Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Conflict and agreement in the collective choice of trade policies: implications for interstate disputes

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

From the collective choice perspective, this paper examines how different trade regimes have differing implications for two enemy countries' arming decisions in a three-country world with a neutral third-party state. We compare the two adversaries' aggregate arming (i.e., overall conflict intensity) and show that it is in ascending order for the following regimes: (i) a free trade agreement (FTA) between the adversaries, leaving the third-party state as a non-member, (ii) worldwide free trade in the presence of the interstate conflict, (iii) trade wars with Nash tariffs, and (iv) an FTA between the third country and one adversary, excluding the other adversary from the trade bloc. These results have policy implications for interstate conflicts. First, “dancing between two enemies” with an FTA results in lower aggregate arming than under worldwide free trade. Second, the world is “more dangerous” in tariff wars than under free trade. Third, an FTA between one adversary and the third party while keeping the other adversary as an outsider is conflict-aggravating since aggregate arming is the highest compared to all other trade regimes. We also analyze aggregate arming under a customs union (CU) and discuss differences/similarities in implications between a CU and an FTA for interstate conflicts.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Findlay and O'Rourke (2010) for issues on natural resources, conflict, and trade from the historical perspective.

  2. Viner (1950) was the first to provide insights into the trade-creation and trade-diversion effects of a customs union.

  3. For studies on economic integration through RTAs and related issues see, e.g., Bagwell and Staiger (1997, 1999), Baier and Bergstrand (2004), Freund and Ornelas (2010), and Bergstrand et al. (2016).

  4. There were debates about the frequency of wars and the trend toward peace. See, e.g., the detailed discussions in Harrison and Wolf (2012) and Gleditsch and Pickering (2014).

  5. See The Global Risks Report of 2018, World Economic Forum.

  6. For empirical studies on trade and conflict see, e.g., Polachek (1980), Barbieri (1996), Barbieri and Levy (1999), Reuveny and Kang (1998), Kim and Rousseau (2005), and Glick and Taylor (2010). Polachek (1980) shows that strengthening the extent of trade openness between enemy countries can reduce their conflicts in terms of overall armament expenditures (a result echoed by O'Neal and Russet, 1999). However, studies such as Kim and Rousseau (2005) find that the pacifying effect of greater trade openness can be neutral. Other studies, such as Barbieri (1996), find that extensive links through trade may increase the likelihood of armed conflicts. Barbieri and Levy (1999) show that war exerts no significant impact on trading relationships between adversaries. There appears no consensus on the trade–conflict nexus. For theoretical studies on trade and conflict see, e.g., Garfinkel et al. (2015) and Chang and Sellak (2019, 2021).

  7. For studies on third-party interventions in conflicts see, e.g., Regan (1998), Siqueira (2003), Rowlands and Carment (2006), Chang et al. (2007), Chang and Sanders (2009), Sanders and Walia (2014), and Chang and Sellak (2022).

  8. Our analysis may also have implications for WTO trade policymakers. A member country that is engaged in war with another member country is likely to aggravate conflict intensity when one adversary signs a preferential trade agreement with a neutral third-party state while excluding the other adversary as a non-member. The world would become "less dangerous" (that is, less military buildup) when WTO policymakers encourage all the countries (the adversaries and the third-party state) to form an FTA or a CU.

  9. As in Hadjiyiannis et al (2016), we assume that \(K^{A}\) and \(K^{B}\) are fixed costs of destruction to A and B.

  10. Since \(\tau_{a}^{B}\) and \(\tau_{a}^{C}\) are all positive under the protectionist regime, the non-arbitrage conditions imply that \(P_{a}^{A} < P_{a}^{B}\) and \(P_{a}^{A} < P_{a}^{C} .\) Country A thus has the comparative advantage in producing and exporting good \(a.\)

  11. An alternative approach leading to the same trade equilibrium condition (8) can be found in Appendix A-1.

  12. See Appendix A-2 for an alternative approach that results in the same trade equilibrium condition as in (11).

  13. This aligns with Hirshleifer (1991) in analyzing arming and the technology of conflict as an economic activity.

  14. These qualitative results in (27) are similar to those as shown in Lemmas 1 and 2 for the tariff comparisons under the protectionist regime.

  15. We substitute zero tariff rates into the price equations in (9), (12), and (15).

  16. We set the tariff rates for \(\tau_{c}^{A}\) and \(\tau_{a}^{C}\) to be zero in the price equations in (9), (12), and (15).

  17. Note that we assign some plausible values for \(K({\text{i.e.}}.,K = 0.2)\) in evaluating the derivative.

  18. See Eq. (26a) for the case of the FTA(A&B) regime and equation (a.6) for that of the CU(A&B) regime.

  19. For the two regimes FTA (A,C) and CU (A,C) that involve elements of asymmetry, the equilibrium levels of aggregate payoff are analytically unsolvable and hence are omitted.

  20. This result is consistent with the empirical finding of the study by Hadjiyiannis et al. (2016).

  21. For studies on armed conflicts that take into account the endogeneity of destructiveness see, e.g., Chang and Luo (2017) and Sanders and Walia (2014).

References

  • Bagwell, K., & Staiger, R. W. (1997). Multilateral cooperation during the formation of free trade areas. International Economic Review, 38, 291–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagwell, K., & Staiger, R. W. (1999). Regionalism and multilateral tariff cooperation. In J. Piggott & A. Woodland (Eds.), International trade policy and the Pacific Rim. Berlin: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bagwell, K., Bown, C. P., & Staiger, R. W. (2016). Is the WTO passé? Journal of Economic Literature, 54, 1125–1231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baier, S. L., & Bergstrand, J. H. (2004). Economic determinants of free trade agreements. Journal of International Economics, 64, 29–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. E. (1997). The causes of regionalism. World Economy, 20, 865–888.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. E., & Jaimovich, D. (2012). Are free trade agreements contagious? Journal of International Economics, 88, 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbieri, K. (1996). Economic interdependence: A path to peace or a source of interstate conflict? Journal of Peace Research, 33, 29–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbieri, K., & Levy, J. S. (1999). Sleeping with the enemy: The impact of war on trade. Journal of Peace Research, 36, 463–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrand, J. H., Egger, P. H., & Larch, M. (2016). Economic determinants of the timing of preferential trade agreement formations and enlargements. Economic Inquiry, 54, 315–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carrere, C. (2006). Revisiting the effects of regional trade agreements on trade flows with proper specification of the gravity model. European Economic Review, 50, 223–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, Y.-M., & Luo, Z. (2017). Endogenous destruction in conflict: Theory and extensions. Economic Inquiry, 55, 479–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, Y.-M., Potter, J., & Sanders, S. (2007). War and peace: Third-party intervention in conflict. European Journal of Political Economy, 23, 954–974.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, Y.-M., & Sanders, S. (2009). Raising the cost of rebellion: The role of third-party intervention in intrastate conflict. Defence and Peace Economics, 20, 149–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, Y.-M., & Sellak, M. (2019). A game-theoretic analysis of international trade and political disputes over external territories. Public Choice, 179, 209–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, Y. M., & Sellak, M. (2021). endogenous security, third-party trade, and interstate disputes: A conflict-theoretic analysis. Defence and Peace Economics, 1–23.

  • Chang, Y.-M., & Sellak, M. (2022). A theory of competing interventions by external powers in intrastate conflicts: Implications for war and armed peace. Applied Economics, 54, 3811–3822.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, Y.-M., & Wu, S.-J. (2020). Insecure resources, bilateral trade, and endogenous predation: A game-theoretic analysis of conflict and trade. Southern Economic Journal, 86, 1337–1371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Findlay, R., & O’Rourke, K. H. (2010). War, trade and natural resources: A historical perspective. The Oxford handbook of the economics of peace and conflict. Oxford University Press. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780195392777.013.0023

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Freund, C., & Ornelas, E. (2010). Regional trade agreements. Annual Review of Economics, 2, 139–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garfinkel, M., Skaperdas, R. S., & Syropoulos, C. (2015). Trade and insecure resources. Journal of International Economics, 95, 98–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gleditsch, K. S., & Pickering, S. (2014). Wars are becoming less frequent: A response to Harrison and Wolf. Economic History Review, 67, 214–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glick, R., & Taylor, A. M. (2010). Collateral damage: Trade disruption and the economic impact of war. Review of Economics and Statistics, 92, 102–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hadjiyiannis, C., Heracleous, M. S., & Tabakis, C. (2016). Regionalism and conflict: Peace creation and peace diversion. Journal of International Economics, 102, 141–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, M., & Wolf, N. (2012). The frequency of wars. Economic History Review, 65, 1055–1076.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1989). Conflict and rent-seeking success functions: Ratio vs. difference models of relative success. Public Choice, 63, 101–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1991). The technology of conflict as an economic activity. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 81, 130–134.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, Y. S., & Rousseau, D. L. (2005). The classical liberals were right (or half wrong): New tests of the ‘liberal peace’, 1960–1988. Journal of Peace Research, 42, 523–543.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, X., & Ornelas, E. (2014). Free trade agreements and the consolidation of democracy. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 6, 29–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. D., & Bronson, R. (1997). Alliances, preferential trading arrangements, and international trade. American Political Science Review, 91, 94–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. D., & Pevehouse, J. C. (2000). Trade blocs, trade flows, and international conflict. International Organization, 54, 775–808.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, P., Mayer, T., & Thoenig, M. (2008). Make trade not war? Review of Economic Studies, 75, 865–900.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, P., Mayer, T., & Thoenig, M. (2012). The geography of conflicts and regional trade agreements. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 4, 1–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, M. C. (2000). Trade and the predatory state: Ricardian exchange with armed competition for resources—A diagrammatic exposition. Public Choice, 182, 459–494.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oneal, J. R., & Russett, B. (1999). Assessing the liberal peace with alternative specifications: Trade still reduces conflict. Journal of Peace Research, 36, 423–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polachek, S. W. (1980). Conflict and trade. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 24, 55–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Regan, P. (1998). Choosing to intervene: Outside intervention in internal conflicts. Journal of Politics, 60, 754–759.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reuveny, R., & Kang, H. (1998). Bilateral trade and political conflict/cooperation: Do goods matter? Journal of Peace Research, 35, 581–602.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rowlands, D., & Carment, D. (2006). Force and bias: Towards a predictive model of effective third party intervention. Defence and Peace Economics, 17, 435–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanders, S., & Walia, B. (2014). Endogenous destruction in a model of armed conflict: Implications for conflict intensity, welfare, and third-party intervention. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 16, 604–609.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siqueira, K. (2003). Conflict and third-party intervention. Defence and Peace Economics, 14, 389–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skaperdas, S. (1996). Contest success functions. Economic Theory, 7, 283–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent seeking. In J. Buchanan, R. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Towards a theory of the rent-seeking society. Texas A&M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vicard, V. (2009). On trade creation and regional trade agreements: Does depth matter? Review of World Economics, 145, 167–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viner, J. (1950). The customs union issue. Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whalley, J. (1998). Why do countries seek regional trade agreements? In J. A. Frankel (Ed.), The Regionalization of the World Economy (pp. 63–90). Berlin: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Economic Forum. The global risks report of 2018, 13th Edition, Geneva.

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to William F. Shughart II, Simon Medcalfe, Shane Sanders, Shih-Jye Wu, and two anonymous referees for their insightful comments and helpful suggestions. The usual disclaimers apply.

Funding

This research did not receive any specific grant from funding agencies in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit sectors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Manaf Sellak.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendices

1.1 A-1: Market equilibrium condition for good a in country A

Alternatively, we have the following equilibrium condition:

$$(\alpha - \beta P_{a}^{A} ) + \left[ {(\alpha - \beta P_{a}^{B} ) - \left( {\frac{{G^{B} }}{{G^{A} + G^{B} }}} \right)3} \right] + (\alpha - \beta P_{a}^{C} ) = \left( {\frac{{G^{A} }}{{G^{A} + G^{B} }}} \right)3 - G^{A} - K^{A} .$$
(a.1)

The second bracket term on the LHS of Equation (a.1) is the consumption of good a by country B, \((\alpha - \beta P_{a}^{B} ),\) minus the quantity of the good that B appropriates from A, \({{[G^{B} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{[G^{B} } (}} \right. \kern-0pt} (}G^{A} + G^{B} )]3.\) This difference gives the amount of good \(a\) that country B imports from country A. The term on the RHS of Equation (a.1) is the quantity of good a that country A supplies, which is given by \(Z_{a}^{A}\) in (2). It is easy to verify that Equation (a.1) is identical to Eq. (8).

1.2 A-2: Market equilibrium condition for good b in country B

Alternatively, we have the following equilibrium condition:

$$\left[ {(\alpha - \beta P_{b}^{A} ) - \left( {\frac{{G^{A} }}{{G^{A} + G^{B} }}} \right)3} \right] + (\alpha - \beta P_{b}^{B} ) + (\alpha - \beta P_{b}^{C} ) = \left( {\frac{{G^{B} }}{{G^{A} + G^{B} }}} \right)3 - G^{B} - K^{B} .$$
(a.2)

The first bracket term on the LHS of Equation (a.2) is the consumption of good b by country A, \((\alpha - \beta P_{b}^{A} ),\) minus the amount of the good that A appropriates from B, \({{[G^{A} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{[G^{A} } (}} \right. \kern-0pt} (}G^{A} + G^{B} )]3.\) This difference gives the quantity of good b that country A imports from country B. The term on the RHS of Equation (a.2) is the quantity of good b that country B supplies, as given by \(Z_{b}^{B}\) in (2). It is easy to verify that Equation (a.2) is identical to Eq. (11).

1.3 A-3: Comparative static results for the protectionist regime

Based on the optimal tariffs under the protectionist regime, as shown in (22), we have the following results:

$$\begin{aligned} & \frac{{\partial \tau_{b}^{A,PR} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} = - \frac{{8G^{B} }}{{7\beta (G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }} < 0,\frac{{\tau_{b}^{A,PR} }}{{\partial G^{B} }} = - \frac{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} - 8G^{A} }}{{7\beta (G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }} < 0, \\ & \frac{{\partial \tau_{a}^{B,PR} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} = - \frac{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} - 8G^{B} }}{{7\beta (G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }} < 0,\frac{{\partial \tau_{a}^{B,PR} }}{{\partial G^{B} }} = - \frac{{8G^{A} }}{{7\beta (G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }} < 0, \\ & \frac{{\partial \tau_{a}^{C,PR} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} = - \frac{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} - G^{B} }}{{7\beta (G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }} < 0,\frac{{\partial \tau_{a}^{C,PR} }}{{\partial G^{B} }} = - \frac{{G^{A} }}{{7\beta (G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }} < 0, \\ & \frac{{\partial \tau_{b}^{C,PR} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} = - \frac{{G^{B} }}{{7\beta (G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }} < 0,\frac{{\partial \tau_{b}^{C,PR} }}{{\partial G^{B} }} = - \frac{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} - G^{A} }}{{7\beta (G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }} < 0, \\ & \tau_{c}^{A,PR} - \tau_{a}^{C,PR} = \frac{{G^{A} + K^{A} }}{7\beta } + \frac{{G^{B} }}{{7\beta (G^{A} + G^{B} )}} > 0, \\ & \tau_{c}^{B,PR} - \tau_{b}^{C,PR} = \frac{{G^{B} + K^{B} }}{7\beta } + \frac{{G^{A} }}{{7\beta (G^{A} + G^{B} )}} > 0. \\ \end{aligned}$$

1.4 A-4: Decomposing the aggregate payoff effect of arming for a contending country under the protectionist regime

Under symmetry, we can look at country A. The country's aggregate payoff function is

\(\begin{aligned} \Pi^{A} & = CS^{A} + PS^{A} + TR^{A} \\ & = \frac{1}{2\beta }[(\alpha - \beta P_{a}^{A} )^{2} + (\alpha - \beta P_{b}^{A} )^{2} + (\alpha - \beta P_{c}^{A} )^{2} ] + [P_{a}^{A} (Z_{a}^{A} ) + P_{b}^{A} (APP_{b}^{A} )] + (\tau_{b}^{A} M_{b}^{A} + \tau_{c}^{A} M_{c}^{A} ), \\ \end{aligned}\) where \(APP_{b}^{A} = {{[G^{A} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{[G^{A} } (}} \right. \kern-0pt} (}G^{A} + G^{B} )]3\) is the amount of good b appropriated by country A. Taking the derivative of \(SW^{A}\) with respect to \(G^{A}\) yields

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\partial \Pi^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} & = \left[ { - (\alpha - \beta P_{a}^{A} )\frac{{\partial P_{a}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} - (\alpha - \beta P_{b}^{A} )\frac{{\partial P_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}} \right] \\ & \quad + \left[ {\frac{{\partial P_{a}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}Z_{a}^{A} + \frac{{\partial Z_{{}}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}P_{a}^{A} + \frac{{\partial P_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}(APP_{b}^{A} ) + \frac{{\partial (APP_{b}^{A} )}}{{\partial G^{A} }}P_{b}^{A} } \right] \\ & \quad + \left( {\tau_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial M_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} + \tau_{c}^{A} \frac{{\partial M_{c}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} + M_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial \tau_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} + M_{c}^{A} \frac{{\partial \tau_{c}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}} \right). \\ \end{aligned}$$

Note that changes in country A's arming do not affect \(M_{c}^{A}\) and \(\tau_{c}^{A} .\) That is, \({{\partial M_{c}^{A} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial M_{c}^{A} } {\partial G^{A} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial G^{A} }} = 0\) and \({{\partial \tau_{c}^{A} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial \tau_{c}^{A} } {\partial G^{A} = 0}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial G^{A} = 0}}.\) Note also that country A's import demand for good b is given by its total consumption of good b minus the amount of the good appropriated, i.e., \(M_{b}^{A} = (\alpha - \beta P_{b}^{A} ) - A_{b} .\) We incorporate the zero derivatives and this definition into the derivative, after re-arranging terms. This exercise yields

$$\frac{{\partial \Pi^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} = \left[ {Z_{a}^{A} - (\alpha - \beta P_{a}^{A} )} \right]\frac{{\partial P_{a}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} + \left[ {\left( {\tau_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial M_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} + M_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial \tau_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}} \right) - M_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial P_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}} \right] + \frac{{\partial Z^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}P_{a}^{A} + \frac{{\partial (APP_{b}^{A} )}}{{\partial G^{A} }}P_{b}^{A} .$$
(a.3)

This derivative contains four different terms:

(i) The first term \([Z_{a}^{A} - (\alpha - \beta P_{a}^{A} )]\frac{{\partial P_{a}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}\) reflects a terms-of-trade effect of arming, which is payoff-increasing since \([Z_{a}^{A} - (\alpha - \beta P_{a}^{A} )] > 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial P_{a}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} > 0.\)

(ii) The second bracket term \([(\tau_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial M_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} + M_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial \tau_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}) - M_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial P_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}]\) reflects the (net) effect of country A's arming on tariff revenue from the import of good b minus import spending. Note that

$$\left( {\tau_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial M_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} + M_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial \tau_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}} \right) = \tau_{b}^{A} \left[ { - 3\frac{{G^{B} }}{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }}} \right] + M_{b}^{A} \left[ { - \frac{{8G^{B} }}{{7\beta (G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }}} \right] < 0.$$

We also consider how arming affects the price of good b in country A, which is \({{\partial P_{b}^{A} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial P_{b}^{A} } {\partial G^{A} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial G^{A} }}.\) This derivative is positive since country A's arming causes country B to raise its price for good b. The second bracket term \([(\tau_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial M_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} + M_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial \tau_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}) - M_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial P_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}]\) is thus unambiguously negative.

(iii) The third term \(\frac{{\partial Z_{a}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}P_{a}^{A}\) reflects an output distortion effect since allocating more resources to arming lowers the amount of resources for final good production and consumption, which is payoff-reducing.

(iv) The fourth term \(\frac{{\partial (APP_{b}^{A} )}}{{\partial G^{A} }}P_{b}^{A}\) is a resource appropriation effect, which is payoff-increasing.

It follows from (a.3) that we can decompose the effect of country A's arming on its aggregate payoff into four different effects as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\partial \Pi^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} & = \underbrace {{\left[ {Z_{a}^{A} - (\alpha - \beta P_{a}^{A} )} \right]\frac{{\partial P_{a}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}}}_{{{\mathrm{Export-revenue}}\,{\mathrm{effect}}\,{\mathrm{of}}\,{\mathrm{arming(+)}}}} \, + \underbrace {{\frac{{\partial (APP_{b}^{A} )}}{{\partial G^{A} }}P_{b}^{A} }}_{{{\mathrm{Resource-appropriation}}\,{\mathrm{effect}}\,{\mathrm{of}}\,{\mathrm{arming}}\,{(+)}}} \\ & \quad + \underbrace {{\left[ {\left( {\tau_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial M_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} + M_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial \tau_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}} \right) - M_{b}^{A} \frac{{\partial P_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}} \right]}}_{{{\mathrm{Tariff-revenue}}\,\&\,{\mathrm{import-spending}}\,{\mathrm{effect}}\,{\mathrm{of}}\,{\mathrm{arming}}\,{(-)}}}{ + }\underbrace {{\frac{{\partial Z_{a}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}P_{a}^{A} }}_{{{\mathrm{Output-distortion}}\,{\mathrm{effect}}\,{\mathrm{of}}\,{\mathrm{arming}}\,{(-)}}} = 0. \\ \end{aligned}$$

1.5 A-5: Optimal arming is lower under the FTA (A&B) regime than under worldwide free trade

We evaluate the slopes of \(SW_{i}\) (for \(i = A,B)\) under the WFT regime at the equilibrium arming allocations under the FTA(A&B) regime, \(\{ G_{{}}^{A,FTA(A\& B)} ,G_{{}}^{B,FTA(A\& B)} \} .\) With symmetry that \(G_{{}}^{A,FTA(A\& B)} = G_{{}}^{B,FTA(A\& B)} = G_{{}}^{FTA(A\& B)} ,\) we look at country A. Since \(\tau_{b}^{A} = \tau_{a}^{B} = 0\) under the FTA(A&B) regime, we have from the aggregate payoff decomposition in (24) that the FOC for country A is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\partial \Pi^{FTA(A\& B)} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} & = \left[ {Z_{a}^{A} - (\alpha - \beta P_{a}^{A,\,FTA(A\& \,B)} )} \right]\frac{{\partial P_{a}^{A,\,FTA(A\& \,B)} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} + \frac{{\partial APP_{b}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}P_{b}^{A,\,FTA(A\& B)} \\ & \quad + \frac{{\partial Z_{a}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}P_{a}^{A,\,FTA(A\& \,B)} = 0, \\ \end{aligned}$$

where \(APP_{b}^{A} = {{[3G^{A} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{[3G^{A} } (}} \right. \kern-0pt} (}G^{A} + G^{B} )]\) is the amount of good b appropriated by country A. Next, we derive results for each of the terms as shown in country A's FOC. Substituting \(\tau_{a}^{A,\,FTA(A\& B)} = {{(3 - G^{A} - K_{A} )} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{(3 - G^{A} - K_{A} )} {8\beta }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {8\beta }}\) from (26a) into \(P_{a}^{A,\,FTA(A\& B)}\) in (25) yields

$$P_{a}^{A,FTA(A\& B)} = \frac{{3\alpha + G^{A} + K^{A} - \beta \tau_{a}^{C} - 3}}{3\beta } = \frac{{8\alpha + 3G^{A} + 3K^{A} - 9}}{8\beta },$$
(a.4)

which implies that

$$\frac{{\partial P_{a}^{A,\,FTA(A\& \,B)} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} = \frac{3}{8\beta }.$$
(a.5)

The appropriation of good b by country A, \(APP_{b}^{A} = {{[3G^{A} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{[3G^{A} } (}} \right. \kern-0pt} (}G^{A} + G^{B} )],\) implies that

$$\frac{{\partial APP_{b} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} = \frac{{3G^{B} }}{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }}.$$
(a.6)

Country A's production of good a, \(Z_{a}^{A} = {{[3G^{A} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{[3G^{A} } (}} \right. \kern-0pt} (}G^{A} + G^{B} )] - G^{A} - K^{A}\), implies that

$$\frac{{\partial Z_{a}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} = \frac{{3G^{B} }}{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }} - 1.$$
(a.7)

Substituting \(\tau_{b}^{C} = {{(3 - G^{B} - K^{B} )} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{(3 - G^{B} - K^{B} )} {(8\beta )}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {(8\beta )}}\) from (26c) into \(P_{b}^{A,\,FTA(A\& B)}\) in (25) yields

$$P_{b}^{A,FTA(A\& B)} = \frac{{3\alpha + G^{B} + K^{B} - \beta \tau_{b}^{C} - 3}}{3\beta } = \frac{{8\alpha + 3G^{B} + 3K^{B} - 9}}{8\beta }.$$
(a.8)

The substitution of the results from (a.4)–(a.8) back into country A's first-order condition implies that

$$\begin{aligned} & \frac{{\partial \Pi^{FTA(A\& B)} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} = \underbrace {{\frac{3}{8\beta }\,\left[ {\left( {\frac{{3G^{A} }}{{G^{A} + G^{B} }} - G^{A} - K^{A} } \right) - \left[ {\alpha - \beta \left( {\frac{{8\alpha + 3G^{A} + 3K^{A} - 9}}{8\beta }} \right)} \right]} \right]}}_{{{\text{Export - revenue}}\,{\text{effect}}\,{\text{of}}\,{\text{arming}}\,{(+)}}} \\ & \quad + \underbrace {{\frac{{3G^{B} }}{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }}(\frac{{8\alpha + 3G^{B} + 3K^{B} - 9}}{8\beta })}}_{{{\text{Resource - appropriation}}\,{\text{effect}}\,{\text{of}}\,{\text{arming}}\,{(+)}}} + \underbrace {{\left[ {\frac{{3G^{B} }}{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }} - 1} \right]\left( {\frac{{8\alpha + 3G^{A} + 3K^{A} - 9}}{8\beta }} \right)}}_{{{\text{Output - distortion}}\,{\text{effect}}\,{\text{of}}\,{\text{arming (}} - {)}}}\, = 0 \\ \end{aligned}$$
(a.9)

where \(G^{A} = G^{B} = G_{{}}^{FTA(A\& B)} .\)

Under the WFT regime, the slope of country A's aggregate payoff function with respect to its arming is

$$\frac{{\partial \Pi^{WFT} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} = \frac{{\partial P_{a}^{A,WFT} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}\left[ {Z_{a}^{A} - (\alpha - \beta P_{a}^{A,WFT} )} \right] + \frac{{\partial (APP_{b}^{A} )}}{{\partial G^{A} }}P_{b}^{A,WFT} + \frac{{\partial Z_{a}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}P_{a}^{A,WFT} ,$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} & P_{a}^{A,\,WFT} = \frac{{3\alpha + G^{A} + K^{A} - 3}}{3\beta },\frac{{\partial P_{a}^{A,\,WFT} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} = \frac{1}{3\beta },P_{b}^{A,\,WFT} = \frac{{3\alpha + G^{B} + K^{B} - 3}}{3\beta },\frac{{\partial P_{b}^{A,\,WFT} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} = 0, \\ & APP_{b}^{A} = \frac{{3G^{A} }}{{G^{A} + G^{B} }},\frac{{\partial (APP_{b}^{A} )}}{{\partial G^{A} }} = \frac{{3G^{B} }}{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }}, \\ & Z_{a}^{A} = \frac{{3G^{A} }}{{G^{A} + G^{B} }} - G^{A} - K^{A} ,\frac{{\partial Z_{a}^{A} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} = \frac{{3G^{B} }}{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }} - 1. \\ \end{aligned}$$

After substituting, we have

$$\begin{aligned} & \frac{{\partial \Pi^{WFT} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} = \underbrace {{\frac{1}{3\beta }\left[ {\left( {\frac{{3G^{A} }}{{G^{A} + G^{B} }} - G^{A} - K^{A} } \right) - \left[ {\alpha - \beta \left( {\frac{{3\alpha + G^{A} + K^{A} - 3}}{3\beta }} \right)} \right]} \right]}}_{{{\text{Export - revenue}}\,{\text{effect}}\,{\text{of}}\,{\text{arming}}\,{(+)}}} \\ & \quad + \underbrace {{\frac{{3G^{B} }}{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }}\left( {\frac{{3\alpha + G^{B} + K^{B} - 3}}{3\beta }} \right)}}_{{{\text{Resource - appropriation}}\,{\text{effect}}\,{\text{of}}\,{\text{arming}}\,{(+)}}} + \underbrace {{\left[ {\frac{{3G^{B} }}{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }} - 1} \right]\left( {\frac{{3\alpha + G^{A} + K^{A} - 3}}{3\beta }} \right)}}_{{{\text{Output - distortion}}\,{\text{effect}}\,{\text{of}}\,{\text{arming}}\,{(} - {)}}} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(a.10)

where \(G^{A} = G^{B} = G_{{}}^{WFT} .\) We evaluate \({{\partial \Pi^{WFT} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial \Pi^{WFT} } {\partial G^{A} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial G^{A} }}\) in (a.10) at the FTA(A&B) equilibrium arming allocations where \(G_{{}}^{A} = G_{{}}^{B} = G_{{}}^{FTA(A\& B)} ,\) taking into account the FOC as shown in (a.9). We have the following:

(i) Comparing the export-revenue effect

$$\begin{aligned} & \frac{1}{3\beta }\left[ {\left( {\frac{{3G^{A} }}{{G^{A} + G^{B} }} - G^{A} - K^{A} } \right) - \left[ {\alpha - \beta \left( {\frac{{3\alpha + G^{A} + K^{A} - 3}}{3\beta }} \right)} \right]} \right] \\ & \quad - \frac{3}{8\beta }\,\left[ {\left( {\frac{{3G^{A} }}{{G^{A} + G^{B} }} - G^{A} - K^{A} } \right) - \left[ {\alpha - \beta \left( {\frac{{8\alpha + 3G^{A} + 3K^{A} - 9}}{8\beta }} \right)} \right]} \right] \\ & \quad \quad = \frac{{[7(G^{A} )^{2} + 7G^{A} G^{B} - 21G^{A} + 51G^{B} + 7(G^{A} + 7G^{B} )K^{A} ]}}{{576\beta (G^{A} + G^{B} )}} > 0. \\ \end{aligned}$$

(ii) Comparing the resource-appropriation effect

$$\frac{{3G^{B} }}{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }}\left( {\frac{{3\alpha + G^{B} + K^{B} - 3}}{3\beta }} \right)\, - \frac{{3G^{B} }}{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }}\left( {\frac{{8\alpha + 3G^{B} + 3K^{B} - 9}}{8\beta }} \right) = \frac{{3G^{B} }}{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }}\,\left( {\frac{{3 - G^{B} - K^{B} }}{24\beta }} \right) > 0.$$

(iii) Comparing the output-distortion effect

$$\begin{aligned} & \left[ {\frac{{3G^{B} }}{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }} - 1} \right]\left( {\frac{{3\alpha + G^{A} + K^{A} - 3}}{3\beta }} \right)\, - \,\left[ {\frac{{3G^{B} }}{{(G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }} - 1} \right]\left( {\frac{{8\alpha + 3G^{A} + 3K^{A} - 9}}{8\beta }} \right) \\ & \quad = - \frac{{[(G^{A} )^{2} + (G^{B} )^{2} + 2G^{A} G^{B} - 3G^{B} ](3 - G^{A} - K^{A} )}}{{24\beta (G^{A} + G^{B} )^{2} }} < 0. \\ \end{aligned}$$

Putting together the three effects, (i)–(iii), we have under symmetry (\(G_{{}}^{A} = G_{{}}^{B} = G_{{}}^{FTA(A\& B)}\)) that

$$\frac{{\partial \Pi^{WFT} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}\left| {_{{_{{G_{{}}^{A} = G_{{}}^{B} = G_{{}}^{FTA(A\& B)} }} }} } \right. = \frac{{[31(G_{{}}^{FTA(A\& B)} )^{2} - 93G_{{}}^{FTA(A\& B)} + 31G_{{}}^{FTA(A\& B)} K - 36K + 108]}}{{576\beta G_{{}}^{FTA(A\& B)} }} > 0.$$

The strict concavity of the aggregate payoff function implies that the optimal arming under the FTA(A&B) regime is lower than that of the global free trade regime. That is, \(G^{FTA(A\& B)} < G^{WFT} .\) Starting from the FTA(A&B) regime, a move to the WFT regime will encourage each contending country to increase arming, since the export-revenue effect plus the resource-appropriation effect (i.e., the marginal revenue of arming) exceeds the output-distortion effect (i.e., the marginal cost of arming).

A-6: Optimal arming allocations of two adversary countries that form a CU

For a CU between countries A and B, denoted as the CU(A&B) regime, we have \(\tau_{b}^{A,CU(A\& B)} = \;\tau_{a}^{B,CU(A\& B)} = 0.\) At the trade policy stage, A and B jointly determine a common external optimal tariff, denoted as \(\tau_{c}^{m,CU(A\& B)}\), on their imports of good c. Country C sets an optimal tariff structure, \(\left\{ {\tau_{a}^{C} ,\;\tau_{b}^{C} } \right\}\), on its imports of good a and b. Making use of the price equations in (9), (12), and (15), and considering that \(\tau_{b}^{A,CU(A\& B)} = \;\tau_{a}^{B,CU(A\& B)} = 0,\) the equilibrium prices under the CU(A&B) regime are

$$\begin{aligned} & P_{a}^{A,CU(A\& B)} = P_{a}^{B,CU(A\& B)} = \frac{{3\alpha - \beta \tau_{a}^{C} - (3 - G^{A} - K^{A} )}}{3\beta }, \\ & P_{b}^{A,CU(A\& B)} = P_{b}^{B,CU(A\& B)} = \frac{{3\alpha - \beta \tau_{b}^{C} - (3 - G^{B} - K^{B} )}}{3\beta }, \\ & P_{a}^{C,CU(A\& B)} = \frac{{3\alpha + 2\beta \tau_{a}^{C} - (3 - G^{A} - K^{A} )}}{3\beta },P_{b}^{C,CU(A\& B)} = \frac{{3\alpha + 2\beta \tau_{b}^{C} - (3 - G^{B} - K^{B} )}}{3\beta }, \\ & P_{c}^{A,CU(A\& B)} = \frac{{3\alpha + \beta \tau_{c}^{m,CU(A\& B)} - 3}}{3\beta },P_{c}^{B,CU(A\& B)} = \frac{{3\alpha + \beta \tau_{c}^{m,CU(A\& B)} - 3}}{3\beta }, \\ & P_{c}^{C,CU(A\& B)} = \frac{{3\alpha - 2\beta \tau_{c}^{m,CU(A\& B)} - 3}}{3\beta }. \\ \end{aligned}$$

In determining their common external tariff on the import of good c, countries A and B jointly maximize their aggregate payoffs: \(\Pi^{A\& B,CU(A\& B)} = \Pi^{A,CU(A\& B)} + \Pi^{B,CU(A\& B)} ,\) where

$$\Pi^{A,CU(A\& B)} = CS^{A,CU(A\& B)} + PS^{A,CU(A\& B)} + \tau_{c}^{m,CU(A\& B)} M_{b}^{A,CU(A\& B)} ,$$
(a.11)
$$\Pi^{B,CU(A\& B)} = CS^{B,CU(A\& B)} + PS^{B,CU(A\& B)} + \tau_{c}^{m,CU(A\& B)} M_{b}^{B,CU(A\& B)} .$$
(a.12)

The FOC for aggregate payoff maximization implies that the common external tariff on good c is

$$\tau_{c}^{m,CU(A\& B)} = \frac{6}{5\beta }.$$
(a.13)

Country C determines an optimal tariff structure,\(\{ \tau_{a}^{C} ,\tau_{b}^{C} \} ,\) to maximize its domestic aggregate payoff:

$$\Pi^{C,CU(A\& B)} = CS^{C,CU(A\& B)} + PS^{C,CU(A\& B)} + \tau_{a}^{C,CU(A\& B)} M_{a}^{C,CU(A\& B)} + \tau_{b}^{C,CU(A\& B)} M_{b}^{C,CU(A\& B)} .$$

The FOCs for country C imply that the optimal tariffs are

$$\tau_{a}^{C,CU(A\& B)} = \frac{{(3 - G^{A} - K^{A} )}}{8\beta }\,\,{\text{and}}\,\,\tau_{b}^{C,CU(A\& B)} = \frac{{(3 - G^{B} - K^{B} )}}{8\beta }.$$
(a.14)

We proceed to the security stage at which A and B independently and simultaneously determine their optimal arming decisions. Substituting the optimal tariffs from (a.13) and (a.14) into the aggregate payoff functions in (a.11) and (a.12), we have the FOCs for A and B:

$$\frac{{\partial \Pi^{A,CU(A\& B)} }}{{\partial G^{A} }} = 0\,\,{\text{and}}\,\,\frac{{\partial \Pi^{B,CU(A\& B)} }}{{\partial G^{B} }} = 0.$$

Denote the Nash equilibrium levels of arming as \(\{ G^{A,CU(A\& B)} ,G^{B,CU(A\& B)} \} .\) Under symmetry in all dimensions, we have \(G^{A,CU(A\& B)} = G^{B,CU(A\& B)} = G^{CU(A\& B)} .\) Calculating the optimal arming yields

$$G^{CU(A\& B)} = \frac{{\sqrt {4096\alpha^{2} - 3159 + K(1521K + 4992\alpha - 3510)} }}{78} - \frac{32\alpha }{{39}} - \frac{K}{2} + \frac{3}{2}.$$

It is easy to verify that \(G^{FTA(A\& B)} = G^{CU(A\& B)} .\) Evaluating the slope \({{\partial \Pi^{A,CU(A\& B)} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial \Pi^{A,CU(A\& B)} } {\partial G^{A} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial G^{A} }}\) at the point where \(G^{A} = G^{A,PR}\), we have

$$\frac{{\partial \Pi^{A,CU(A\& B)} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}\left| {_{{G^{A} = G^{A,PR} }} } \right. < 0,$$

which implies that \(G^{A,CU(A\& B)} = G^{B,CU(A\& B)} = G^{CU(A\& B)} < G^{A,PR} .\)

2.1 A-7: CU between one contending country and a neutral third country

For the scenario where there is a CU between countries A and C, denoted as the CU(A&C) regime, we have \(\tau_{c}^{A,CU(A\& C)} = \;\tau_{a}^{C,CU(A\& C)} = 0.\) At the trade policy stage, countries A and C jointly determine a common external tariff, denoted as \(\tau_{b}^{m,CU(A\& C)} ,\) on their imports of good b. Simultaneously, country B sets an optimal tariff structure, \(\{ \tau_{a}^{B} ,\tau_{c}^{B} \} ,\) on its imports of goods a and c. Making use of the price equations in (9), (12), and (15), and considering that \(\tau_{c}^{A,CU(A\& C)} = \;\tau_{a}^{C,CU(A\& C)} = 0,\) the equilibrium prices under the CU(A&C) regime are

$$\begin{aligned} & P_{a}^{A,CU(A\& C)} = P_{a}^{C,CU(A\& C)} = \frac{{3\alpha - \beta \tau_{a}^{B} - (3 - G^{A} - K^{A} )}}{3\beta }, \\ & P_{c}^{A,CU(A\& C)} = P_{c}^{C,CU(A\& C)} = \frac{{3\alpha - \beta \tau_{c}^{b,CU(A\& C)} - 3}}{3\beta }, \\ & P_{a}^{B,CU(A\& C)} = \frac{{3\alpha + 2\beta \tau_{a}^{B} - (3 - G^{A} - K^{A} )}}{3\beta },P_{b}^{A,CU(A\& C)} = \frac{{3\alpha + \beta \tau_{b}^{m,CU(A\& C)} - (3 - G^{B} - K^{B} )}}{3\beta }, \\ & P_{b}^{B,CU(A\& C)} = \frac{{3\alpha - 2\beta \tau_{b}^{m,CU(A\& C)} - (3 - G^{B} - K^{B} )}}{3\beta }, \\ & P_{b}^{C,CU(A\& C)} = \frac{{3\alpha + \beta \tau_{b}^{m,CU(A\& C)} - (3 - G^{B} - K^{B} )}}{3\beta },P_{c}^{B,CU(A\& C)} = \frac{{3\alpha + 2\beta \tau_{c}^{B} - 3}}{3\beta }. \\ \end{aligned}$$

In determining their tariff on the import of good b, countries A and C set a common external tariff that maximizes their aggregate payoff: \(\Pi^{AC,CU(A\& C)} = \Pi^{A,CU(A\& C)} + \Pi^{C,CU(A\& C)}\), where

$$\begin{aligned} & \Pi^{A,CU(A\& C)} = CS^{A,CU(A\& C)} + PS^{A,CU(A\& C)} + \tau_{b}^{m,CU(A\& C)} M_{b}^{A,CU(A\& C)} , \\ & \Pi^{C,CU(A\& C)} = CS^{C,CU(A\& C)} + PS^{C,CU(A\& C)} + \tau_{b}^{m,CU(A\& C)} M_{b}^{C,CU(A\& C)} . \\ \end{aligned}$$

The FOC for the joint payoff maximization problem is \({{\partial \Pi^{AC,CU(A\& C)} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial \Pi^{AC,CU(A\& C)} } {\partial \tau^{m,CU(A\& C)} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial \tau^{m,CU(A\& C)} }} = 0.\) Solving for the optimal common external tariff yields

$$\tau_{b}^{m,CU(A\& C)} = \frac{{2G^{B} (3 - G^{A} - G^{B} ) - 3G^{A} - 2K^{B} (G^{A} + G^{B} )}}{{5\beta (G^{A} + G^{B} )}}.$$
(a.15)

Similarly, country B determines an optimal tariff structure,\(\{ \tau_{a}^{B} ,\tau_{c}^{B} \} ,\) to maximize its domestic aggregate payoff:

$$\Pi^{B,CU(A\& C)} = CS^{B,CU(A\& C)} + PS^{B,CU(A\& C)} + \tau_{a}^{B,CU(A\& C)} M_{a}^{B,CU(A\& C)} + \tau_{c}^{B,CU(A\& C)} M_{c}^{B,CU(A\& C)}$$

Making use of the FOCs for country B, we solve for its optimal tariffs:

$$\tau_{a}^{B,CU(A\& C)} = \frac{{G^{A} (3 - G^{A} - G^{B} ) - 6G^{B} - K^{A} (G^{A} + G^{B} )}}{{8\beta (G^{A} + G^{B} )}}\,\,{\text{and}}\,\,\tau_{c}^{B,CU(A\& C)} = \frac{3}{8\beta }.$$
(a.16)

We proceed to the security stage at which countries A and B independently and simultaneously make their arming decisions. Country A determines an optimal arming, denoted as \(G^{A,CU(A\& C)} ,\) that maximizes its aggregate payoff:

$$\Pi^{A,CU(A\& C)} = CS^{A,CU(A\& C)} + PS^{A,CU(A\& C)} + \tau_{b}^{m,CU(A\& C)} M_{b}^{A,CU(A\& C)} .$$

Evaluating the slope \({{\partial \Pi^{A,CU(A\& C)} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial \Pi^{A,CU(A\& C)} } {\partial G^{A} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial G^{A} }}\) at the point where \(G^{A} = G^{A,PR}\), we have

$$\frac{{\partial \Pi^{A,CU(A\& C)} }}{{\partial G^{A} }}\left| {_{{G^{A} = G^{A,PR} }} } \right. > 0.$$

The strict concavity of the aggregate payoff function implies that \(G^{A,CU(A\& C)} > G^{A,PR} .\)

Country B determines an optimal arming, denoted as \(G^{B,CU(A\& C)} ,\) that maximizes its aggregate payoff: \(\Pi^{B,CU(A\& C)} = CS^{B,CU(A\& C)} + PS^{B,CU(A\& C)} + \tau_{c}^{B} M_{c}^{B,CU(A\& C)} + \tau_{a}^{B} M_{a}^{B,CU(A\& C)} .\)

Evaluating the slope \({{\partial \Pi^{B,CU(A\& C)} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial \Pi^{B,CU(A\& C)} } {\partial G^{A} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\partial G^{A} }}\) at the point where \(G^{B} = G^{B,PR}\), we have

$$\frac{{\partial \Pi^{B,CU(A\& C)} }}{{\partial G^{B} }}\left| {_{{G^{B} = G^{B,PR} }} } \right. < 0,$$

which implies that \(G^{B,CU(A\& C)} < G^{B,PR} .\)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chang, YM., Sellak, M. Conflict and agreement in the collective choice of trade policies: implications for interstate disputes. Public Choice 199, 103–135 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-022-01040-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-022-01040-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation