote 5 To remove frivolous suits, DMZ impose a series of filters, building on the existing legal literature.Footnote 6 The final step is to restrict the DMZ sample to frauds that are revealed directly or indirectly by an auditor. Directly revealed by the auditors are frauds where the auditor in DMZ was the whistleblower. Indirectly revealed by the auditor are frauds where the auditor issued a qualified opinion and the whistleblower in DMZ is either the company itself or an analyst. For these latter cases, we reread the auditor’s qualifying opinion in the DMZ cases where the company itself or an analyst was the whistleblower and dropped two cases where the fraud could not be plausibly related to the reason why the audit opinion was qualified.

The second measure is financial misrepresentation that led to an Accounting and Auditing Enforcement by the SEC, as contained in the AAER dataset created by Dechow et al. (2011). Since 1982, the SEC has issued Accounting and Auditing Enforcement Releases (AAERs) during or at the conclusion of an investigation against a company, an auditor, or an officer for alleged accounting or auditing misconduct. The benefit of this sample is that all AAERs are likely to be material violations, since an AAER release by the SEC is considered a severe step meant to attract attention. Dechow et al. (2011) refer to AAERs as misstatements, “although fraud is often implied by the SEC’s allegations,” because “firms and managers typically do not admit or deny guilt with respect to the SEC allegations.” We will refer to them simply as AAERs.

The main shortcoming of this measure is that the sample may be overly restrictive because the SEC does not have the budget to go after all frauds (e.g., Dechow et al. 1996; Miller 2006). Furthermore, as the SEC website notices, “[AAER] only highlights certain actions and is not meant to be a complete and exhaustive compilation of all of the actions that fall into this category.”Footnote 7 For example, during the period 2001–2014, there were, on average, 54 AAERs per year, versus 220 securities class actions (Soltes 2019).

The third measure does not capture fraud – only restatements. To obtain such a measure, we start from the most widely employed data on restatements: the Audit Analytics database. We then use the Audit Analytics classification to separate clerical errors from intentional implementation of misstatements.

Finally, the fourth measure of fraud is the full set of SEC section 10b-5 securities fraud cases. While all 10b-5 cases arise from some material misstatements or omissions in providing material information, they also include non-auditing-related misrepresentations, like this example from DMZ: “The Department of Justice indicts Sotheby’s for price fixing after a long investigation of the art industry. Shareholders sue the firm for failing to disclose that a large portion of their revenues are being derived from the unsustainable high prices achieved through the pricing arrangement with Christie’s” (DMZ Appendix, 2010). In this example, no accounting violation has occurred, but omitting the economic implications of fixing prices represents an SEC rule 10b-5 violation. In DMZ, 35% of the 10b-5 violations are omissions of information concerning an underlying legal violation, as in the Sotheby’s example. Rather than using the original DMZ set of 10b-5 class actions, we use the updated dataset from the Securities Class Action Clearinghouse, as compiled by Kempf and Spalt (2022). We refer to this measure as SCAC securities fraud, again noting that these are alleged frauds.

Figure 1 plots the fraction of Compustat large US corporations engaged in (alleged) fraud or misconduct (henceforth, for simplicity, “fraud”) according to the various measures. The data are monthly from 1997 to 2005, and a company is classified as committing a fraud during a certain month if that month falls within the fraud period determined after detection. When the measure we use is accounting restatements, the fraction of firms involved in fraud is large (on average 13% per year, plotted with magnitudes on the right axis) and increasing over time (which might reflect the increased complexity of the accounting rules). All the other measures of misconduct produce a much lower incidence – between 1 and 4% of firms (plotted with magnitudes on the left axis) – with a pronounced hump shape centered around the turn of the millennium. This pattern is consistent with Wang et al. (2010), who find that firms start fraud more in booms because monitoring is lower and the managerial reward from cheating is higher.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Frequency of Observed Corporate Fraud. We plot the prevalence rates of corporate fraud, for cases of corporate fraud that are eventually caught. The magnitudes represent the percentage of all US large public corporations committing corporate fraud that are caught. Auditor-detected frauds are frauds in the DMZ sample of SEC 10(b) securities class actions which were triggered by an auditor, either by an auditor resignation or by the auditor issuing a qualified opinion and either the firm or analysts revealing the fraud. Restatements are from AuditAnalytics and refer to restatements triggered by accounting misapplication. AAERs are the SEC investigation releases used in Dechow et al. (2011). The sample SCAC securities fraud is from Kempf and Spalt (2022). Restatements are plotted with magnitudes on the right axis

3 Methodology: inferring the detection likelihood using the Arthur Andersen experiment

3.1 Experiment overview

Figure 1 depicts the incidence of corporate frauds that are eventually caught. Our main agenda is to estimate what percentage of initiated frauds are caught. We refer to this percentage as the detection likelihood.

Our methodology relies on two key ingredients – the Kolmogorov axiom of conditional probability and the Arthur Andersen natural experiment. The pervasiveness of corporate fraud is the probability of a firm engaging in fraud (denoted F), regardless of whether it is caught or not: \(Pr\left(F\right)\). What we observe instead is the joint event of a firm engaging in fraud and being caught: \(\bf Pr\left(\boldsymbol{F},\boldsymbol{caught}\right)\). (We will use the convention of bolding the variables we observe.) By the law of conditional probability, the unconditional probability of engaging in a fraud can be written as:

$$\Pr (F)=\frac{{\mathbf{Pr}}\left(\boldsymbol{F},\kern0.25em \boldsymbol{caught}\right)}{{Pr}\left( caught| F\right)}$$
(1)

Thus, if we knew the denominator, \({{Pr}}\left(caught | F\right)\), we could calculate \({Pr}\left(F\right).\)  

Our experiment derives an upper bound of \({{Pr}}\left(caught | F\right)\) and thus a lower bound of \({Pr}\left(F\right)\) by comparing the frequency of revealed fraud in “normal” times with the frequency of revealed fraud in a sample where scrutiny increased substantially. In our experiment, the sample of firms under enhanced scrutiny is the set of Arthur Andersen (AA) clients after the AA demise following the Enron scandal. On October 22, 2001, Enron acknowledged an SEC inquiry concerning possible conflicts of interest in various partnerships (Barton 2005). On November 23, 2001, the New York Times ran an article with the headline “From Sunbeam to Enron: Andersen’s Reputation Suffers.” Thus, we assume that the period of enhanced scrutiny started after November 30, 2001, a date to which we refer as “the watershed date.”Footnote 8 Since roughly one-fifth of all large publicly traded firms had AA as their auditor in 2001, this event provides a natural experiment of increased scrutiny of firms. We look at the revelation of fraud that started being perpetrated before the watershed date. Thus, we can ignore any deterrence effect, since the enhanced scrutiny produced by Enron’s crisis was unexpected.

One source of the increased scrutiny is the new auditors (Chen and Zhou 2007). Kealey et al. (2007) find that the audit fees charged by AA successors to AA former clients when they switched after Enron are positively related to the length of AA tenure with those clients, suggesting that there is a perceived risk associated with AA clients that needs to be mitigated with additional monitoring. This enhanced scrutiny is also consistent with Nagy’s (2005) finding that smaller ex-AA clients have lower discretionary accruals after switching to a new auditor.

Nevertheless, new auditors are not the only source of enhanced scrutiny. As Chaney and Philipich (2002) and Krishnamurthy et al. (2006)) show, after the Enron scandal exploded, all AA clients came under a cloud of suspicion. Investment intermediaries and internal gatekeepers of AA clients had stronger incentives to scrutinize their firms thoroughly to clear them of the shadow of suspicion. Likewise, short sellers and the media had special incentives to focus their attention on AA clients in search for the next big scandal.

3.2 Identification Assumption 1: AA firms are not different in 1998–2000

Our first assumption is that in the period before AA’s demise (1998–2000), fraud \(\left(F\right)\) was equally likely in AA firms and non-AA firms \(\left(\overline{AA }\right)\)Footnote 9:

  • Assumption 1: \(Pr\left(\left.F \right| \overline{AA }\right)=Pr\left(\left.F \right| AA\right)\)

AA’s indictment by the Department of Justice and its initial conviction for obstruction of justice may make this a surprising assumption. Yet, the initial conviction of AA was for obstruction of justice, not for being a bad auditor, and it was unanimously overturned upon appeal.

More convincingly, the accounting literature has concluded that there was no difference between AA and other auditors in terms of auditing rigor. In a matched sample, Agrawal and Chada (2005) find that the existence of AA as the auditor is not associated with firms having more restatements. Likewise, controlling for client size, region, time, and industry, Eisenberg and Macey (2004) find that AA clients did not perform any better or worse than other firms. Nevertheless, we retest this assumption for assurance and because our sample of large US corporations is different from the aforementioned studies.

Table 1 reports summary statistics comparing the characteristics and industry of AA clients and non-AA clients during the period 1998–2000. The firms in the set are large (> $750 million in assets) US corporations with data in Compustat. We identify auditors using the Compustat “AU” item, mapping the auditor who signs a financial statement to the calendar month-year of the report. We use two sets of non-AA clients: all non-AA clients and the subset of all non-AA clients that are audited by another of the Big Five audit firms. Statistics are collapsed to one observation per firm over the time period. A firm appears in multiple columns only if it switches auditors. Because of auditor transitions and firms’ delisting during the three-year period, the sample of AA firms is larger than in the subsequent tables, where we require a firm to be audited by AA in 2001.

Table 1 Statistics: Arthur Andersen Clients (AA) and Non-AA Clients, 1998–2000

Panel A reports that AA clients are statistically similar to other Big Five clients in assets, sales, and EBITDA, but have higher leverage (long term debt-to-assets). The leverage difference suggests a difference in industry composition, which is what we present in Panel B. For example, compared to Big Five auditors that are not AA, AA has at least 2 percentage points fewer clients in the industries of Banks & Insurance, Retail & Wholesale, and Computers, and 2 percentage points more clients in Utilities, Refining & Extractive, Communication & Transport, and Services & Healthcare. We return to these industry compositional differences in our empirical specifications.

Were AA clients more fraudulent? In Table 2, we consider this question using eight measures of fraud, collapsed to one observation per firm for the 1998–2000 period before AA’s demise (allowing, as before, a firm to have two observations if it switched to or from AA in this period). For the discrete variables of caught fraud – auditor-caught frauds, AAERs, restatements, and SCAC securities fraud – we define a fraud event if the event ever occurs in the three-year period. Thus, to compare the detected fraud in this table to detected frauds in Fig. 1 (and to those in the subsequent tables), we need to divide the reported number by three. In addition to these measures of fraud, we include measures of fraud likelihood based on a continuous measure from the accounting literature. We include both the probability of accounting manipulation score, ProbM (Beneish 1999),Footnote 10 and the probability of fraud score, FScore (Dechow et al. 2011).Footnote 11 Following Beneish (1999) and Dechow et al. (2011), we also consider a discrete version of the ProbM and FScore in the form of a threshold dummy variable, with the authors considering a firm above the threshold as indicating a strong likelihood of the firm’s being a manipulator.

Table 2 Did Arthur Andersen clients exhibit excess corporate fraud in the pre-period of 1998—2000?

Panel A of Table 2 reports that for all eight measures of fraud, AA clients are never more likely to be committing fraud. In fact, based on the measures from the accounting literature, AA clients show lower scores, indicating that they are less likely to be committing fraud. These results do not account for the above-mentioned leverage and industry differences.

In Panel B, Table 2, we report estimates from multivariate estimations of fraud likelihood using accounting literature measures of probM, the indicator probM > -2.2, FScore, and the indicator FScore > 1.4. For each estimation, our variable of interest is an AA dummy, and we include a set of controls for size (log assets and sales/assets), debt (LT Debt/Assets), and profitability (EBITDA/Sales). When we estimate the threshold models (columns 3, 6, 9, and 12), we estimate via logit instead of OLS. All columns include year fixed effects. Columns 2, 3, 5, 6, 8, 9, 11, and 12 include industry fixed effects (where the industries are those of Table 1). Columns 2, 5, 8, and 11 include industry*year fixed effects. (We do not include this further interaction for the logit, as the estimation does not consistently converge uniquely.) In columns 4–6 and 10–12, we restrict the non-AA firms to Big Five accounting firm clients only.

Across all specifications, the coefficient on the AA dummy is never positive and significant. In columns 1 and 3, the AA dummy is negative and significant (i.e., AA firms are associated with less probability of manipulation). Being an AA client does not significantly affect the positive likelihood of manipulation or fraud in the pre-demise period.

In Panel C, we repeat these tests using, as dependent variables, auditor-caught fraud, AAERs, restatements, and SCAC securities fraud. In all even-numbered specifications, we control for industry crossed with year fixed effects, except for auditor-detected fraud (whose small sample forces us to include only industry fixed effects). As in Panel B, the coefficient on the AA dummy is never positive and significant.

Krishnan and Visvanathan (2009) find that earnings management was more pronounced in the AA Houston office than in the Houston offices of other Big Five auditors. Since Enron was headquartered in Houston, this is not that surprising. Nevertheless, to address the concern that in certain regions AA-audited firms may have been more likely to commit fraud, in Appendix Table A1, we restrict our sample to large corporations located in the state of Texas. For each AA client, we find a match among other Big Five clients within the two-digit SIC code, based on a propensity score to be an AA client. We generate the propensity score based on assets, sales, EBITDA, and leverage within industry. In Table A1 (columns 1 and 2), the dependent variable is the ProbM score. An AA dummy variable (equal to one for an AA client) is not significant either in the Texas sample (Panel A) or in the United States sample (Panel B). Across the remaining columns, we repeat the same tests using other measures of uncaught (FScore) and caught fraud (auditor-caught fraud, AAERs, restatements, and SCAC securities fraud). The results are unchanged. We find no evidence that AA clients are statistically or economically different from other auditors’ clients, consistent with Assumption 1.

3.3 Identification Assumption 2

Our methodology is based on the assumption that after the watershed date, AA clients were subject to an enhanced level of scrutiny not only by the new auditors but also by gatekeepers, short sellers, investment intermediaries, and the media. This assumption implies that \(Pr\left(\left.caught\right| F, AA\right)>Pr\left(\left.caught\right| F, \overline{AA }\right).\) While we cannot test this inequality directly, the hypothesis is consistent with the decline in the stock price of AA clients at the announcement of AA’s problems (Chaney and Philipich 2002) and indictment (Krishnamurthy et al. 2006). Furthermore, as we will show in Table 3, this inequality is true in the data for all our measures of fraud.

To obtain a point estimate on the amount of undetected fraud, we further assume:

  • Assumption 2: \(Pr\left(\left.caught\right| F, AA\right)=1\).

When it comes to purely financial fraud or financial restatements, Assumption 2 may be plausible since this was the fraud discovered in Enron (and later in WorldCom) and since this is the type of fraud every gatekeeper was fearful of missing. However, when we use, as a measure of fraud, all SCAC cases (including for instance price fixing), the level of alertness was less. The reason is that some of the detectors with enhanced incentives (like the new auditors) have no role in uncovering these types of fraud. Thus, for some types of fraud, it is more likely that \(Pr\left(\left.caught\right| F, AA\right)>Pr\left(\left.caught\right| F, \overline{AA }\right)\), but \(Pr\left(\left.caught\right| F, AA\right)<1.\) When this is the case – as we explain below – our estimate will yield an upper bound of the detection likelihood and a lower bound on the amount of undetected fraud.

In some cases – Kohlbeck et al. (2009) estimate that the number is 25% – AA clients switched audit firms but not audit partners. The former AA engagement partner moved to another audit firm, bringing the account. This continued relationship might reduce the new auditor’s willingness to “clean the dirty laundry”; yet it is hard to imagine that such relationships will completely eliminate the power of the experiment. Speaking about a firm that went from AA to Grant Thornton, the CEO of Grant Thornton testified at trial that “we converted it to a Grant Thornton audit approach and Grant Thornton audit-quality controls, and we had other people review the engagement.”Footnote 12 Thus, even when the audit partner remains the same, the new audit firm performs an extra screening.

A more general concern is that the increased attention on corporate fraud that followed the Enron and WorldCom scandals might have prompted the SEC (or the other auditors not affected by the turnover) to become more active in detecting fraud. In the limit, if this enhanced scrutiny exposed all fraud in all firms, there will be no difference between the amount of fraud revealed in AA clients and the amount of fraud revealed in clients of other audit firms, invalidating our experiment. Yet, as long as some enhanced scrutiny affects all firms but AA firms are affected more, our methodology will work, but will underestimate undetected fraud. Thus, our results should be interpreted as a lower bound on the pervasiveness of fraud.

Finally, the AA demise was completely unexpected, so it could not have altered the ex ante incentives to commit fraud. In this sense, it is different from a mandatory turnover, which is anticipated.

3.4 Conditional probabilities within the AA experiment

With Assumptions 1 and 2 in hand, we can use the law of conditional probability to derive an estimator for the detection likelihood of fraud. If we write down two versions of Eq. (1) (one for AA and one for non-AA), bringing the denominators to the other side and dividing one by the other, we have a relationship that puts only observable detections of fraud on the right-hand side:

$$\frac{Pr\left(\left.caught\right|F,\overline{AA}\right)\cdot Pr\left(\left.F\right|\overline{AA}\right)}{Pr\left(\left.caught\right|F,AA\right)\cdot Pr\left(\left.F\right|AA\right)}=\frac{\mathbf{Pr\left(\left.F,caught\right|\overline{AA}\right)}}{\mathbf{Pr\left(\left.F,caught\right|AA\right)}}.$$
(2)

Substituting Assumptions 1 and 2 into the left-hand side of Eq. (2) implies:

$$Pr\left(\left.caught\right|F,\overline{AA}\right)=\frac{\mathbf{Pr\left(\left.F,caught\right|\overline{AA}\right)}}{\mathbf{Pr\left(\left.F,caught\right|AA\right)}}.$$
(3)

Since the normal level of scrutiny is the one experienced by non-AA clients, \({Pr}\left(\left.caught\right|F,\overline{AA }\right)=\)  \({Pr}\left(\left.caught\right|F\right)\). Thus, Eq. (3) provides an estimator for the detection likelihood of fraud that is based solely on two observables: the emergence of fraud in non-AA firms and the emergence of fraud in former AA firms.

Note that to the extent that not all fraud emerges in former AA clients (Assumption 2 becomes \(Pr\left(\left.caught\right| F, AA\right)<1\)), then our estimate \(Pr\left( F\right)\) of the pervasiveness of fraud represents a lower bound of the real amount of fraud. To see this, consider that

$$Pr(F)=\frac{\mathbf{ Pr(F,caught)}}{Pr(\left.caught\right| F)}>\frac{\mathbf{Pr(F,caught)}}{{Pr(\left.caught\right| F)}},$$
(4)

where the inequality derives from (3) and \(Pr\left(\left.caught\right| F, AA\right)<1\)).

Note also that we derive the detection likelihood by comparing fraud detection in two groups (former AA clients and non-AA clients) at the same time. Thus, this estimate should not be affected by fluctuations in the probability of committing fraud, as long as these fluctuations are similar in the two groups. Yet, these fluctuations will matter for the level of fraud pervasiveness at any point in time, since this is likely to vary over the business cycle as shown by Wang et al. (2010).

3.5 Empirical methodology

Having explained why the detection likelihood given in Eq. (3) is the number we want to estimate, we now describe how we will estimate it. For each company, we observe whether fraud is discovered during the so-called detection period, both for companies that were AA clients and for companies that were not. This experiment can be thought of as a sum of Bernoulli trials, which can be modeled using a Poisson probability distribution, where the mean \(\lambda\) is the proportion of firms discovered as fraudulent per unit of time. The maximum likelihood estimate of \(\lambda\) in a Poisson distribution is simply the frequency of fraud during the detection period. To facilitate a system estimation (see below), we will estimate this mean \(\lambda\) with a Poisson regression, where \(E\left(Y|X\right)=\lambda ={e}^{\theta x}\).

In this framework, the object of our interest (i.e., the detection likelihood (\(Pr\left(\left.caught\right|F,\overline{AA}\right)=\frac{\mathbf{Pr\left(\left.F,caught\right|\overline{AA}\right)}}{\mathbf{Pr\left(\left.F,caught\right|AA\right)}}\)) is simply the relative risk (RR) of a firm being caught committing a fraud if it is not an AA former client versus if it is an AA former client. Thus, the detection likelihood is simply the ratio of the frequency of fraud in the two samples. Given the paucity of fraud observations, we compute the exact p-values of this ratio in finite samples. Following Agresti (1992), we do so by enumerating all possible draws in the sample and then computing the frequency of outcomes that are at least as different from the null hypothesis as the one observed.

4 Results

The timing of the experiment is as follows. We define a company as having AA as an auditor if AA signed a financial report anytime in the calendar year 2001, irrespective of the firm’s fiscal year. All companies without AA as auditor during this period are non-AA clients. We consider that a fraud was revealed during the detection period if the fraud started before the watershed date of November 30, 2001, and came to light between the watershed date and the end of 2003 (the detection period). Note that our estimates are obtained from the ratio of the fraud caught in AA and non-AA firms. Thus, as long as the amount of fraud committed in AA and non-AA clients responds to cyclical fluctuations in a similar fashion, our estimates are not affected by business cycle fluctuations in the aggregate level of fraud, an important phenomenon documented by Wang et al. (2010).

The count of observations is shown at the bottom of Table 3, Panel A. The natural experiment includes 353 AA clients in the pre-period who survive at least one year in the post-period, and 2,404 non-AA client firms. The number of detected fraud events depends on the fraud measure: 168 restatements, 63 SCACs, 59 AAERs, and 21 auditor-detected fraud.

4.1 Detection likelihood results

Table 3, Panel A reports the main detection likelihood estimates across the four fraud measures – auditor-detected fraud, AAERs, restatements, and SCAC securities fraud. For each of these measures, the estimated coefficient of the Poisson regression we report is the coefficient of a dummy variable equal to one if a company was a former AA client. Thus, if former AA clients have an average frequency of fraud of \({\lambda }_{AA}={e}^{{\theta }_{AA}x}\) and non-AA clients have an average frequency of fraud of \({\lambda }_{N}={e}^{{\theta }_{N}x}\), the estimated coefficient we report is \({\theta }_{AA}-{\theta }_{N}\). Since the detection likelihood ratio is nothing but \(\frac{{\lambda }_{N}}{{\lambda }_{AA}}=\frac{{e}^{{\theta }_{N}}}{{e}^{{\theta }_{AA}}}={e}^{{\theta }_{N}-{\theta }_{AA}}\), we obtain the detection likelihood ratio as \(\frac{1}{{e}^{{\theta }_{AA}-{\theta }_{N}}}\), or the inverse of e raised it to the power of the estimated coefficient. We report both the asymptotic and the exact p-values for the hypothesis that the detection likelihood is equal to 1.

Table 3 Detection likelihood estimates

As we can see in Panel A of Table 3, the hypothesis that the detection likelihood is bigger or equal to 1 is rejected at least at the 10% level in all four measures and in three out of four cases at the 5% level or better. These findings verify the assumption that after the demise of AA more frauds are caught in AA firms than in non-AA firms (\(Pr\left({\text{caught}}|F|AA\right)>Pr\left({{caught}}|F|\overline{AA }\right)\)).

More specifically, when we look at auditor-detected fraud, the estimated detection likelihood is 0.29, which is different from 1 at the 3% level. For AAERs, the detection likelihood estimate is 0.52, different from 1 at the 7% level. The detection likelihood estimate for accounting violations is 0.34, different from one at the 0.1% level. For the SCAC securities fraud measure, the detection likelihood is 0.47, different from 1 at the 2% level.Footnote 13 In sum, despite the different sources and the different definitions of fraud, there is a clear result: a substantial amount of corporate fraud remains undetected. With detection likelihood between 29 and 52%, there is indeed an iceberg of undetected fraud that ranges between 48 and 71% of total fraud.

If we want to move beyond this simple result and estimate more precisely the amount of undetected fraud, we need to pool together all the possible observations toward the estimation of a single detection likelihood. This is what we do in Table 3, Panel B. The first column reports the estimates obtained by estimating simultaneously the four Poisson regressions, with the restriction that the coefficient should be the same in all four. When we pool the four measures of fraud, the estimated detection likelihood is 0.38, with a 95% confidence interval between 0.30 and 0.49. Thus, we can say with 95% confidence that between 51 and 70% of all fraud is undetected.

These estimates of undetected fraud are downward biased because Assumption 2 (that after the Enron scandal all the fraud in former AA firms was revealed) is unlikely to be satisfied. This is true for all the measures, but particularly so for SCACs and AAERs. The SCAC securities fraud measure includes frauds that are not misrepresentation of accounting information but rather failures to disclose material information. It is unlikely that the additional scrutiny triggered by the AA demise would expose all these failure-to-disclose cases. In such cases, the experiment design implies that 0.47 detection likelihood is only an upper bound (biasing downward the proportion of undetected fraud). Similarly, the detection of an AAER-type of fraud depends on the willingness of the SEC to bring an enforcement action. In any economic analysis of crime and punishment (see Becker 1968), the SEC’s incentives to bring a case against a defunct firm like AA are small. Thus, the 0.52 AAER estimate is also likely an upper bound.

By contrast, Assumption 2 is more likely to hold for misconducts that auditors are more likely to catch, such as accounting restatements and auditor-detected fraud. Thus, in column 2 of Table 3, Panel B, we report the detection likelihood estimate obtained by pooling together only the two fraud measures for which Assumption 2 is more likely to hold. The estimated detection likelihood is 0.33, with a 95% confidence interval of 0.24–0.45. Thus, only one-third of corporate fraud is detected, and the total amount of corporate fraud is three times the corporate fraud that is observed. In the rest of the paper we will treat this as our best point estimate, with a 95% confidence interval that the total amount of fraud is between 2.2 and 4.1 times the fraud observed.

4.2 Detection likelihood robustness

4.2.1 Small firms

Krishnan et al. (2007) document that Big Four auditors were much more likely to issue a going concern qualification in their audits of large former AA clients than in their audits of large non-former AA clients (specifically, 5.6% versus 2.3%). In our experiment, this ratio would imply a detection likelihood of 0.41, quite consistent with our results. Yet, Krishnan et al. (2007) find the opposite for small firms: former AA clients received less than half of the going concern opinions of non-AA clients (6.2% to 14.5%). As the authors recognize, this difference in the results for large and small firms is driven by sample selection. Krishnan et al (2007) restrict their attention to AA firms that are subsequently audited by Big Four auditors. It is likely that Big Four auditors accept all the large former AA clients but only the best of the small ones, leaving the rest to less prestigious auditors. In this paper we can test this conjecture by looking at all former AA clients, not just those subsequently audited by a Big Four auditor. To do so, however, we need to expand the sample to small firms.

Table 4, Panel A reproduces our detection likelihood estimation setup for smaller public corporations – those that were never over $750 million in assets in the pre-period years. We run the experiment in the same setup as Table 3. Since DMZ does not collect auditor-detected data for small firms, the first measure of misconduct is not available for this sample.

Table 4 Detection Likelihood Robustness: Small Corporations & Placebo

We find, in Panel A, that for all three measures the detection likelihood is less than 1 and that for two out of three measures the detection likelihood is significantly less than 1 at the 1% level. This analysis, suggested by an anonymous referee, provides an out-of-sample validation of our methodology to use the AA-forced turnover to identify misconduct that generally remains undetected.

For the AAER and restatement measures, the detection likelihood estimates obtained using small firms in Table 4 are very similar to the ones obtained using large firms and reported in Table 3: 0.64 versus 0.52 for AAERs and 0.42 versus 0.34 for restatements. By contrast, for securities fraud cases, the detection likelihood falls drastically from 0.47 (large firms) to 0.29 (smaller firms). Most likely, this drop is due to the fact that the probability of a class action suit among small non-AA clients is only 0.5%, versus the 2% observed in large firms. This is hardly surprising. The main reason why DMZ restrict their sample to large companies is that the discovery of a fraud will always lead to a class action suit in large companies, where there is plenty of money to pay the lawyers, but not necessarily in small companies. Thus, the lower detection likelihood reflects a real difference between large and small companies: more fraud goes undetected in small companies.

4.2.2 Placebo

It is possible that AA clients were in businesses intrinsically more prone to corporate fraud or its detection. One way to help to rule out this possibility is to observe these firms in a different time period and check that they are not behaving differently. To this purpose, we reproduce the same experiment comparing former AA and non-AA clients (minus a few firms that do not survive) in the two years after the detection period (i.e., 2004–2006) and measure fraud detection in these years. Since the enhanced scrutiny following the demise of AA cannot last forever, we regard this exercise as a placebo test. This placebo period coincides with the beginning of the implementation of SOX. A large literature has tried to establish what the effects of the introduction of SOX are (see Coates and Srinivasan (2014)). Our test, however, is unaffected by any impact of SOX, since it compares the detection rate in former AA clients and former non-AA clients at the same time.

Table 4, Panel B reports the results. The percentage of firms caught committing fraud is very similar between former AA clients and former non-AA clients (detection likelihood estimates for all three measures are not different from 1), suggesting that there is not a natural proclivity of former AA clients to commit more fraud. In addition, the similarity between the fraud revealed in AA and non-AA clients suggests that the enhanced disclosure of fraud during the treatment period is not just an acceleration of the discovery that would have taken place regardless, but a net increase in discovery.

4.2.3 Industry and geography

In Sect. 3.2, we showed that AA had more clients in Communications & Transport, Refining & Extractive, Services & Healthcare, and Utilities, and fewer clients in Banks & Insurance, Retail & Wholesale, and Computers. If, for unspecified reasons, corporate fraud was more prevalent among sectors in which AA was overrepresented just prior to the detection period and not afterward, then our detection likelihood estimate could be biased. To address this concern, we report the detection likelihood estimates in various subsamples that remove industries where AA was either overrepresented or underrepresented. (Appendix Table A2, Panels B and C report the industry and regional distribution of fraud for all the fraud measures.) As Table 5, Panel A shows, the detection likelihoods remain substantially unchanged.

Table 5 Detection Likelihood Robustness: Industry and Region Subsampling

The same concern could arise from regional variation in AA clients. For this reason, in Table 5, Panel B, we repeat the same exercise excluding some regions or some large states. Once again, the detection likelihood results appear stable.

4.3 Pervasiveness of corporate fraud results

We now can use the detection likelihood estimates in Eq. (1), \({Pr}\left(F\right)=\)  \(\frac{\boldsymbol P\boldsymbol r\mathbf{\left({F,caught}\right)}}{Pr\left(\left.caught\right|F\right)}\), to estimate the overall pervasiveness of corporate fraud. The numerator in Eq. (1) is the observable incidence of fraud that is caught. The denominator in Eq. (1) is the detection likelihood. Table 6 reports observed caught frequencies in Panel A, detection likelihood estimates from Table 3 in Panel B, a baseline estimate of the pervasiveness of fraud across the measures of misconduct and alleged fraud in Panel C, and a best estimate of the pervasiveness of fraud across the measures of misconduct and alleged fraud using the best estimate detection likelihood in Panel D. Since AA firms during the detection period are assumed to have a probability of detection equal to one, we exclude them from Panel A, which computes the frequency of caught frauds under normal circumstances.

Table 6 How Pervasive Is Corporate Fraud?

Focusing first on Panel A, recall that Fig. 1 showed that observed incidences of misconduct vary widely depending on the definition of corporate fraud and the time period of reference. Since fraud may be cyclical (Wang et al. 2010), we do not want to rely on a specific point in time, instead preferring to estimate pervasiveness over a full cycle of boom and bust years. The start in January 1998 and the end point in December 2005 are each almost exactly halfway through the respective expansion periods; thus the period covers one full business cycle from mid-point to mid-point.Footnote 14

Panel A reports that auditor-detected securities frauds hover around 1%, with a peak of 1.1% in 2000–2001. AAER investigations average 2.6%, with a peak of 3.5% in 2000–2001 and a trough of 2.0% in 1998–99. Accounting violations measured by non-clerical restatements average 13.5% during the entire sample period, with a peak of 18.3% in 2002–2003 and a trough of 7.2% in 1998–1999. The broader SCAC securities fraud averages 3.4%, with a peak of 4.8% in 2000–2001 and a trough of 2.3% in 2004–2005.

Using these observed misconduct averages in Panel A and detection likelihood estimates from Table 3 reproduced in Panel B, Table 6, Panel C reports estimates of the pervasiveness of fraud. A concern with Panel C is that, as we discussed with regard to Table 3, some of the detection likelihood estimates are clearly more biased than others. The biases are always conservative, but they do not help with the precision of our fraud pervasiveness estimates. In particular, our experimental design of using AA’s demise has the most power to identify the whole iceberg of hidden fraud (Assumption 2 holding as an equality) for auditor-detected securities fraud and restatements, as opposed to AAERs and the broader SCAC securities fraud cases, since no matter how rigorous the monitoring of the new auditors is, they will find it difficult to identify cases of price fixing such as Sotheby’s. Thus, the best estimate detection likelihood is based on the pooled detection likelihood of auditor-detected and restatement measures, or 0.33, as highlighted before. We use this detection likelihood to calculate the best estimate of corporate misconduct across all of our fraud measures in Panel D.

Our findings as to the pervasiveness of corporate fraud depend on the measure of misconduct we use. We find that in any year averaged across the business cycle, 2.5% of large corporations are committing severe financial misreporting that auditors can detect. Auditor-detected securities fraud is a subcategory of SCAC alleged securities fraud; thus, it is not surprising that it has a low frequency. Such a measure is interesting for the detection likelihood estimation, given that it maps well to our AA demise design, but of more interest to speak to fraud at large are the SCAC securities frauds.

We find that, during an average year over the business cycle, 10% of large corporations are committing a misrepresentation, an information omission, or another misconduct that can lead to an alleged securities fraud claim settled for at least $3 million (with a 95% confidence interval between 7 and 14%). This result from the SCAC data is our main estimate of the pervasiveness of corporate fraud, since SCAC cases are indeed (alleged) securities fraud. By using the AAER measure, we arrive at similar estimates: 8% of fraud pervasiveness, with a 95% confidence interval range of 6%-11%. This magnitude is similar to the SCAC estimate, even though AAERs have lower observed frequencies because their existence requires the SEC to act. (Recall that the SEC failed to act on Madoff despite six substantive complaints.Footnote 15)

Accounting violations, less severe than alleged securities fraud, are more prevalent, with an average annual pervasiveness of 41% (95% confidence interval between 30 and 55%). We do not want to conclude from this estimate that each year 41% of large corporations commit a severe misreporting. To reach this conclusion we would need some more substantive filters to eliminate inconsequential misreporting. Nevertheless, this estimate does not bode well for the US auditing system. In spite of all the regulation, roughly half of the US financial statements suffer from misreporting more serious than pure clerical errors.

4.3.1 Comparison with pervasiveness estimates in the literature

Taking the estimate of 10% as our main estimate of the pervasiveness of corporate fraud, we now ask how our estimates lines up with the literature. As the summary reported below shows, our estimate is at the low end of the pervasiveness of corporate fraud found in the literature. This is not surprising, since if Assumption 2 is violated, our estimate represents a lower bound.

We begin with evidence concerning the appetite for corporate misdoing for personal gain. Prior to Lie (2005), the existence of the options backdating practice had not been understood, and thus firms wanting to commit fraud in this manner could do so with little detection threat. Bebchuk et al. (2010) look back over the pre-2005 period and identify the percentage of publicly traded firms from 1996 to 2005 in which CEOs or directors were “lucky” in that they received option grants on the day of the month when the stock price was the lowest. By their estimate, 12% of firms had such lucky CEOs, suggesting that the appetite for fraudulent behavior was present in at least 12% of firms.

That at least 12% of firms are committing some fraud is supported also by survey evidence and accounting prediction models. Dichev et al. (2013) survey 169 CFOs of public companies and find that 18% of firms manage earnings to misrepresent performance. Beneish et al. (2013) build a model, based on Beneish (1999), that out of sample was able to predict successfully 71% of the most important accounting violations. They apply this model to estimate the pervasiveness of accounting manipulation and find that 18% of firms are fraudulent each year during the period 1997–2005.

How do the structural approaches to modelling the hidden iceberg of corporate misconduct line up with the evidence reported thus far? Wang et al. (2010) examine financial fraud among the 3,297 IPOs from 1995 to 2005. While their main goal is to show that fraud is procyclical, their bivariate probit model produces predicted probabilities of engaging in fraud of 10%-15%, very much in line with our estimates.Footnote 16 Similarly, in their flexible Bayesian priors approach to partial observability, Hahn et al. (2016) estimate a pervasiveness of SEC-investigated accounting misconduct of 15%. Zakolyukina (2018) uses a structural model to explore detected and undetected GAAP manipulation (more in line with our accounting violation measure) and reports that 73% of CEOs manipulate their financials, with a detection likelihood of only 0.06.

5 How expensive is corporate fraud?

5.1 Expected cost of fraud

The finding that 10% of large corporations are committing fraud does not necessarily imply that the economic cost of fraud is large. To draw this conclusion, we need to estimate the cost of these corporate frauds. We do not innovate here, but rely on existing estimates of the cost of fraud. As in the prior literature, we focus on the cost of fraud borne by equity holders of firms involved in fraud, ignoring other potential losses (e.g., loss in debt value, loss of employee pensions and jobs, loss of supplier payables, loss of customer prepayments, loss of taxes owed, professional fees and administrative expenses for firms in bankruptcy) and spillover costs borne by competitors (e.g., Bower and Gilson 2003). In this sense, the equity cost estimates provide a lower bound on costs from a social welfare perspective.Footnote 17 We build our calculations off two prior papers.

Using an event-study methodology, KLM estimate the reputational loss of detected fraud at 25% of the equity value of a fraudulent firm. This cost, which is almost entirely due to a loss in reputation, represents the present value of the decline in expected cash flows as firms’ investors, suppliers, and customers change the terms on which they interact with a fraudulent firm.

KLM’s cost estimates are for detected fraud and do not necessarily apply to undetected fraud. Even when a fraud is not yet in the public domain, the firm incurs costs for two reasons. First, the fraud is unlikely to remain a secret for customers and employees, who will seek business relationships or employment elsewhere, demand a premium to remain, or take advantage of the fraud themselves. For example, Bernie Madoff’s employees like Frank Di Pasquale were lavishly paid to ensure their silence. In addition, they stole money for themselves.Footnote 18 Second, the biggest cost is often the cover-up. For 20 years, the Japanese company Olympus was able to hide a $730 million financial loss from 1990 with a series of bad acquisitions and accounting tricks. The bad acquisitions alone cost $300 million.Footnote 19

It is hard to put a number on these costs. Yet, if we assume that, at least in the medium term, the stock market is strong-form efficient, the abnormal low returns of companies that are likely to have committed a fraud but were never exposed as fraudulent can provide an estimate of these hidden costs. Beneish et al. (2013) perform this exercise. They compare the annual buy-and-hold return of firms with a high probM score with that of firms with a low probM score. After controlling for a four-factor model, they estimate an annual 10.9% difference in returns. We take this underperformance as an estimate of the costs of undetected fraud.Footnote 20

We are now in the position to compute the total cost of fraud. Our estimates suggest that 10% of firms are committing fraud. If the detected fraud (representing 33% of cases) costs the firm 25% of market value and the undetected fraud (representing 67% of cases) costs 10.9%, then the cost of an average fraud is 15.6% of firms’ market capitalization. Thus, the cost of fraud is 1.6% of a firm’s equity value per year (i.e., fraud pervasiveness (10%) multiplied by the loss of market capitalization for an average firm in case of fraud (15.6%)). The 95% confidence interval for cost of fraud is between 1.2% and 2.2% of the firm’s equity value.

In 2004, the total capitalization of the US equity market was $16 trillion.Footnote 21 Since, on average, 10% of firms are engaged in fraud, the annual fraud cost is $254 billion a year (with a 95% confidence interval between $189 billion and $347 billion). If we repeat the calculation at the end of 2021, the expected annual cost of fraud is $830 billion (with a 95% confidence interval between $5609 billion and $1,133 billion).

5.2 An application to cost–benefit analysis

When a firm is 100% owned by one individual, the cost of fraud is fully internalized by the owner. In publicly traded companies, where equity is dispersed and insiders often own only a tiny fraction of the outstanding equity, this is not the case. These agency costs are one of the justifications for the introduction of regulations like Sarbanes–Oxley (SOX). As an illustration of the wide applicability of our estimates, we sketch how it can be used for a cost–benefit analysis of SOX. Note that reducing agency costs is only one of the benefits of SOX. We are completely silent on other potential benefits, like reducing the lemon discount due to the asymmetry of information in the financial accounts.

Hochberg et al. (2009) exploit survey data collected by Finance Executives International (FEI) to arrive at an estimate of $3.8 million of compliance costs per firm, with costs increasing in the issuer’s size.Footnote 22 To calculate the total compliance costs, we multiply these average compliance costs by the number of publicly traded firms in 2004 (5,226) to obtain an annual compliance cost of SOX of $19.9 billion per year. Note that faced with a regulatory mandate to increase monitoring in some ways, firms may cut down some of the monitoring they were previously doing in other ways (Karpoff and Lott 1993). Thus, $19.9 billion represents an overestimate of SOX compliance costs.

The potential benefit of SOX is equal to the net reduction in the probability of fraud times the cost of fraud when it occurs. If instead of 10% of firms engaged in fraud, a policy change resulted in only 9% of firms engaged in fraud, the cost of fraud would drop by $25 billion (1% times 15.6%, which is the average cost of fraud, times $16 trillion, which is the 2004 total equity market capitalization). Thus, for the benefits of SOX regulation to exceed the costs, it would suffice if SOX were able to reduce the probability of fraud by one percentage point (a 10% reduction). Establishing whether this was indeed the case is beyond the scope of our paper. The purpose here is simply to illustrate the usefulness of an estimate of the pervasiveness of fraud, which enables us to derive an estimate of the total cost of fraud. With this estimate, we can easily assess what is the minimum level of effectiveness (in terms of reduction in the probability of starting a fraud) that any system of controls needs to achieve to justify its cost.

6 Conclusion

In this paper, we use the natural experiment provided by the sudden demise of a major auditing firm, Arthur Andersen, to infer the fraction of corporate fraud that goes undetected. This detection likelihood is essential to quantify the pervasiveness of corporate fraud in the United States and to assess the costs that this fraud imposes on investors. We find that two out of three corporate frauds go undetected, implying that, pre Sox, 41% of large public firms were misreporting their financial accounts in a material way and 10% of the firms were committing securities fraud, imposing an annual cost of $254 billion on investors.

These figures project a dismal picture of the effectiveness of financial auditing pre SOX. Whether SOX reduced or eliminated the problem, our paper is unable to answer. Yet, the magnitude of the problem suggests that some action was warranted. Based on our estimates, we can also infer that if the new regulation reduced by 10% the probability of starting a fraud, its cost would be fully justified.