Skip to main content
Log in

Potlatch economy: reciprocity among northwest coast Indians

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Among the Pacific Northwest Coast Indians of North America before and during the extended era of European contact, a pervasive institution known as the potlatch governed human relations through reciprocity rather than the hierarchical state. Potlatching involved recurring intertribal feasting, gift giving, ceremonial dance, storytelling, oratory, dispute resolution, declarations of claim or right, and some measure of property destruction. The tribes referred to this network of publicly declared favors given and owed and promises made and received as their customary “potlatch law.” Like law in the Western world, it was the foundation on which their economies rested. The potlatch memorialized obligations, enforced property rights, insured against risk, promoted knowledge accumulation, supplied investment capital, and served as a system of fractional reserve banking. Beyond that, it was the foundation of the tribes’ unique culture. The potlatch provides fascinating insight into the nuance and power of reciprocity in ordering human relations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. I use the term “tribe” generically to refer to the resource management unit at any level in the social order of chiefs, sub-chiefs, and sub-sub-chiefs in the hierarchy of lineages, clans, houses, etc. All shared the exclusive right to manage owned resources and all engaged in potlatching.

  2. Prior to European contact, the Copper River and other sites in northern British Columbia were the source of the ore from which coppers were made.

  3. Women had their own resource sites and potlatch networks (Bracken, 1997).

  4. In modern legal parlance, the chief held formal legal title as trustee for the tribe and the tribe (current and future members) held equitable title, just as in many trustee-beneficiary relationships. At least among some tribes, a chief could not alienate tribal territories, yet it appears that under limited circumstances he could pledge them as collateral. Title disputes sometimes arose owing to the circumstances of succession and other factors, possibly including default on outstanding potlach debts. Title could pass to the winner of a “rivalry” potlatch, for example, in which claimants essentially competed in a second-price auction (Johnsen, 2006).

  5. By way of example, Sockeye run on a four-year cycle. Labeling the salmon run that spawns in any arbitrary year as Stock A1, their offspring spawn four years later as A5. The next year the run of Stock B2 spawns, and its offspring spawn four years later as B6, etc.

  6. The nomenclature of property rights has evolved since the time North and Thomas wrote. What they refer to as common property rights are now widely referred to as open access rights, and exclusive communal property rights are referred to as common property. It is a mistake to conclude that open access means the complete absence of ownership. Even under open access, having captured a fish I have exclusive ownership over it, but the stock of fish that generates individual fish is subject to open access rights and dissipation is likely. In some cases, however, open access properly constrained can be efficient (Lueck, 1995; Johnsen, 2009).

  7. This is exactly how the upstream tribes of the interior Fraser and Columbia River drainages organized production. During the salmon run, a multitude of tribes converged on known harvesting sites such as Si’lailo Falls on the Columbia River, where Ostrom-like norms of sharing, turn-taking, and conservation were carefully followed (Johnsen, 2007). In this setting, ETRs to salmon stocks were largely absent because migrating salmon had to run the gauntlet of downstream fishing and were essentially subject to open access. With property rights looser than on the Coast, potlatching, though practiced, was far less formalized (Johnsen, 2001).

  8. In his discussions on the viability of anarchy, Tullock (1972) (and others) conclude that the strong, who have comparative advantage in violence, will defeat and subjugate the weak via the apparatus of the predatory state, leaving the weak no better off than under anarchy and possibly worse. Yet the distinction between strong and weak becomes ambiguous in a comparative advantage model and raises a serious dilemma. Once the relatively week but absolutely strong win an all-out war, the relatively strong but absolutely week will slowly assert their comparative advantage in violence and come to control the apparatus of governance as ressentiment sets in. As Nietzsche (1967) reflected, the more a person is active, strong-willed, and dynamic, the less time and attention is left for contemplating victimhood or engaging in reflective self-doubt. If left to their own devices, the absolutely weak will likely build a hierarchical state (or university administration) to redress their grievances and quietly neuter the absolutely strong, excluding them from state governance and leaving them to their productive pursuits and the payment of taxes. Angelbeck and Gier specifically identify the NWC tribes as having developed a “peer-exchange” network for mutual aid and that “individuals participating in them actively resisted the centralization of power” (2012, p. 553), thereby avoiding Nietzsche’s dilemma.

  9. Most likely, potlatch partners shifted with circumstances. There is evidence that Tribe B, having been the beneficiary of a potlatch hosted by Tribe A, could delegate to Tribe C its obligation to repay, just as Tribe A could assign its right to collect to Tribe D.

  10. As Hirshleifer (1985) observes, “redistribution institutions, whereby prestige is earned by liberal generosity, tend to moderate rat-race competitions for income” (1985, p. 59).

  11. Ellickson (1991) and others use the term “side-payments.”

  12. In arguing against claims that gift giving should be abandoned because it invariably generates allocative inefficiencies (Waldfogel, 1993; Gill & Thomas, 2022) argue that long-run dynamic efficiencies likely outweigh these short-run allocative inefficiencies. My model of the NWC tribes provides specific theoretical and empirical support for their work.

  13. Though it may sound fantastic, I can think of no evidence to refute the hypothesis that the five distinct species of Pacific salmon were genetically engineered from a single parent species to develop a diversified portfolio of species with different life histories and other characteristics. This is no more fantastic than that pre-Columbian Indians engineered modern maze from a tiny, barely edible seed pod (Mann, 2005).

  14. In his revealing analysis of Shasta County cattle country norms, Ellickson (1991) prefers the behavioral postulate of welfare maximization, rather than wealth maximization, to avoid any suggestion that people are motivated by money alone. It is a fair point, but for my purposes it is one of second order importance to the focus wealth maximization puts on intertemporal resource allocation and the critical role the structure of property rights plays in providing the incentives to make decisions for the long run. Ellickson finesses this deficiency in welfare maximization when he modifies it to “long-run” welfare maximization.

  15. Being in the bad state was just one circumstance that could generate valuable investment projects. Innovation obviously identified others.

    In contrast to the Coast, in the Columbia, Fraser, Skeena and other large river interior plateaus, along which many different tribes resided, salmon had to run an open-access gauntlet to reach the spawning beds and were subject to depensatory fishing by downstream tribes. Perhaps for this reason, it was common in the interior for upstream tribes to encroach on downstream tribes’ territories during the harvest, and this encroachment was tolerated by downstream tribes, with shared access occurring at known sites under Ostrom-like norms.

  16. Forced loans were apparently common in the ancient world (Homer & Sylla, 2005).

References

  • Acemoğlu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2019). The narrow corridor: States, societies, and the fate of liberty. Penguin Books.

  • Alchian, A. (1977).Why money? Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking9,133–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62, 777–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, D. W. (1991). What are transaction costs? Research in Law and Economics, 14, 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, T. L., & McChesney, F. S. (1994). Raid or trade: An economic model of indian-white relations. Journal of Law and Economics, 37, 39–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, T. L., & Hill, P. J. (2004). The not so wild, wild west: Property rights on the frontier. Stanford University Press. 2004.

  • Anderson, T. L., Leonard, B., Parker, D. P., & Regan, S. (2016). Natural resources on american indian reservations: Blessing or curse? In T. L. Anderson (Ed.), Unlocking the Wealth of Indian Nations. Lexington Books.

  • Angelbeck, B., & Grier, C. (2012). Anarchism and the archaeology of anarchic societies: Resistance to centralization in the Coast Salish region of the Pacific Northwest Coast. Current Anthropology, 53(5), 547–587.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, H. G. (1938). The nature of the potlatch. American Anthropologist (New Series), 40, 349–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauer, P. T. (2000). From subsistence to exchange and other essays. Princeton University Press.

  • Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., & McCabe, K. (1995). Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 122–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein, L. (1992). Opting out of the legal system: Extralegal contractual relations in the diamond industry. Journal of Legal Studies, 21(1), 115–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boas, F. (1897). The social organization and the secret societies of the Kwakiutl Indians. Smithsonian Institution.

  • Boas, F. (1966). Kwakiutl ethnography. University of Chicago Press.

  • Bonenko, A. (1980). Pacific salmon fishing. A.S. Barnes & Co.

  • Boyd, R. (1999). The coming of the spirit of pestilence: Introduced infectious diseases and population decline among Northwest Coast Indians (pp. 1774–1874). University of Washington Press.

  • Bracken, C. (1997). The potlatch papers: A colonial case history. University Chicago Press.

  • Campbell, S. K., & Butler, V. L. (2010). Archaeological evidence for resilience of Pacific Northwest salmon populations and the socioecological system over the last ~ 7,500 years.Ecology and Society15(1), https://www.jstor.org/stable/26268107.

  • Camera, G., Casari, M., & Bigoni, M. (2013). Money and trust among strangers. www.pnas.org/cgi/doi/10.1073/pnas.1301888110.

  • Candela, R. A., & Geloso, V. J. (2021). Trade or raid: Acadian settlers and native Americans before 1755. Public Choice, 188, 549–575.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Codere, H. (1950). Fighting with property.American Ethnological Society Monographs18.

  • Cole, D., & Chaikin, I. (1990). An iron hand upon the people: The law against the potlatch on the Northwest Coast. University of Washington Press.

  • Crepelle, A., Fegley, T., & Murtazashvili, I. (2022). Military societies: Self-governance and criminal justice in indian country. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-022-01004-1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cybulski, J. (2007). Skeletal biology: Northwest Coast and Plateau. Handbook of north american Indians, volume 3: Environment, Origins, and Population (pp. 532–547). Washington D.C.): Smithsonian Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deur, D., Kim Recalma-Clutesi, and, & Dick, A. (2020). Balance on every ledger: Kwakwaka’wakw resource values and traditional ecological management. The Routledge Handbook of Indigenous Environmental Knowledge (pp. 126–135). Routledge.

  • De Soto, H. (2000). The mystery of capital: Why capitalism triumphs in the West and fails everywhere else. Basic Books.

  • Donald, L., & Mitchell, D. H. (1975). Some correlates of local group rank among the Southern Kwakiutl. 14 Ethnology 325 at 333.

  • Donald, L. (1997). Aboriginal slavery on the northwest coast of North America. University of California Press.

  • Drucker, P. (1955). Indians of the Northwest Coast. Natural History Press.

  • Drucker, P. (1965). Cultures of the North Pacific Coast. Chandler.

  • Ellickson., R. C. (1991). Order without law: How neighbors settle disputes. Harvard University Press.

  • Ferguson, B. (1979). Warfare and redistributie exchange on the Northwest Coast. In Elisabeth Tooker (Ed.), The development of political organization in Native North America. 1979 Proceedings of the American Ethnological Society, 133–147.

  • Gill, A., & Thomas, M. D. (2022). The dynamic efficiency of gifting. Journal of Institutional Economics, 1–16. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137422000200.

  • Goldenweiser, A. (1940). Culture of the indian tribes of the Pacific Northwest. Oregon Historical Quarterly, 41(2), 137–146.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, D. C. (2001). Fish law and colonialism: The legal capture of salmon in British Columbia. University of Toronto Press.

  • Hayden, B. (1981). Research and development in the stone age: Technological transitions among hunter-gatherers. Current Anthropology, 22, 525–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendry, A. P., Wenburg, J. K., Bentzen, P., Volk, E. C., & Quin, T. P. (2000). Rapid evolution of reproductive isolation in the wild: Evidence from introduced salmon. Science, 290, 516–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1985). The expanding domain of economics. American Economic Review, 75(6), 53–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, E., McCabe, K. A., & Smith, V. L. (1998). Behavioral foundations of reciprocity: Experimental economics and evolutionary psychology. Economic Inquiry, 36(3), 335–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Homer, S., & Sylla, R. (2005). A history of interest rates. Rutgers University Press.

  • Hutchings, R. M., & Williams, S. (2020). Salish Sea islands archaeology and precontact history. Journal of Northwest Anthropology, 54, 22–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnsen, D. B. (1986). The formation and protection of property rights among the Southern Kwakiutl Indians. J Leg Stud, 15(10), 41–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnsen, D. B. (2001). Customary law, scientific knowledge, and fisheries management among northwest coast tribes. New York University Environmental Law Journal, 10, 1–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnsen, D. B. (2006). A culturally correct proposal to privatize the British Columbia salmon fishery. In T. Anderson, B. Benson, & T. Flanagan (Eds.), Self-Determination: The other path for native Americans. Stanford University Press.

  • Johnsen, D. B. (2007). The Si’lailo redux. The Green Bag (2d), 10, 245–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnsen, D. B. (2009). Myths about mutual fund fees: Economic insights on Jones v. Harris J Corp L, 35, 561–614.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnsen, D. B. (2016). The potlatch as fractional reserve banking. In T. Anderson (Ed.), Unlocking the Wealth of Indian Nations. Lexington Books.

  • Knight, F. H. (1924). Some fallacies in the interpretation of social costs. Q J E, 38(4), 582–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Croix, S. (2019). Hawai‘i: Eight hundred Years of Political and Economic Change. University of Chicago Press.

  • Landa, J. T. (1983). The enigma of the Kula Ring: Gift-exchanges and primitive law and order. Int’l Review of Law & Economics, 3, 137–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2007). Better off stateless: Somalia before and after government collapse. Journal of Comparative Economics, 35, 689–710.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2009). The laws of lawlessness. Journal of Legal Studies, 38, 471–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leonard, B., Parker, D. P., & Anderson, T. L. (2020). Land quality, land rights, and indigenous poverty. Journal of Development Economic, 143, 102435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lepofsky, D., Smith, N. F., Cardinal, N., Harper, J., Mary Morris, Gitla (Elroy White), Randy Bouchard, Dorothy, I. D., Kennedy, A. K., & Salomon, Michelle Puckett, Kirsten Rowell, and Eric McLay. 2015. Ancient shellfish mariculture on the Northwest Coast of North America. American Antiquity 80(2), 236 – 59.

  • Lueck, D. (1995). The rule of first possession and the design of the law. Journal of Law and Economics, 38, 393–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mann, C. C. (2005). 1491: New Revelations of the Americas before Columbus. Alfred A. Knopf.

  • Marsh, G. P. 1874. The earth as modified by human action.Sampson Low and Co.

  • Mauss, M. (2002). The gift: Forms and functions of exchange in archaic societies. Routledge (2002). First published: Paris, 1925 (in French).

  • McChesney, F. S. (1990). Government as definer of property rights: Indian lands, ethnic externalities, and bureaucratic budgets. Journal of Legal Studies, 19(2), 297–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morin, J. (2012). The political economy of the stone celt exchange in pre-contact British Columbia: The Salish nephrite/jade industry. University of British Columbia (Ph.D. thesis).

  • Morin, J., Zhang, H., Royle, T. C. A., Speller, C., Alcaide, M., Morin, R., & Yang, D. (2021a). DNA-based species identification of ancient salmonid remains provides new insight into pre-contact Coast Salish salmon fisheries in Burrard Inlet, British Columbia, Canada,Journal of Archaeological Science: Reports.

  • Morin, J., Royle, T. C. A., Royle, H., Zhang, C., Speller, M., Alcaide, R., Morin, M., Ritchie, A., Cannon, M., George, M., & George, D. Y. (2021b). Indigenous sex-selective salmon harvesting demonstrates pre-contact marine resource management in Burrard Inlet, British Columbia, Canada. Scientific Reports 11, 21160.

  • North, D. C. (2005). Understanding the process of economic change. Princeton University Press.

  • North, D. C., & Thomas, R. P. (1977). The first economic revolution. The Economic History Review, 30(2), 229–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C., Wallis, J. J., & Weingast, B. R. (2009). Violence and social orders: A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. Cambridge University Press.

  • Oberg, K. (1973). The social economy of the Tlingit Indians. University of Washington Press.

  • Ortmann, A., Fitzgerald, J., & Boeing, C. (2000). Trust, reciprocity, and social history: A re-examination. Experimental Economics, 3, 81–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press.

  • Piddocke, S. (1965). The potlatch system of the Southern Kwakiutl: A new perspective. Southwestern Journal of Anthropology, 21(3), 244–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polanyi, K. (1957). The economy as instituted process. Trade and market in the early empires: Economies in history and theory. The Free Press.

  • Powell, B., & Stringham, E. P. (2009). Public choice and the economic analysis of anarchy: A survey. Public Choice, 140(3/4), 503–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romanoff, S. (1992). The cultural ecology of hunting and potlatches among Lillooet Indians, in A Complex culture of the British Columbia Plateau. UBC Press, (B. Hayden ed.) 498.

  • Sproat, G. M. (1868). Scenes and studies of lavage life. Elder and Co: Smith.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stratmann, T. (forthcoming) (Ed.). A reservation economic freedom index.

  • Suttles, W. (1958). Private knowledge, morality, and social classes among the Coast Salish. American Anthropologist, 60, 497–507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suttles, W. (1960). Affinal ties, subsistence, and prestige among the Coast Salish. American Anthropologist, 62(2), 296–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1972). The edge of the jungle. In G. Tullock (Ed.), Explorations in the theory of anarchy (pp. 65–75). Blacksburg, VA: Center for Study of Public Choice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Umbeck, J. A. (1977). A theory of contract choice and the California Gold Rush. Journal of Law and Economics, 20, 421–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waldfogel, J. (1993). The deadweight loss of Christmas. The American Economic Review, 83(5), 1328–1336.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1947). The theory of social and economic organization. Free Press.

  • Williams, J. C. (1984). Fractional reserve banking in grain. Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 16(4), 488–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williams, J. (2006). Clam gardens: Aboriginal mariculture on Canada’s west coast. New Star Books.

  • Williamson, O. E. (1996). The mechanisms of governance. Oxford University Press.

  • Zerbe, R. O., & Anderson, C. L. (2001). Culture and fairness in the development of institutions in the California gold fields. The Journal of Economic History, 61(1), 114–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This essay condenses, compiles, and expands on my past works on the potlatch system of the Pacific Northwest Coast Tribes of North America (Johnsen 1986, 1998, 2001, 2003, 2006, 2007, 2009, 2016). Where appropriate, I provide specific references to these and other works. At the same time, I am sensitive to distracting the reader with too many references. I thank Terry Anderson for comments and encouragement on this project and acknowledge my great debt to him for urging me forward. At his invitation, I presented an early version of this essay at the Public Choice Workshop on The Political Economy of American Indian Policy at the Hoover Institution, Stanford University, co-sponsored by the Center for Governance and Markets, University of Pittsburgh, and the Institution for Humane Studies, May 16–18, 2022. Adam Crepelle, Ilia Murtazashvili, Dominic Parker, Thomas Stratmann, and other workshop participants for their helpful comments. I also thank Jesse Morin for his insights from the field of archaeology.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to D. Bruce Johnsen.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Johnsen, D.B. Potlatch economy: reciprocity among northwest coast Indians. Public Choice (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01062-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-023-01062-z

Keywords

JEL Codes

Navigation