Skip to main content
Log in

Competitive lobbying in the influence production process and the use of spatial econometrics in lobbying research

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Much of the lobbying process is inherently competitive: when lobbyists with opposing goals attempt to move outcomes in their preferred direction, successful lobbying by one actor will disadvantage opposing actors. This article theorizes and quantifies the indirect form of influence that competing lobbying actors exert on each other. While existing theories of competitive lobbying have focused on legislation, we argue that all stages of the lobbying process involve competition. Our findings make two contributions to the study of lobbying influence. First, using spatial econometrics, we present the first estimates of how the success of one lobbying actor is shaped by the lobbying activities of opposing actors. Second, we study competition in three diverse empirical settings that capture three different stages of the lobbying process: (1) lobbying camps favoring opposite legislative outcomes in five European countries, (2) US lobbying firms competing over client resources, and (3) corporations competing for administrative trade barriers in 19 World Trade Organization member countries. The results reveal important insights about how interdependence among lobbyists conditions their effectiveness. Our application of spatial techniques to model interdependence between actors is useful for all scholars who want to take competitive or collaborative diffusion mechanisms into account in studies of lobbying and public policy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

Data and code for replication can be found here: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/MZF8EH.

Notes

  1. For more on the additional phases of the lobbying and policymaking processes, see Godwin et al. (2013).

  2. We do not reproduce Becker’s full model here. Rather, we rely on the comparative statics he derives to show how his model predicts that changes in camp characteristics will affect competition (Becker 1983, pp. 378–380).

  3. The distinction between contract and in-house lobbying is important. In the former, the interest group hires one or more professional lobbying firms to act on its behalf. In the latter, the group hires one or more lobbyists to work in a dedicated public affairs division of the group. We focus on the former because competition is more clearly observable.

  4. Note that the practice is sanctioned by the World Trade Organization and, as previous research has shown, antidumping duties have large negative effects on competition and the volume of international trade (Blonigen & Prusa, 2003; Bown & Crowley, 2007).

  5. For more information, see: https://govlis.eu/.

  6. Link to the CRP bulk data: https://www.opensecrets.org/bulk-data.

  7. The countries are Argentina, Australia, Brazil, Canada, Colombia, the European Union, India, Israel, Japan, Malaysia, Mexico, the Philippines, Russia, South Africa, South Korea, Taiwan, Turkey, Ukraine, and the United States.

  8. We obtain similar results when we enter a binary measure of success and the variable is not log transformed.

  9. The inverse index (1-HHI) ranges from 0 (most homogenous: only one group type in the camp) to 1 minus 1/number of different group types, which is the most diverse distribution. For more details, see Appendix A.2.

  10. When estimating Moran’s I—without conditioning on covariates—diffusion is estimated as −0.98; we cannot reject the possibility that it is exactly −1. The smaller spatial diffusion parameter in the full model indicates that part of the competition between camps is captured by the camp-level characteristics that are included in the model.

  11. We obtain the same result using the log of inverse distance, a convex functional form, or a binary matrix.

References

  • Austen-Smith, D., & Wright, J. R. (1992). Competitive lobbying for a legislator’s vote. Social Choice and Welfare, 9(3), 229–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D., & Wright, J. R. (1994). Counteractive lobbying. American Journal of Political Science, 38(1), 25–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ban, P., Palmer, M., & Schneer, B. (2019). From the halls of Congress to K Street: Government experience and its value for lobbying. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 44, 713–752.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron, D. P. (2006). Competitive lobbying and supermajorities in a majority-rule institution. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 108(4), 607–642.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumgartner, F. R., Berry, J. M., Hojnacki, M., Kimball, D. C., & Leech, B. (2009). Lobbying and policy change: Who wins, who loses, and why. University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3), 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berkhout, J., Carroll, B. J., Braun, C., Chalmers, A. W., Destrooper, T., Lowery, D., Otjes, S., & Rasmussen, A. (2015). Interest organizations across economic sectors: Explaining interest group density in the European Union. Journal of European Public Policy, 22(4), 462–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binderkrantz, A. S., Christiansen, P. M., & Pedersen, H. H. (2014). A privileged position? The influence of business interests in government consultations. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 24(4), 879–896.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blonigen, B. A., & Prusa, T. J. (2003). Antidumping. In E. K. Choi & J. Harrigan (Eds.), Handbook of international trade (pp. 251–284). Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Bown, C. (2016). Global antidumping database. Wiley Online Library. https://datacatalog.worldbank.org/dataset/temporary-trade-barriers-database-includingglobal-antidumping-database/resource/dc7b361e

  • Bown, C., & Crowley, M. A. (2007). Trade deflection and trade depression. Journal of International Economics, 72(1), 176–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, R. A. (1961). Who governs? Democracy and power in an American city. Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duggan, J., & Gao, J. (2020). Lobbying as a multidimensional tug of war. Social Choice and Welfare, 54(1), 141–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dür, A. (2008). Measuring interest group influence in the EU: A note on methodology. European Union Politics, 9(4), 559–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dür, A., Bernhagen, P., & Marshall, D. (2015). Interest group success in the European Union: When (and why) does business lose? Comparative Political Studies, 48(8), 951–983.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dür, A., & Mateo, G. (2013). Gaining access or going public? Interest group strategies in five European countries. European Journal of Political Research, 52(5), 660–686.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egerod, B. C. K., & Justesen, M. (2021). Asset specificity, corporate protection and trade policy: Firm-level evidence from antidumping petitions in nineteen jurisdictions. British Journal of Political Science Online first, 1–10.

  • Furlong, S. R., & Kerwin, C. M. (2005). Interest group participation in rule making: A decade of change. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 15(3), 353–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furnas, A. C., Heaney, M. T., & LaPira, T. M. (2019). The partisan ties of lobbying firms. Research & Politics, 6(3), 205316801987703.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Godwin, K., Ainsworth, S. H., & Godwin, E. (2013). Lobbying and policymaking. CQ Press, an Imprint of Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gray, V., & Lowery, D. (1996). A niche theory of interest representation. The Journal of Politics, 58(1), 91–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gray, V., & Lowery, D. (1998). To lobby alone or in a flock. American Politics Quarterly, 26(1), 5–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. The American Economic Review, 84(4), 833–850.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2001). Special interest politics. MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haider-Markel, D. P. (1997). Interest group survival: Shared interests versus competition for resources. The Journal of Politics, 59(3), 903–912.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanegraaff, M., & Pritoni, A. (2019). United in fear: Interest group coalition formation as a weapon of the weak? European Union Politics, 20(2), 198–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heaney, M. (2014). Multiplex networks and interest group influence reputation: An exponential random graph model. Social Networks, 36, 66–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heaney, M., & Leifeld, P. (2018). Contributions by interest groups to lobbying coalitions. The Journal of Politics, 80(2), 494–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hojnacki, M. (1997). Interest groups’ decisions to join alliances or work alone. American Journal of Political Science, 41(1), 61–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holyoke, T. (2009). Interest group competition and coalition formation. American Journal of Political Science, 53(2), 360–375.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holyoke, T. (2011). Competitive interests. Georgetown University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Junk, W. M. (2019). When diversity works: The effects of coalition composition on the success of lobbying coalitions. American Journal of Political Science, 63(3), 660–674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Junk, W. M., & Rasmussen, A. (2019). Framing by the flock: Collective issue definition and advocacy duccess. Comparative Political Studies, 52(4), 483–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelejian, H., & Piras, G. (2017). Spatial models: Basic issues. In H. Kelejian & G. Piras (Eds.), Spatial econometrics (pp. 1–10). Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klüver, H. (2013a). Lobbying as a collective enterprise: Winners and losers of policy formulation in the European Union. Journal of European Public Policy, 20(1), 59–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klüver, H. (2013b). Lobbying in the European Union: Interest groups, lobbying coalitions, and policy change. Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A. O. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. The American Economic Review, 64(3), 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffont, J. J., & Tirole, J. (1991). The politics of government decision-making: A theory of regulatory capture. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(4), 1089–1127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • LaPira, T. M., Thomas, H. F., & Baumgartner, F. R. (2014). The two worlds of lobbying: Washington lobbyists in the core and on the periphery. Interest Groups & Advocacy, 3(3), 219–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leech, B. L. (2010). Lobbying and influence. In L. S. Maisel, J. M. Berry, G. C. Edwards, & B. L. Leech (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of American political parties and interest groups (pp. 534–552). Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • LeSage, J. P., & Dominguez, M. (2012). The importance of modeling spatial spillovers in public choice analysis. Public Choice, 150(3), 525–545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • LeSage, J. P., & Pace, R. K. (2014). Interpreting spatial econometric models. In M. M. Fischer & P. Nijkamp (Eds.), Handbook of regional science (pp. 1535–1552). Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • LeSage, J. P., Pace, R. K., Lam, N., Campanella, R., & Liu, X. (2011). New Orleans business recovery in the aftermath of Hurricane Katrina. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 174(4), 1007–1027.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lorenz, G. M. (2020). Prioritized interests: Diverse lobbying coalitions and congressional committee agenda setting. The Journal of Politics, 82(1), 225–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lowery, D. (2013). Lobbying influence: Meaning, measurement and missing. Interest Groups & Advocacy, 2(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lowery, D., & Brasher, H. (2004). Organized interests and American government. McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lowery, D., & Gray, V. (2004). A neopluralist perspective on research on organized interests. Political Research Quarterly, 57(1), 164–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahoney, C., & Baumgartner, F. R. (2015). Partners in advocacy: Lobbyists and government officials in Washington. The Journal of Politics, 77(1), 202–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCrain, J. (2018). Revolving door lobbyists and the value of congressional staff connections. The Journal of Politics, 80(4), 1369–1383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKay, A. (2012). Buying policy? The effects of lobbyists’ resources on rheir policy success. Political Research Quarterly, 65(4), 908–923.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moran, P. A. P. (1948). The interpretation of statistical maps. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series B (methodological), 10(2), 243–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oliver, C., & Holzinger, I. (2008). The effectiveness of strategic political management: A dynamic capabilities framework. Academy of Management Review, 33(2), 496–520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rasmussen, A., Mäder, L. K., & Reher, S. (2018). With a little help from the people? The role of public opinion in advocacy success. Comparative Political Studies, 51(2), 139–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5(3), 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yackee, S. W. (2005). Sweet-talking the fourth branch: The influence of interest group comments on federal agency rulemaking. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 16(1), 103–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • You, H. Y. (2017). Ex post lobbying. The Journal of Politics, 79(4), 1162–1176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful for comments and suggestions they have received from Marcel Hanegraaf, Thomas Holyoke, Torben Iversen, Jennifer Victor, Christoffer Pfeiffer Cappelen and Florian Weiler. Previous versions of this manuscript were presented at annual meetings of the American Political Science Association, the Danish Political Science Association, and the European Consortium for Political Research. The authors also thank Professor William Shughart II, and the four anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestions, and Kelley Friel for excellent copy-editing. Any remaining errors are the authors’ own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Wiebke Marie Junk.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Authors listed alphabetically.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file1 (DOCX 195 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Egerod, B.C.K., Junk, W.M. Competitive lobbying in the influence production process and the use of spatial econometrics in lobbying research. Public Choice 191, 193–215 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-022-00962-w

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-022-00962-w

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation