Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Economic growth and political extremism

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

A Correction to this article was published on 23 September 2020

This article has been updated

Abstract

We argue that the growth rate, but not the level of aggregate income, affects the support for extreme political parties. In our model, extreme parties offer short-run benefits to part of the population at the expense of a minority. Growth effects on the support for such parties arise when uncertainty exists over whether the same subset of individuals will receive the same benefits in the future. More people are willing to take political risks if economic growth is slow. Based on a panel of 16 European countries, our empirical analysis shows that slower growth rates are associated with a significant increase in right-wing extremism. We find no significant effect of economic growth on the support for extreme left-wing parties.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: Eurobarometer. The figure is based on answers to the question: “If there were general elections tomorrow, which party would you vote for”. The figure plots the share of people that selected as an answer to the previous question extreme right-wing parties. Extreme right-wing parties are classified according to the ZEUS party code

Fig. 2

Source: Eurobarometer. The figure is based on answers to the question: “If there were general elections tomorrow, which party would you vote for”. The figure plots the share of people that selected as an answer to the previous question extreme left-wing parties. Extreme left-wing parties are classified according to the ZEUS party code

Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Change history

  • 23 September 2020

    This article was published in Public Choice 185:1-2 and is part of the “Special Issue of Public Choice in Honor of the 90th Birthday of Peter Bernholz/Edited by Arye L. Hillman and Heinrich W. Ursprung”.

Notes

  1. Our theoretical model concentrates on purely economic motives and does not consider other, in particular, social motives of political choices that have been discussed in the literature (see, e.g., Lipset 1967; Corneo and Grüner 2000). Our analysis applies to democratic countries, i.e., countries in which exists political competition exists. In that context, we call a political platform extreme if it proposes major redistributions of resources when compared to standard policies. See, for related theoretical analysis, Artale and Grüner (2000).

  2. Glaeser (2005) provides political economy insights on hatred.

  3. Although totalitarian regimes often are founded on strict systems of rules and beliefs - “the rule of law is limited by the rights of leaders to interpret the true meaning of constitutional or other legal statements” (Bernholz 1991, p. 436).

  4. According to Porter (1998): Different groups wore different triangles, and different triangles denoted different crimes. Jews wore yellow stars but also red triangles [and] political triangles. One of the biggest groups consisted of Germans who were made to wear black triangles, meaning saboteurs. Green triangles were worn by murderers. There were other triangles or strips for Jehovah’s Witnesses, vagrants, emigrants, Gypsies, race defiler (male), race defiler (female), escape suspects, special inmates, repeaters (those who were incarcerated more than once), and members of armed forces. A bewildering array of stigmatization.

  5. One such example is the stigmatization of homosexuals during the Nazi era. Porter (1998) writes: “The Nazis’ murder of some homosexuals started earlier than that of the Jews with the murders of Ernst Roehm and other brown shirts in his paramilitary group known as the SA.... Roehm was a major Nazi leader, second only to Hitler as they rose to power in the 20’s and early 30’s. He and his cadre of “brownshirts” were homosexuals, which was not a problem at the beginning for Hitler, but later did prove an embarrassment and a threat. Roehm and other SA leaders were murdered without warning in a famous blood purge which was led by Himmler and other SS officers at the instigation of Hitler and began on June 30, 1934, which has been called “The Night of Long Knives”.”

  6. Our formal model does not capture forms of stigmatization that go beyond group-specific income redistribution, such as harassment, imprisonment or genocide.

  7. Using time series analysis and US data, Durr (1993) finds that changes in consumers’ economic expectations are significantly positively correlated with a survey-based measure that takes on larger values for liberal policy sentiments and lower values for conservative policy sentiments. Fetzer (2018) finds that the support for the UK’s Independence Party is significantly increasing in individuals’ exposure to fiscal austerity.

  8. A similar assumption is made by Benhabib and Przeworski (2006). An exogenous probability of returning to the moderate regime would not affect any of our comparative static results.

  9. See Konrad (2004) for an analysis of political competition with costly signals to voters when voters do not know their own group status.

  10. Note that if unstigmatized individuals can be sure that they will not be stigmatized in the future \(\left( p=0\right)\), we get that \(\hat{y}=\frac{\tau +\frac{s}{1-s}}{\tau }\bar{y}\), which exceeds \(\bar{y}\) if \(\tau >0\). The threshold exceeds average income because of the uniform gains from stigmatization. Obviously, that result may change if the probability p that an individual becomes stigmatized in the future is positive.

  11. In “Appendix” we permit that \(s_{1}\ne s_{2}\) and we explore the conditions under which the negative relationship prevails.

  12. In the present model we assume away any incentive effects of redistribution, permitting us to obtain a full analytical solution for voters’ income thresholds. In our simple model, fully endogenizing the choice of tax rates is not very interesting. With median below mean income, moderate two-party competition leads to an equilibrium with full redistribution. When an extreme party offers the same tax rate, the threshold simplifies to \(\hat{y}=\frac{1+\frac{s}{1-s}}{\left( \frac{1+\delta g^{\alpha }}{1+\left( 1-p\right) \delta g^{\alpha }}\right) ^{\frac{1}{\alpha }}}\bar{y}\), thus leading to the same result on the effects of growth. However, even in the present simple setup, studying a subgame perfect equilibrium is more involved. That complexity holds, in particular, if incentive effects actually must be taken into account. Although interesting, we prefer to leave that analysis for future research.

  13. The countries (time-period) covered in our dataset are: Austria (1994–2002), Belgium (1970–2002), Denmark (1973–2002), Finland (1993–2002), France (1970–2002), West-Germany (1970–2002), Great Britain (1973–2002), Greece (1980–2002), Ireland (1973–2002), Italy (1970–2002), Luxembourg (1973–2002), Netherlands (1970–2002), Norway (1990–1995), Portugal (1985–2002), Spain (1985–2002) and Sweden (1994–2002). That is the largest possible sample given the availability of data from Eurobarometer. See Appendix Table 1 for summary statistics. For a list of the extreme right-wing and left-wing parties, see Table 12.

  14. The data are publicly available at http://zacat.gesis.org/webview/index.jsp.

  15. The average survey size was 1088, with an interquantile range of [1000, 1049].

  16. One can model actual vote shares as the survey vote shares plus measurement error. Larger measurement errors in the dependent variable has no effect asymptotically on the estimated coefficients of the right-hand-side variables, but it does inflate their standard errors.

  17. The coefficient of 0.07 on the immigration variable in column (2) can be interpreted as follows: for each 0.1 million immigrants, the support for extreme right-wing parties increases by about 0.7 percentage points. The coefficient on GDP per capita growth is around \(-\) 0.3, which means that, conditional on the four control variables in column (2), for each 1 percentage point decline in annual GDP per capita growth, the support for extreme right-wing parties increases by about 0.3 percentage points.

  18. If a semi-elasticity effect is estimated, i.e., by entering the natural logarithm of immigration on the right-hand side of the estimating equation, then, for the specification in column (2), the coefficient on log immigration is insignificant and negative; the coefficient on growth remains negative and significantly different from zero at the 1% level (estimates not reported).

  19. Brückner et al. (2012) use the same instrument to estimate the effects of persistent income on democracy in a world panel. Weather shocks, used by Brückner and Ciccone (2011) to estimate the effects of transitory income on democracy in sub-Saharan African countries, are not suitable for the present paper’s analysis. Leigh (2009) finds that faster world growth increases the likelihood that incumbents are reelected significantly.

  20. The same result can be seen from Fig. 4, which displays a scatter plot between lagged GDP per capita growth and the support for left-wing extremism.

  21. The median median-to-mean after-tax income ratio in Panel A is 0.92; in Panel B the median median-to-mean after-tax income ratio is 0.83.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J., & Yared, P. (2008). Income and democracy. American Economic Review, 98, 808–842.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J., & Yared, P. (2009). Reevaluating the modernization hypothesis. Journal of Monetary Economics, 56, 1043–1058.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Londregan, J., & Rosenthal, H. (1993). A model of the political economy of the United States. American Political Science Review, 87, 12–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arceneaux, K. (2001). Is the road to bad inference paved with good intentions? An audit of vote intention survey items. In Summer methods conference, Atlanta, GA, July 19–21, 2001.

  • Artale, A., & Grüner, H. P. (2000). A model of stability and persistence in a democracy. Games and Economic Behavior, 33, 20–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. (1973). The control of politicians: An economic model. Public Choice, 14, 19–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J., & Przeworski, A. (2006). The political economy of redistribution under democracy. Economic Theory, 29, 271–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernholz, P. (1991). The constitution of totalitarianism. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 147, 425–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernholz, P. (2017). Totalitarianism, terrorism and supreme values: History and theory. Cham: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bromhead, A., Eichengreen, B., & O’Rourke, K. (2012). Political extremism in the 1920s and 1930s: Do the German lessons generalize? Journal of Economic History, 73, 371–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, A. (2010). The rise and fall of communism. London: Vintage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brückner, M., & Ciccone, A. (2011). Rain and the democratic window of opportunity. Econometrica, 79, 923–947.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brückner, M., Ciccone, A., & Tesei, A. (2012). Oil price shocks, income and democracy. Review of Economics and Statistics, 94, 389–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corneo, G., & Grüner, H. P. (2000). Social limits to redistribution. American Economic Review, 90, 1491–1507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Mesquita, E. B., & Friedenberg, A. (2006). Optimal retrospective voting. New York: Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Durr, R. (1993). What moves policy sentiment? American Political Science Review, 87, 158–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edo, A., Giesing, Y., Öztunc, J., & Poutvaara, P. (2019). Immigration and electoral support for the far-left and the far-right. European Economic Review, 115, 99–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elinder, M., Jordahl, H., & Poutvaara, P. (2015). Promises, policies and pocketbook voting. European Economic Review, 75, 177–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eurobarometer Trend File 1970-2002, [Computer file]. GESIS Study ZA3521 (2nd ed.) (2.01), Cologne, Germany.

  • Eurostat (2019). Online database. Immigration data downloaded from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/en/web/products-datasets/-/MIGR_IMM8. Retrieved September 1, 2019.

  • Ferejohn, J. (1986). Incumbent performance and electoral control. Public Choice, 50, 5–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fetzer, T. (2018). Did austerity cause brexit? CAGE Working Paper

  • Fiorina, M. (1981). Retrospective voting in American national elections. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, B. (2005). The moral consequences of economic growth. New York: Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E. (2005). The political economy of hatred. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 45–86.

    Google Scholar 

  • Halla, M., Wagner, A., & Zweimüller, J. (2017). Immigration and voting for the far right. Journal of the European Economic Association, 15, 1341–1385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Key, V. O, Jr. (1966). The responsible electorate. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Konrad, K. A. (2004). Inverse campaigning. The Economic Journal, 114, 69–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leigh, A. (2009). Does the world economy swing national elections. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71, 163–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipset, S. (1967). Elections: The expression of the democratic class struggle. In R. Bendix & S. M. Lipset (Eds.), Class, status, and power (pp. 413–428). London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K., & Engels, F. (1848). Communist manifesto (p. 1848). London: Workers’ Educational Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maskin, E., & Tirole, J. (2004). The politician and the judge: accountability in government. American Economic Review, 94, 1034–1054.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norpoth, H. (1996). Presidents and the prospective voter. Journal of Politics, 58, 776–792.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD Statistics. (2009). Online Database. Retrieved November 10, 2019 from http://stats.oecd.org/index.aspx.

  • Porter, J. N. (1998). Sexual politics in Nazi Germany: The persecution of the homosexuals during the holocaust. Newton, MA: The Spencer Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rao, M., Raschky, P., & Tombazos, C. (2018). Political extremism and economic activity. Economics Letters, 170, 59–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson, R. (2001). The economy and policy mood: A fundamental dynamic of democratic politics? American Journal of Political Science, 45, 620–633.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J., & Yogo, M. (2005). Testing for weak instruments in linear IV regression. In D. W. K. Andrews & J. H. Stock (Eds.), Identification and inference for econometric models: Essays in honor of Thomas Rothenberg (pp. 80–108). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to two anonymous referees for constructive comments. We also gratefully acknowledge comments received on an earlier version of this paper from participants of the Silvaplana Workshop in Political Economy. For informal discussions and feedback on this work, we are grateful to Fabio Canova, Francesco Caselli, Bruce Chapman, Antonio Ciccone, Jana Friedrichsen, Nicola Gennaioli, Simon Grant, Eckhard Janeba, Ali Khan, Christina Kolerus, Meinhard Miegel, Sven-Oliver Proksch, Martin Schulte, Rabee Tourky, Stefanie Wahl and Philipp Zahn as well as members of “Denkkreis Funktionsfähigkeit der Gesellschaft” at Denkwerk Zukunft. We thank Annette Harms, Nora Müller-Alten and Michèle Weynandt for excellent research assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Markus Brückner.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

In the main text, the positive relationship between economic growth and the support for the moderate regime has been established for the case when \(s_{1}=s_{2}\). If it is the case that \(s_{1}\ne s_{2}\), no closed form solution exists for \(\hat{y}\). The following analysis addresses that issue.

Table 12 List of extreme right-wing and extreme left-wing parties

Proposition 1

Let \(\tau \ge 0\). For any given \(p\in \left[ 0,1\right]\)the following holds. Consider given values of \(s_{1}\)and q. If p is sufficiently large and if the critical income value \(\hat{y}\)satisfies \(\hat{y}<\bar{y}_{1}\)then \(d\hat{y}/dg<0\).

Proof

First note that \(s_{1},\)p, and q determine \(s_{2}=s_{1}q+\left( 1-s_{1}\right) p\). Define

$$\begin{aligned} F\left( \delta ,g,p,q,\hat{y},s_{1}\right) := \hat{y}^{\alpha }+\delta g^{\alpha }\hat{y}^{\alpha } \end{aligned}$$
(14)
$$\begin{aligned}&-\left( \left( 1-\tau \right) \hat{y}+\left( \tau +\frac{s_{1}}{1-s_{1}}\right) \bar{y}\right) ^{\alpha } \end{aligned}$$
(15)
$$\begin{aligned}&-\delta \left( 1-p\right) \end{aligned}$$
(16)
$$\begin{aligned}&\cdot \left( g\left( \left( 1-\tau \right) \hat{y}+\left( \tau +\frac{s_{1}q+\left( 1-s_{1}\right) p}{1-s_{1}q-\left( 1-s_{1}\right) p}\right) \bar{y}\right) \right) ^{\alpha }. \end{aligned}$$
(17)

When \(F\left( \delta ,g,p,q,\hat{y},s_{1}\right) =0\), non-stigmatized voters with income \(\hat{y}\) are indifferent between the two regimes, i.e., \(U^{M}=U^{E}\). We have

$$\begin{aligned} F_{g}= & {} \alpha \delta \hat{y}^{\alpha }g^{\alpha -1} \end{aligned}$$
(18)
$$\begin{aligned}&-\delta \left( 1-p\right) \alpha \left( \left( 1-\tau \right) \hat{y}+\left( \tau +\frac{s_{2}}{1-s_{2}}\right) \bar{y}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(19)
$$\begin{aligned}&\cdot \left( g\left( \left( 1-\tau \right) \hat{y}+\left( \tau +\frac{s_{2}}{1-s_{2}}\right) \bar{y}\right) \right) ^{\alpha -1}, \end{aligned}$$
(20)

and

$$\begin{aligned} F_{\hat{y}}= & {} \alpha \hat{y}^{\alpha -1}+\delta \alpha g^{\alpha }\hat{y}^{\alpha -1} \end{aligned}$$
(21)
$$\begin{aligned}&-\alpha \left( 1-\tau \right) \left( \left( 1-\tau \right) \hat{y}+\left( \tau +\frac{s_{1}}{1-s_{1}}\right) \bar{y}\right) ^{\alpha -1} \end{aligned}$$
(22)
$$\begin{aligned}&-\delta \alpha \left( 1-p\right) g\left( 1-\tau \right) \end{aligned}$$
(23)
$$\begin{aligned}&\cdot \left( g\left( \left( 1-\tau \right) \hat{y}+\left( \tau +\frac{s_{2}}{1-s_{2}}\right) \bar{y}\right) \right) ^{\alpha -1}. \end{aligned}$$
(24)

Now let \(p=1\). In that case

$$\begin{aligned} F_{g}=\alpha \delta \hat{y}^{\alpha }g^{\alpha -1}>0, \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} F_{\hat{y}}=\alpha \hat{y}^{\alpha -1}+\delta \alpha g^{\alpha }\hat{y}^{\alpha -1}-\alpha \left( 1-\tau \right) \left( \left( 1-\tau \right) \hat{y}+\left( \tau +\frac{s_{1}}{1-s_{1}}\right) \bar{y}\right) ^{\alpha -1}. \end{aligned}$$
(25)

Hence,

$$\begin{aligned} F_{\hat{y}}>0\Leftrightarrow \left( 1+\delta g^{\alpha }\right) \hat{y}^{\alpha -1}>\left( 1-\tau \right) \left( \left( 1-\tau \right) \hat{y}+\left( \tau +\frac{s_{1}}{1-s_{1}}\right) \bar{y}\right) ^{\alpha -1}. \end{aligned}$$
(26)

When \(\hat{y}<\bar{y}\) we have

$$\begin{aligned} \left( 1-\tau \right) \left( \hat{y}+\frac{s_{1}}{1-s_{1}}\hat{y}\right) ^{\alpha -1}>\left( 1-\tau \right) \left( \left( 1-\tau \right) \hat{y}+\left( \tau +\frac{s_{1}}{1-s_{1}}\right) \bar{y}\right) ^{\alpha -1}. \end{aligned}$$

Hence,

$$\begin{aligned} F_{\hat{y}}> & {} 0\Leftarrow \left( 1+\delta g^{\alpha }\right) \hat{y}^{\alpha -1}>\left( 1-\tau \right) \left( \hat{y}+\frac{s_{1}}{1-s_{1}}\hat{y}\right) ^{\alpha -1} \end{aligned}$$
(27)
$$\begin{aligned}\Leftrightarrow & {} 1+\delta g^{\alpha }>\left( 1-\tau \right) \left( \frac{1}{1-s_{1}}\right) ^{\alpha -1} \end{aligned}$$
(28)
$$\begin{aligned}\Leftrightarrow & {} 1+\delta g^{\alpha }>\left( 1-\tau \right) \left( 1-s_{1}\right) ^{1-\alpha }. \end{aligned}$$
(29)

The foregoing holds obviously. Therefore, using the implicit function theorem we get \(d\hat{y}/dg<0\). The proposition follows from the continuity of the functions \(F,F_{g}\), and \(F_{\hat{y}}\) in all of their arguments. \(\square\)

Proof of Results 2 and 4.

Result 2 Result 2 follows from

$$\begin{aligned} U^{M}= & {} U^{E}\Leftrightarrow \end{aligned}$$
(30)
$$\begin{aligned} \left( 1+\delta g^{\alpha }\right) \gamma _{i}^{\alpha }= & {} \left( \left( 1-\tau \right) \gamma _{i}+\left( \tau +\frac{s_{1}}{1-s_{1}}\right) \right) ^{\alpha } \end{aligned}$$
(31)
$$\begin{aligned}&+\,\delta \left( 1-p\right) \left( g\left( \left( 1-\tau \right) \gamma _{i}+\left( \tau +\frac{s_{2}}{1-s_{2}}\right) \right) \right) ^{\alpha }. \end{aligned}$$
(32)

Only relative income \(\gamma _{i1}\) is an argument in that equation, not absolute income.

Result 4 Economic growth shifts the threshold income \(\hat{y}\) to the left. The mass of individuals between the new and the old values of the threshold gives us the additional support for the extreme party. Result 4 follows from the fact that, with a uniform income distribution, more inequality is associated with fewer individuals being located in any given income bracket. \(\square\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Brückner, M., Grüner, H.P. Economic growth and political extremism. Public Choice 185, 131–159 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00745-w

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00745-w

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation