Skip to main content
Log in

Balancing difficulty of performance targets: theory and evidence

  • Published:
Review of Accounting Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine how firms balance difficulty of performance targets in their annual bonus plans. We present an analytical model showing that managerial allocation of effort is a function of not only relative incentive weights but also the difficulty of performance targets. We find that relative incentive weights and target difficulty can either be complements or substitutes in motivating effort depending on the extent to which managers have alternative employment opportunities. To test the predictions of our model, we use survey data on performance targets in annual bonus plans. Our sample of 877 survey respondents consists primarily of financial executives in small- and medium-size private companies where annual bonuses are important both for motivation and retention. Consistent with our model, we find that relative incentive weights are negatively (positively) associated with perceived target difficulty when concerns about managerial retention are high (low). It follows that performance measures included in annual bonus plans have sometimes easy and other times challenging targets depending on their relative incentive weights and retention concerns.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Intuitively, the purpose of these constraints is to rule out the theoretically plausible but empirically unappealing solution that the salary fully adjusts for any changes in outside labor market opportunities. An alternative assumption that yields the same results in our model is that salary and target bonus adjustments incur arbitrarily small costs, whereas performance target level adjustments are costless.

  2. A substitute (complement) relation between two incentive design choices implies that marginal returns to one choice variable decrease (increase) with the levels of another choice variable (Milgrom and Roberts 1995). In our setting, this means that the cross partial derivative of firm profits with respect to relative incentive weight and target difficulty is negative (positive). If firm profits (and managerial effort) are to remain unchanged at some equilibrium level, a substitute (complement) relation implies that an increase in relative incentive weight has to be accompanied by a decrease (increase) in target difficulty.

  3. We validate our survey measure of retention concerns using publicly available data on average compensation and cost of living in different metropolitan areas.

  4. For example, the expectancy theory predicts that managerial effort and performance increase with target levels up to a point, after which further increasing targets discourages effort (Rockness 1977). Also, studies motivated by the goal-setting theory document a positive relation between performance and target difficulty up to a point where “the limits of ability were reached or when commitment to a highly difficult goal lapsed” (Locke and Latham 2002: 706).

  5. The manager is risk-neutral but protected by limited liability. Assuming that that the manager is risk averse complicates the analysis without yielding any new insights. Specifically, high targets would become less effective in motivating effort of a risk-averse manager because they imply more uncertainty. As explained later, the firm can easily compensate for this by lowering high targets closer to the mid-point of the distribution in Figure 1. See Ray (2017) for a full analysis of targets under risk aversion.

  6. When w i  = 0 and consequently e i  = 0, our model reduces to a setting with a single performance measure. Our model could also easily be generalized to a setting with more than two performance measures, albeit at the cost of a more cumbersome notation.

  7. We can also allow for multiple targets, such as those commonly referred to as the threshold, target, and maximum in prior work (e.g., Murphy 2001; Merchant et al. 2015). This more general specification features bonuses that increase with performance within an “incentive zone” (i.e., a performance range between the threshold and maximum). We do not present this generalization here because it does not yield any additional insights. However, the results are available upon request.

  8. The only unique target that exists satisfies the knife-edge condition that v i  = w i bg(0),in which \( {t}_i={e}_i^{\ast }. \)The single-peaked log-concave distribution rules out more than two targets implementing the same effort.

  9. Although the proof of Proposition 1 presented in Appendix A assumes that changes in reservation utility are independent of other parameters in our model, this assumption can be relaxed. For example, the insights of our model apply unchanged even if economic shocks resulting in tighter labor markets (i.e., higher reservation utility) are positively correlated with greater demand for managerial effort (i.e., higher marginal product of effort).

  10. Administration of the 2013 survey followed largely the same procedures as in 2011. The most important difference was that the 2013 survey collected data on respondents’ geographical location and offered participants a feedback report on compensation design, including a tool benchmarking CFO compensation by metropolitan areas. This new feature considerably increased the number of respondents in 2013, relative to 2011.

  11. The following are examples of performance measures included in the six categories: operations—quality, process improvement metrics; customers and strategy—customer satisfaction, market share; accounting and information systems—ERP implementation, absence of audit issues; financing, transactions and investor relations—capex planning, merger and acquisition-related activities; teamwork—employee turnover, leadership; sustainability—energy use, emissions.

  12. To address the issue of multiple target levels, the survey question adds the following explanation: “Bonus target refers to the performance level that earns you the full targeted bonus (as opposed to some minimum performance level below which no bonuses are paid or some maximum performance level at which bonuses may be capped).”

  13. See “the National Compensation Survey” available from http://www.bls.gov/data/.

  14. “Cost of Living Index—Selected Urban Areas” is a part of the 2012 Statistical Abstract and can be downloaded from the Census Bureau’s website: http://www.census.gov/compendia/statab/cats/prices/consumer_price_indexes_cost_of_living_index.html

  15. The validation sample size ranges between 1212 and 1395 depending on the association among the four variables (SALARY, RETAIN, and both external proxies).

  16. Specifically, ROS is based on responses to the question, “Profitability of your company … was approximately (in $ millions)?” We do not include a detailed definition of profitability to make sure that “actual profit/loss” matches respondents’ own definition of “budgeted profit/loss.”

  17. Annual bonus plans are by far the most important incentive instruments among respondents in our survey. Only 11% of the respondents receive multi-year bonus plans and 26% receive equity compensation. We also find that annual bonuses are larger than the sum of equity grants and multi-year bonuses for 86% of our sample. Section 4 discusses a robustness check where we drop all observations with nonzero long-term compensation and find qualitatively similar results.

  18. For example, achievability of sustainability targets (77%) appears higher than the sample average for financial targets (69%). However, the small sample of companies using some sustainability targets happens to have financial targets that are even more achievable (83%) than sustainability targets.

  19. When one of the additional LL or CC constraints is binding as well, the firm may no longer be able to implement first-best effort.

  20. [year_t-1] stands for last year, i.e., 2010 or 2012 depending on the timing of the survey.

  21. [year] stands for the year of the survey, i.e., 2011 or 2013.

  22. If one or more of the nonfinancial target categories in the previous question was checked, the generic category “nonfinancial performance targets” was replaced with one or more of these items where [category label] stands for operations, sustainability, financing and investment, etc.

References

  • Ai, C., & Norton, E. C. (2003). Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Economics Letters, 80, 123–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, S. W., Dekker, H. C., & Sedatole, K. L. (2010). An empirical examination of goals and performance-to-goal following the introduction of an incentive bonus plan with participative goal-setting. Management Science, 56, 90–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aral, S., Brynjolfsson, E., & Wu, L. (2012). Three-way complementarities: Performance pay, human resource analytics, and information technology. Management Science, 58, 913–931.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnaiz, Ó. G., & Salas-Fumás, V. (2008). Performance standards and optimal incentives. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 45, 139–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora, A. (1996). Testing for complementarities in reduced-form regressions: A note. Economics Letters, 50, 51–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora, A., & Gambardella, A. (1990). Complementarity and external linkages - the strategies of the large firms in biotechnology. Journal of Industrial Economics, 38, 361–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asker, J., Farre-Mensa, J., & Ljungqvist, A. (2014). Corporate investment and stock market listing: A puzzle? Review of Financial Studies, 28, 342–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagnoli, M., & Bergstrom, T. (2005). Log-concave probability and its applications. Economic Theory, 26, 445–469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balsam, S., & Miharjo, S. (2007). The effect of equity compensation on voluntary executive turnover. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 43, 95–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banker, R. D., & Datar, S. M. (1989). Sensitivity, precision, and linear aggregation of signals for performance evaluation. Journal of Accounting Research, 27, 21–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bebchuk, L. A. (2009). Pay without performance: The unfulfilled promise of executive compensation. Cambridge and London: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bewley, T. F. (1999). Why wages don't fall during a recession. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonner, S. E., Hastie, R., Sprinkle, G. B., & Young, S. M. (2000). A review of the effects of financial incentives on performance in laboratory tasks: Implications for management accounting. Journal of Management Accounting Research, 12, 19–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bouwens, J., & Kroos, P. (2011). Target ratcheting and effort reduction. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 51, 171–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, C. M., & Kamlani, K. S. (1997). The reasons for wage rigidity: Evidence from a survey of firms. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 759–789.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carter, M. E., & Lynch, L. J. (2001). An examination of executive stock option repricing. Journal of Financial Economics, 61, 207–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casas-Arce, P., Indjejikian, R., & Matějka, M. (2013). Information asymmetry and the choice of financial and nonfinancial performance targets during an economic downturn. Working paper, Arizona State University.

  • Elsby, M. W. (2009). Evaluating the economic significance of downward nominal wage rigidity. Journal of Monetary Economics, 56, 154–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feltham, G. A., & Xie, J. (1994). Performance measure congruity and diversity in multi-task principal-agent relations. The Accounting Review, 69, 429–453.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, J. G., Peffer, S. A., Sprinkle, G. B., & Williamson, M. G. (2015). Performance target levels and effort: Reciprocity across single-and repeated-interaction settings. Journal of Management Accounting Research, 27, 145–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grabner, I., & Moers, F. (2013). Management control as a system or a package? Conceptual and empirical issues. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 38, 407–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R. E. (2005). Employment fluctuations with equilibrium wage stickiness. The American Economic Review, 95, 50–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmström, B., and Milgrom, P. (1991). Multitask principal agent analyses—Incentive contracts, asset ownership, and job design. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 7, 24–52.

  • Indjejikian, R. J., & Matějka, M. (2006). Organizational slack in decentralized firms: The role of business unit controllers. The Accounting Review, 81, 849–872.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Indjejikian, R. J., & Matějka, M. (2012). Accounting decentralization and performance evaluation of business unit managers. The Accounting Review, 87, 261–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Indjejikian, R. J., & Nanda, D. (2002). Executive target bonuses and what they imply about performance standards. The Accounting Review, 77, 793–819.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Indjejikian, R. J., Matějka, M., Merchant, K. A., & Van der Stede, W. A. (2014). Earnings targets and annual bonus incentives. The Accounting Review, 89, 1227–1258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Innes, R. D. (1990). Limited liability and incentive contracting with ex-ante action choices. Journal of Economic Theory, 52, 45–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ittner, C. D., Larcker, D. F., & Rajan, M. V. (1997). The choice of performance measures in annual bonus contracts. The Accounting Review, 72, 231–255.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ittner, C. D., Lambert, R. A., and Larcker, D. F. (2003). The structure and performance consequences of equity grants to employees of new economy firms. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 34, 89–127.

  • Kaplan, R. S., & Norton, D. P. (1996). The balanced scorecard: Translating strategy into action. Boston: Harvard Business Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kominis, G., & Emmanuel, C. R. (2007). The expectancy–valence theory revisited: Developing an extended model of managerial motivation. Management Accounting Research, 18, 49–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E. P. (2004). Output-based pay: Incentives, retention or sorting? In Accounting for worker well-being (Research in labor economics), Vol. 23, ed. S. W. Polachek. Bingley:Emerald Group Publishing Limited.

  • Lazear, E. P., & Rosen, S. (1981). Rank-order tournaments as optimum labor contracts. The Journal of Political Economy, 89, 841–864.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leone, A. J., & Rock, S. (2002). Empirical tests of budget ratcheting and its effect on managers' discretionary accrual choices. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 33, 43–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Locke, E. A., & Latham, G. P. (2002). Building a practically useful theory of goal setting and task motivation: A 35-year odyssey. American Psychologist, 57, 705–717.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahlendorf, M., Matějka, M., & Schäffer, U. (2015). Target ratcheting, incentives, and achievability of earnings targets. Working paper, Arizona State University.

  • Matějka, M., Merchant, K. A., & Van der Stede, W. A. (2009). Employment horizon and the choice of performance measures: Empirical evidence from annual bonus plans of loss-making entities. Management Science, 55, 890–905.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merchant, K. A. (1989). Rewarding results: Motivating profit center managers. Brighton: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merchant, K. A., & Manzoni, J. F. (1989). The achievability of budget targets in profit centers - a field study. The Accounting Review, 64, 539–558.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merchant, K. A., Stringer, C., & Shantapriyan, P. (2015). The anatomy of a complex performance-dependent incentive system. Working paper, University of Southern California.

  • Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. (1992). Economics, organization and management. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. (1995). Complementarities and fit—Strategy, structure, and organizational change in manufacturing. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 19, 179–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. J. (2001). Performance standards in incentive contracts. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 30, 245–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oyer, P. (2004). Why do firms use incentives that have no incentive effects? Journal of Finance, 59, 1619–1649.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oyer, P., & Schaefer, S. (2005). Why do some firms give stock options to all employees?: An empirical examination of alternative theories. Journal of Financial Economics, 76, 99–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ray, K. (2007). Performance evaluations and efficient sorting. Journal of Accounting Research, 45, 839–882.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ray, K. (2017). Optimal performance targets. Working paper, Texas A&M University.

  • Rockness, H. O. (1977). Expectancy theory in a budgetary setting: An experimental examination. The Accounting Review, 52, 893–903.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schöttener, A. (2016). Optimal sales force compensation in dynamic settings: Commissions vs. bonuses. Management Science, 63, 1529–1544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Webb, R. A., Williamson, M. G., & Zhang, Y. (2013). Productivity-target difficulty, target-based pay, and outside-the-box thinking. The Accounting Review, 88, 1433–1457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zellner, A. (1962). An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated regressions and tests for aggregation bias. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 57, 348–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This research project has been supported by the American Institute of Certified Public Accountants (AICPA). We would also like to gratefully acknowledge helpful comments of Paul Fischer, two anonymous reviewers, Shannon Anderson, Pablo Casas-Arce, Jeremy Bertomeu, Shane Dikolli, Henry Friedman, Chris Ittner, Andrei Kovrijnykh, Ken Merchant, Michael Raith, Dae-Hee Yoon, as well as workshop participants at Bocconi University, Columbia University, George Washington University, Texas A&M University, Yonsei Univsersity, University of Houston, and the 2015 MAS Research Conference.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michal Matějka.

Appendices

Appendix 1—Analytical framework and proofs

Proof of Lemma 1. The manager solves the problem:

$$ \underset{e_i}{\max }s+{w}_1{bP}_1+{w}_2{bP}_2-\frac{1}{2}{c}_1{e}_1^2-\frac{1}{2}{c}_2{e}_2^2 $$
(3)

Differentiating with respect to e i gives the incentive constraint (IC):

$$ {e}_i=\frac{w_ib}{c_i}g\left({e}_i-{t}_i\right) $$
(IC)

and second order sufficient condition (SOSC):

$$ 1-\frac{w_ib}{c_i}{g}^{\prime}\left({e}_i-{t}_i\right)>0. $$
(4)

Assume SOSC holds. Using (4) and differentiating IC with respect to each of the contract choices gives:

$$ \frac{\partial {e}_i}{\partial b}=\frac{g\left({e}_i-{t}_i\right)\frac{w_i}{c_i}}{1-\frac{w_ib}{c_i}{g}^{\prime}\left({e}_i-{t}_i\right)}>0, $$
(5)
$$ \frac{\partial {e}_i}{\partial {w}_i}=\frac{\frac{b}{c_i}g\left({e}_i-{t}_i\right)}{1-\frac{w_ib}{c_i}{g}^{\prime}\left({e}_i-{t}_i\right)}>0, $$
(6)
$$ \frac{\partial {e}_i}{\partial {t}_i}=\frac{-\frac{w_ib}{c_i}{g}^{\prime}\left({e}_i-{t}_i\right)}{1-\frac{w_ib}{c_i}{g}^{\prime}\left({e}_i-{t}_i\right)}>0\kern0.72em \mathrm{iff}\kern0.30em {e}_i>{t}_i.\mathrm{QED}. $$
(7)

Proof of Lemma 2. Rearranging IC and using the fact that g is symmetric around zero yields

$$ {t}_i={e}_i\pm {g}^{-1}\left(\frac{c_i{e}_i}{w_ib}\right). $$
(8)

Thus there exists δ > 0, low target \( {t}_i^L={e}_i-\delta \), and a high target \( {t}_i^H={e}_i+\delta, \) such that g(e i  − t i L) = g(δ) = g(−δ) = g(e i  − t i H) and IC is satisfied both for \( {t}_i^L \) and \( {t}_i^H \). QED.

Proof of Lemma 3. Fix an effort level e 0 = e(t, w) from the manager’s problem. Using (6) and (7), we obtain by the implicit function theorem:

$$ \frac{\partial {t}_i}{\partial {w}_i}=-\frac{\partial e/\partial {w}_i}{\partial e/\partial {t}_i}=\frac{g\left({e}_i-{t}_i\right)}{w_i{g}^{\prime}\left({e}_i-{t}_i\right)}. $$
(9)

Given that g is increasing only over its negative domain, \( {g}^{\prime}\left({e}_i-{t}_i^L\right)={g}^{\prime}\left(\delta \right)<0 \) and so by (9), \( \frac{\partial {t}_i^L}{\partial {w}_i}<0 \). Similarly, \( {g}^{\prime}\left({e}_i-{t}_i^H\right)={g}^{\prime}\left(-\delta \right)>0 \), and therefore \( \frac{\partial {t}_i^H}{\partial {w}_i}>0 \). QED.

Proof of Proposition 1. The firm selects a contract ω = (s, b, t i , w i ) that maximizes gross profits, subject to the participation (PC), incentive (IC), limited liability (LL) and compensation cap constraints (CC). For ease of exposition, we first describe the firm’s optimization problem with the former two constraints only and subsequently discuss the effect of adding the latter two constraints.

Suppose that only the PC and IC constraints are binding. We know that the firm can implement first-best effort \( {e}_i^{\ast } \) because both contracting parties are risk neutral.Footnote 19 From Lemma 2, we also know that each effort level \( {e}_i^{\ast } \) can be implemented with either a high (\( {t}_i^H \)) or a low (\( {t}_i^L \)) target, for a fixed bonus b and relative incentive weights w i . Let s jk be the salary when measure 1 is j = L , H and measure 2 is k = L , H. It follows that any first-best effort \( {e}_i^{\ast } \) can be implemented with four different contracts \( {\omega}_{jk}=\left({s}_{jk},b,{t}_1^j,{t}_2^k,{w}_1,{w}_2\right) \) for jk = LL , LH , HL , HH. The expected utility of the manager under each of the four contracts is \( {EU}_{jk}={s}_{jk}+{E}_1^j+{E}_2^k-C\left({e}_1,{e}_2\right) \), where \( {E}_i^L \) and \( {E}_i^H \)denote the expected bonus contingent on performance measure i under a low and high target, respectively. Low targets increase the probability of success and the expected bonus so that \( {E}_i^L>{E}_i^H \). Given a binding participation constraint PC, \( {EU}_{jk}=\overline{u} \), the salary under high targets must exceed the salary under low targets (s LL  < s HH ).

An increase in the reservation utility \( \overline{u} \) does not affect the choice of first-best effort level \( {e}_i^{\ast } \), but the firm has to adjust the contract to increase the manager’s expected utility. Specifically, the firm can take one of the following four actions.

  1. 1.

    Increase salary. The firm can raise salary s jk , which has no effect on incentives and implements the same \( {e}_i^{\ast } \).

  2. 2.

    Increase target bonus. The firm can raise target bonus b but that would also lead to an increase in effort(∂e i /∂b > 0). To keep effort fixed at \( {e}_i^{\ast } \), the firm can either increase the high target or reduce the low target, because \( \partial {e}_i/\partial {t}_i^L>0 \) and \( \partial {e}_i/\partial {t}_i^H<0 \). As shown below, both of these changes also increase the manager’s expected utility.

Specifically, the IC constraint implies a functional relationship between target bonus b and targets \( {t}_i^j \) if effort is to remain unchanged at \( {e}_i^{\ast } \):

$$ b=\frac{e_i^{\ast }c}{w_ig\left({e}_i-{t}_i^j\right)}. $$

The expected bonus is \( {E}_i^j={w}_i bG\left({e}_i-{t}_i^j\right)={e}_i cG\left({e}_i-{t}_i^j\right)/g\left({e}_i-{t}_i^j\right). \) Differentiating this expected bonus with respect to target \( {t}_i^j \) yields the following:

$$ \frac{\partial {E}_i^j}{\partial {t}_i^j}={e}_ic\left[\frac{-g{\left({e}_i-{t}_i^j\right)}^2+G\left({e}_i-{t}_i^j\right){g}^{\prime}\left({e}_i-{t}_i^j\right)}{g{\left({e}_i-{t}_i^j\right)}^2}\right]. $$

For low targets \( {g}^{\prime}\left({e}_i-{t}_i^L\right)<0 \), and therefore \( \partial {E}_i^j/\partial {t}_i^L<0 \), so decreasing the low target will increase expected bonus. For high targets \( {g}^{\prime}\left({e}_i-{t}_i^j\right)>0 \), but log-concave G implies that Gg ' > g 2, which assures that \( \partial {E}_i^j/\partial {t}_i^H>0 \), so increasing the high targets also increases expected bonus.

  1. 3.

    Change relative incentive weights. The firm can also change relative incentive weightsw i . WLOG, suppose the performance measures are sorted in the sense that i = 1 denotes the performance measure that accounts for a majority of the target bonus. The manager’s expected utility can be increased without changing \( {e}_i^{\ast } \) as follows. If the target accounting for the majority of the target bonus is low (\( {t}_1^L \)), the firm can simultaneously increase w 1 (which increases effort) and reduce \( {t}_1^L \) (which decreases effort), holding effort unchanged. If the target accounting for the majority of the target bonus is high (\( {t}_1^H \)), the firm can simultaneously increase w 1 (which increases effort) and increase \( {t}_1^H \) (which decreases effort), also holding effort unchanged. Given that w 1 > 0.5, marginal changes in total expected bonus will have the same sign as marginal changes in \( {E}_1^j \). As shown above, \( \partial {E}_i^j/\partial {t}_i^j<0 \) for low and \( \partial {E}_i^j/\partial {t}_i^j>0 \) for high targets, and the IC constraint implies that higher w 1 has to be accompanied by decreasing the low target and increasing the high targets.

  2. 4.

    Switch targets. The firm can leave target bonus b and relative incentive weights w i unchanged and select between the four different contracts ω jk by switching from high targets to low targets. This will increase the expected bonus since the probability of success is greater under a low target \( \left({P}_i^L=G\left({e}_i-{t}_i^L\right)>G\left({e}_i-{t}_i^H\right)={P}_i^H\right) \) but implement the same effort \( {e}_i^{\ast } \) by Lemma 2.

Without additional assumptions, the firm can choose any (combination) of the above four actions to increase the agent’s expected utility until PC binds. However, the third action becomes infeasible at some point, as the reservation utility changes, because w i has to be between zero and one by definition. Similarly, the LL and CC constraints impose bounds on the salary (\( \underline{s}\le s\le \overline{s} \)) and target bonus (\( 0\le b\le \overline{b} \)), and when these constraints are binding, switching targets (the fourth action) becomes the only feasible way to further increase or reduce the manager’s expected compensation.

For example, the highest possible expected utility for a given choice of targets jk is \( {\overline{u}}_{jk}^{\ast }=\overline{s}+{w}_1\overline{b}G\left({e}_1^{\ast }-{t}_1^j\right)+{w}_2\overline{b}G\left({e}_2^{\ast }-{t}_2^k\right)-C\left({e}_1^{\ast },{e}_2^{\ast}\right) \).

For any reservation utility above this threshold, the firm must switch some high targets to low targets. For sufficiently high reservation utility, \( \overline{u}>\max \left\{{\overline{u}}_{LH}^{\ast },{\overline{u}}_{HL}^{\ast}\right\} \), the firms will choose low targets on both measures, jk = LL. A symmetric argument applies for decreases in reservation utility. QED.

Appendix 2—Survey questions

SALARY: Your annual base salary in [year_t-1]Footnote 20 was approximately

TBONUS: If [year]Footnote 21 performance meets all targets, the [year] annual bonus will be approximately

If your [year_t-1] bonus plan included a nonfinancial performance target fitting one or more of the broad categories below, please check the box next to the categories. You can also describe your nonfinancial performance targets in the text boxes.

Customers, market, and strategy

(e.g., market share, customer satisfaction, strategic milestones)

Operations

(e.g., efficiency, safety, quality, process improvement, cost control)

Sustainability

(e.g., energy use, emissions, social reporting, stakeholder satisfaction)

Financing and investment

(e.g., working capital management, capex planning, M&A deals, divestitures, investor relations)

Accounting, reporting, and IT systems

(e.g., timeliness and efficiency of reporting, management satisfaction, IT projects)

Teamwork and human resource management

(e.g., employee turnover, leadership, collaboration, and communication)

If [year] performance meets all targets, what percentage of this bonus will you earn based on

WEIGHT: Financial performance targets

WEIGHT_t Nonfinancial performance targets(e.g., market share, strategy milestones, customer satisfaction)

WEIGHT_t [Alternatively] Nonfinancial performance targets related to [category label]Footnote 22

Achievements evaluated subjectively (i.e., without objective targets)

WEIGHT_t Other

Given the current business environment, how likely is it that you will meet your [year] bonus targets?

Bonus target refers to the performance level that earns you the full targeted bonus (as opposed to some minimum performance level below which no bonuses are paid or some maximum performance level at which bonuses may be capped).

PROB: Earnings targetPROB: Other financial performance targetsPROB_t: Nonfinancial performance targetsPROB_t [Alternatively] Nonfinancial performance targets related to [category label]

To what extent do you agree with the following statements?

RETAIN: Retention of executives is the key objective of our [year] bonus plan

CAPITAL: Our [entity] has adequate (access to) capital for the near term

Scales: Strongly agree / Somewhat agree / Neither agree nor disagree / Somewhat disagree / Strongly disagree / N/A

SALES: Sales of your company in [year] were approximately (in $ millions):

SIZE: Number of [entity] employees in [year_t-1]?

ROS and FAIL: Profitability of your company in [year_t-1] was approximately (in $ millions)?

Actual profit/loss

Budgeted profit/loss

GROWTH: How would you characterize the long-term (5–10 years) business prospects of your company?

Expected annual growth in sales

Scale: Negative / 0–5% / 6–12% / 13–20% / More than 20% / N/A

NOISE: To what extent do financial performance measures reflect management’s overall performance?

Scale: Not at all / Low / Medium / High / Very high / Don’t know

CEO, CFO: Which of the following best describes your job?

CEO (the top executive)

CFO (or similar title referring to the top financial executive)

Other financial executive (reporting to the top financial executive)

Other, please specify:

PUBLIC: Is the company you are a part of:

Publicly traded

Privately owned

BU: Are you answering for:

Corporate level

Division level

Other, please specify

INDUSTRY: Please describe your industry. Select from the list below

Manufacturing / Finance and Insurance / Wholesale Trade / Retail Trade / Transportation and Warehousing / Construction / Real Estate / Professional, Scientific and Technical Services / Hospitality and Food Services / Healthcare / Information and Media / Education / Arts, Entertainment and Recreation / Utilities / Mining and Oil & Gas / Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting / Holding Company or Conglomerate / Other

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Matějka, M., Ray, K. Balancing difficulty of performance targets: theory and evidence. Rev Account Stud 22, 1666–1697 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-017-9420-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-017-9420-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation