Skip to main content
Log in

Evolution, uncertainty, and the asymptotic efficiency of policy

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Politics, like any social system, involves selection mechanisms. This paper presents a model of politics as an evolutionary process. Our model yields three main results. First, the political process selects for efficient policies in the long run. We call that attribute asymptotic efficiency. Second, bargaining amongst interest groups bounds the inefficiencies that can exist in the short run. Potential inefficiency declines when organizing interest groups becomes less costly. Finally, policies that appear to be inefficient in a static analysis can be efficient once economists consider the dynamic nature of political decisions. We argue that viewing the political process as a selection mechanism allows political economists to use efficiency as a criterion for positive economic analysis. In our approach, applied political economy involves looking for relevant costs that make the policy efficient. However, our approach does not rob political economists of the ability to make meaningful normative statements; it only constrains the type of statements made.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See IGM Forum (n.d.).

  2. While many definitions of “efficiency” are possible and it is not always clear what individual authors have in mind, we mean Kaldor-Hicks efficiency, whereby an outcome is efficient if the benefits outweigh the costs and could, in principle, involve transfers to make the policy Pareto efficient, whether or not those who benefit actually compensate anyone. Buchanan (1959) discusses criticisms of Kaldor-Hicks efficiency, notably that side-payments (compensation) to those who lose from policy changes are almost always hypothetical. Without actual compensation, "the whole controversy over the appropriate tests [for welfare-enhancing policy] becomes meaningless" (Buchanan, 1959, p. 128). Our arguments extend Buchanan's insight. We discuss Buchanan's (1959) paradigm for doing welfare economics more fully in the Conclusion. However, in our model, compensation is paid, so the distinction does not matter: Kaldor-Hicks efficient policies are Pareto efficient.

  3. By efficiency, we are referring to what we call “planner efficiency”. In doing so, we follow how most economists use the term, which implicitly ignores the political costs of implementing a policy. Our result that policies are efficient (in that sense) in the long run is stronger than saying that they are efficient once we account for all costs, a criterion adopted by Cheung (1998) and Leeson (2020), among others. We elaborate on the distinction in the next section.

  4. We could similarly assume that political actors maximize some measure of “political success”, such as votes. However, for simplicity, we assume that they maximize wealth, since the rest of our analysis is framed in terms net of simple cost and benefits.

  5. While it is referred to as the “Coase” theorem, the theorem is credited to George Stigler and bears little resemblance to Coase’s interpretation of his own paper. See, e.g., Medema (1994), McCloskey (1998) and Albrecht and Kogelmann (2020). On the application of the Coase theorem to politics, see Acemoglu (2003), Parisi (2003), and Munger (2019).

  6. Note that we have assumed that \(\mu \ge 0\). If \(\mu <0\), then the net costs of the policy would have a negative drift over time and eventually would be insignificant without any action needed.

  7. Multiplying both side of the discrete time representation by \(1+\rho \Delta t\) and rearranging yields.

    $$\rho V\left(N\right)=\frac{1}{\Delta t}EdV,$$

    where \(EdV:=EV(N{^{\prime}},t+\Delta t)-V(N,t)\). Taking the limit as \(\Delta t\) goes to zero yields the continuous time representation.

  8. For recent work, see Brendon (2013), Lockwood and Weinzierl (2015), Lockwood and Weinzierl (2016), and Heathcote and Tsujiyama (2021).

References

  • Acemoglu, D. (2003). Why not a political Coase theorem? Social conflict, commitment, and politics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 620–652.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P., Alesina, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Endogenous political institutions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(2), 565–611.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albrecht, B. C., & Kogelmann, B. (2020). Coasean causal inference: Using models as foils [working paper]. https://www.briancalbrecht.com/Albrecht_Kogelmann_Coasean_Inference.pdf

  • Alchian, A. A. (1950). Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy, 58(3), 211–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashworth, S. (2012). Electoral accountability: Recent theoretical and empirical work. Annual Review of Political Science, 15(1), 183–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbera, S., & Jackson, M. O. (2004). Choosing how to choose: Self-stable majority rules and constitutions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(3), 1011–1048.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron, D. P. (1994). Electoral competition with informed and uniformed voters. The American Political Science Review, 88(1), 33–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bassetto, M., & Sargent, T. J. (2006). Politics and efficiency of separating capital and ordinary government budgets. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4), 1167–1210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3), 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., Coyne, C. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2007). Saving government failure theory from itself: Recasting political economy from an Austrian perspective. Constitutional Political Economy, 18(2), 127–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brendon, C. (2013). Efficiency, equity, and optimal income taxation [working paper]. https://cadmus.eui.eu/handle/1814/27937

  • Breton, A. (1993). Toward a presumption of efficiency in politics. Public Choice, 77(1), 53–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1949). The pure theory of government finance: A suggested approach. Journal of Political Economy, 57(6), 496–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1959). Positive economics, welfare economics, and political economy. The Journal of Law and Economics, 2, 124–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1975). A contractarian paradigm for applying economic theory. The American Economic Review, 65(2), 225–230.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1987). The constitution of economic policy. Science, 236(4807), 1433–1436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chamley, C. (1986). Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives. Econometrica, 54(3), 607–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chetty, R., Hendren, N., & Katz, L. F. (2016). The effects of exposure to better neighborhoods on children: New evidence from the moving to opportunity experiment. American Economic Review, 106(4), 855–902.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, S. (1968). Private property rights and sharecropping. Journal of Political Economy, 76(6), 1107–1122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, S. (1970). The structure of a contract and the theory of a non-exclusive resource. The Journal of Law and Economics, 13(1), 49–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, S. (1973). The fable of the bees: An economic investigation. The Journal of Law and Economics, 16(1), 11–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, S. (1998). The transaction costs paradigm. Economic Inquiry, 36(4), 514–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clemens, M. A. (2011). Economics and emigration: Trillion-dollar bills on the sidewalk? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(3), 83–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law & Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. A., & Mirrlees, J. A. (1971). Optimal taxation and public production I: Production efficiency. The American Economic Review, 61(1), 8–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. Harper Collins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duggan, J., & Martinelli, C. (2017). The political economy of dynamic elections: Accountability, commitment, and responsiveness. Journal of Economic Literature, 55(3), 916–984.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M. P. (1981). Retrospective voting in American national elections. Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox, J. (2007). Government transparency and policymaking. Public Choice, 131(1/2), 23–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gennaioli, N., & Shleifer, A. (2007). The evolution of common law. Journal of Political Economy, 115(1), 43–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golosov, M., Kocherlakota, N., & Tsyvinski, A. (2003). Optimal indirect and capital taxation. The Review of Economic Studies, 70(3), 569–587.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1996). Electoral competition and special interest politics. The Review of Economic Studies, 63(2), 265–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heathcote, J., & Tsujiyama, H. (2021). Optimal income taxation: Mirrlees meets Ramsey. Journal of Political Economy, 129(11), 3141–3184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendrickson, J. R. (2019). U.S. maritime policy and economic efficiency (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. 3486330). Social Science Research Network.

  • Hendrickson, J. R. (2020). Usury enforcement as an alternative to capital taxation in pre-modern states (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. 3652489). Social Science Research Network.

  • Hendrickson, J. R., Salter, A. W., & Albrecht, B. C. (2018). Preventing plunder: Military technology, capital accumulation, and economic growth. Journal of Macroeconomics, 58, 154–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IGM Forum. (n.d.). Steel and aluminum tariffs. https://www.igmchicago.org/surveys/steel-and-aluminum-tariffs/

  • Judd, K. L. (1985). Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of Public Economics, 28(1), 59–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keen, M., & Wildasin, D. (2004). Pareto-efficient international taxation. American Economic Review, 94(1), 259–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2012). Ordeals. The Journal of Law and Economics, 55(3), 691–714.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2020). Logic is a harsh mistress: Welfare economics for economists. Journal of Institutional Economics, 16(2), 145–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood, B. B., & Weinzierl, M. (2015). De gustibus non est taxandum: Heterogeneity in preferences and optimal redistribution. Journal of Public Economics, 124, 74–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood, B. B., & Weinzierl, M. (2016). Positive and normative judgments implicit in U.S. tax policy, and the costs of unequal growth and recessions. Journal of Monetary Economics, 77, 30–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lohmann, S. (1998). An information rationale for the power of special interests. The American Political Science Review, 92(4), 809–827.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maskin, E., & Tirole, J. (2004). The politician and the judge: Accountability in government. American Economic Review, 94(4), 1034–1054.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. (1998). The so-called Coase theorem. Eastern Economic Journal, 24(3), 367–371.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCormick, R. E., Shughart, W. F., & Tollison, R. D. (1984). The disinterest in deregulation. The American Economic Review, 74(5), 1075–1079.

    Google Scholar 

  • Medema, S. G. (1994). The myth of two Coases: What Coase is really saying. Journal of Economic Issues, 28(1), 208–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munger, M. C. (2019). Tullock and the welfare costs of corruption: There is a “political Coase Theorem.” Public Choice, 181(1), 83–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1994). Economic performance through time. The American Economic Review, 84(3), 359–368.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1971). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parisi, F. (2003). Political Coase theorem. Public Choice, 115(1), 1–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. The Journal of Law & Economics, 19(2), 211–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (1974). Theories of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5(2), 335–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Priest, G. L. (1977). The common law process and the selection of efficient rules. The Journal of Legal Studies, 6(1), 65–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, P. H. (1977). Why is the common law efficient? The Journal of Legal Studies, 6(1), 51–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1966). The theory of price (3rd ed.). MacMillan Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1992). Law or economics? Journal of Law and Economics, 35(2), 455–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stokey, N. L. (2008). The economics of inaction: Stochastic control models with fixed costs. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, E. A. (2008). A rational alternative to social contract theory and correspondingly new theory of optimal government [working paper]. Available from authors upon request.

  • Thompson, E. A. (1974). Taxation and national defense. Journal of Political Economy, 82(4), 755–782.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, E. A. (1979). An economic basis for the “national defense argument” for aiding certain industries. Journal of Political Economy, 87(1), 1–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, E. A., & Faith, R. L. (1981). A pure theory of strategic behavior and social institutions. The American Economic Review, 71(3), 366–380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, E. A., & Hickson, C. R. (2001). Ideology and the evolution of vital institutions. Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tollison, R. D. (1988). Public choice and legislation. Virginia Law Review, 74(2), 339–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R., Shepsle, K. A., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89(4), 642–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1989). Why democracies produce efficient results. Journal of Political Economy, 97(6), 1395–1424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Brian C. Albrecht.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Albrecht, B.C., Hendrickson, J.R. & Salter, A.W. Evolution, uncertainty, and the asymptotic efficiency of policy. Public Choice 192, 169–188 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-022-00978-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-022-00978-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation