Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Distributive politics and congressional voting: public lands reform in the Jacksonian era

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

During the 1830s, Congress passed a series of laws reforming U.S. policy on acquiring public lands. These laws established a federal land policy of preemption, under which squatters on public land obtained legal title to it in exchange for payment of a minimum (and low) price per acre. Preemption significantly liberalized the terms of land ownership in the U.S. We analyze roll call voting on the preemption acts in Congress from a distributive politics perspective. The key finding is that a member’s region of the country consistently adds explanatory power on top of that provided by ideology or party: members of Congress from the original thirteen states were less supportive of preemption on Western lands, all else constant. Moreover, this effect is much stronger in the House of Representatives than in the Senate. This is inconsistent with explanations of a West-South coalition vs. the North often found in the historical literature, but is consistent with a distributive politics perspective based on rent seeking by Western landholders.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For another example of distributive politics and congressional voting during the antebellum era—on the issue of military service pensions—see Finocchiaro and Jenkins (2016).

  2. The first dimension revolves around the classic “left–right” conflict in politics; in the antebellum period, the second is closely related to the future of slavery in the United States and the sectional balance in the Senate (Poole and Rosenthal 2007; McCarty, Poole and Rosenthal 2000).

  3. Contemporary policymakers recognized that effect; e.g., Sen. Thomas Hart Benton of Missouri made the point in Senate floor speeches in 1829 (Feller 1984).

  4. Not only were Army troops often sympathetic to squatters, but officers leading campaigns to burn the squatters out often were tried in local courts even more sympathetic to the Army’s victims.

  5. Around the same time, beginning in the 1840 s, there was regional conflict and competition at the subnational legislative level on a related issue – that of granting formal legal and economic rights to married women. Such rights included being able to own property, enter into contracts without their husband’s permission, and stand in court as independent persons. For a detailed analysis, see Lemke (2016).

  6. 4 Stat. 420 (May 29, 1830).

  7. 4 Stat. 503 (April 15, 1832).

  8. 4 Stat. 678 (June 19, 1834).

  9. At the same time, advocates of preemption sought another federal law. Those efforts were led in Congress by Sen. Robert Walker (Democrat-Mississippi) and opposed by Sen. Henry Clay (Whig-Kentucky). Walker’s preemption bill gained no traction in 1836. A revised version of the bill was tried again in 1837 (during the lame-duck session of the 24th Congress), and while it passed 27-23 in the Senate it failed in the House (see Van Atta 2014, pp. 214-216).

  10. 5 Stat. 251 (June 22, 1838).

  11. For an extended discussion of the politics behind the Preemption Act of 1838, see Van Atta (2008).

  12. 5 Stat. 382 (June 1, 1840).

  13. Clay would manage this bill in the Whig-controlled 27th Congress, but the permanent prospective preemption idea was first introduced in 1840 by Robert Walker and Thomas Hart Benton in their “Log Cabin Bill.” Walker and Benton managed to get the bill through the Senate in the lame-duck session (on a 31 to 19 vote), but it died in the House. See Hibbard (1924, p. 347).

  14. 5 Stat. 453 (September 4, 1841).

  15. See also Feller (1984, pp, 187-188).

  16. Prior to the adoption of the 17th Amendment in 1913, US senators were elected indirectly: citizens elected state legislators, and those state legislators elected senators. As a result, the electoral connection for senators in the pre-17th Amendment era tended to be relatively weak (Gailmard and Jenkins 2009).

  17. While the electoral connection in the antebellum Congress was not as fully developed as in the contemporary era, research suggests that it was indeed in operation. See Bianco, Spence and Wilkerson (1996), Carson and Engstrom (2005), and Jenkins and Finocchiaro (2016). For a general examination of the electoral connection in Congress across time, see Carson and Jenkins (2011).

  18. Note that, for simplicity, we focus on two party labels—Democrats and Whigs—throughout our analysis. These labels assume antecedents (Jacksonians become Democrats and Adamsites/Anti-Jacksonians become Whigs) and combine third parties into their most natural party category (Anti-Masons into Whigs and Conservatives/Nullifiers into Democrats). We believe that the latter combination does little damage, as a check of individual third-party member backgrounds (in the Congressional Biographical Directory and Martis 1989) confirms perfectly the eventual movement into the assumed major party.

  19. Combining measures of ideology and economic interests is a common way to model how members of a legislature vote (Mueller 2003, pp. 489-496). Examples include Poole and Romer (1993), Brady and Schwartz (1995), Jenkins and Weidenmier (1999), Colburn and Hudgins (2003) and Rosenson (2007).

  20. Estimation of linear probability models by OLS and model comparisons by F-tests reveals substantively similar results to those we outline below. Those results are available from the authors on request.

  21. Population density data for House districts and states (essentially, population per square mile) was obtained from Parsons, Beech and Herman (1978).

  22. Given the limited coverage of the 1830 census and other data sources, more direct measures of manufacturing-commercial intensiveness are not available at the congressional district level.

  23. Based on exp(-ΔAICc/2), where ΔAICc is the difference in AICc between the minimum AICc and AICc from alternative model, a difference of 7 indicates that the alternative model is roughly 3% as likely to provide the best fit; a difference of 2 indicates that the alternative is roughly 36% as likely (Burnham and Anderson 2002).

  24. In both the Senate and House models, replacing 1st and 2nd DW NOMINATE scores with party never results in the best fitting model in the sense of AICc. And in only one of the ten roll calls (in the Senate of the 27th Congress) does a party-based distributive model outperform an ideology-based distributive model.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2005). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Akaike, H. (1974). A new look at the statistical model identification. IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control, 19(6), 716–723.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bianco, W. T., Spence, D. B., & Wilkerson, J. D. (1996). The electoral connection in the early Congress: The case of the Compensation Act of 1816. American Journal of Political Science, 40(1), 145–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C. (2003). Democracy and redistribution. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Brady, D., & Schwartz, E. P. (1995). Ideology and interests in congressional voting: The politics of abortion in the U.S. Senate. Public Choice, 84(1–2), 25–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burnham, K. P., & Anderson, D. R. (2002). Model selection and inference: A practical information theoretic approach (2nd ed.). New York: Springer-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carson, J. L., & Engstrom, E. (2005). Assessing the electoral connection: Evidence from the early United States. American Journal of Political Science, 49(4), 746–757.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carson, J. L., & Jenkins, J. A. (2011). Examining the electoral connection across time. Annual Review of Political Science, 14, 25–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colburn, C. B., & Hudgins, S. C. (2003). The intersection of business, state government, and special interest in federal legislation: An examination of congressional votes on the road to interstate banking. Economic Inquiry, 41(4), 620–638.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feller, D. (1984). The public lands in Jacksonian politics. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Finocchiaro, C. J., & Jenkins, J. A. (2016). Distributive politics, the electoral connection, and the antebellum US Congress: The case of military service pensions. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 28(2), 192–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frymer, P. (2014). A rush and a push and the land is ours Territorial expansion land policy. Perspectives on Politics, 12(1), 119–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gailmard, S., & Jenkins, J. A. (2009). Agency problems, the 17th Amendment, and representation in the Senate. American Journal of Political Science, 53(2), 324–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., Moav, O., & Vollrath, D. (2009). Inequality in land ownership, the emergence of human capital promoting institutions, and the Great Divergence. Review of Economic Studies, 76(1), 143–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gates, P. W. (1968). History of public land law development. Washington: Government Printing Office.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hibbard, B. H. (1924). A history of the public lands policies. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins, J. A., & Weidenmier, M. (1999). Ideology, economic interests, and congressional roll-call voting: Partisan instability and Bank of the United States legislation”. Public Choice, 100(3–4), 225–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kanazawa, M. (1996). Possession is nine points of the law: The political economy of early public land disposal”. Explorations in Economic History, 33(2), 227–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keyssar, A. (2000). The right to vote: The contested history of democracy in the United States. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lemke, J. S. (2016). Interjurisdictional competition and the Married Women’s Property Acts. Public Choice, 166(3–4), 291–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martis, K. C. (1989). The historical atlas of political parties in the United States Congress, 1789-1989. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCarty, N., Poole, K., & Rosenthal, H. (2000). Congress and the territorial expansion of the United States. In M. D. McCubbins, C. A. Stanford, & D. W. Brady (Eds.), New directions in studying the history of the U.S. Congress. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Muhn, J. (1997). A brief history of the disposition and administration of the public domain in Arkansas to 1908. Denver, CO: National Applied Resource Science Center, Bureau of Land Management, U.S. Department of the Interior.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murtazashvili, I. (2013). The political economy of the American frontier. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, S. B., Beech, W. W., & Herman, D. (1978). United States congressional district data, 1788–1841. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T., & Romer, T. (1993). Ideology, ‘shirking’, and representation. Public Choice, 77(1–2), 185–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (2007). Ideology and Congress. Piscataway, New Jersey: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prucha, F. P. (1969). The sword of the republic: The United States army on the frontier, 1783-1846. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robbins, R. M. (1931). Preemption—A frontier triumph. Mississippi Valley Historical Review, 18, 331–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenson, B. A. (2007). Explaining legislators’ positions on outside income limits: Voting on honoraria ceilings in the U.S. Senate, 1981–1983. Public Choice, 133(1–2), 111–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stathis, S. W. (2003). Landmark legislation, 1774–2002. Washington, DC: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Atta, J. R. (2008). ’A lawless rabble’: Henry Clay and the cultural politics of squatters’ rights, 1832-1841. Journal of the Early Republic, 28(3), 337–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Atta, J. R. (2014). Securing the west: Politics, public lands, and the fate of the old republic, 1785-1850. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, R. (1991). The middle ground: Indians, empires, and republics in the Great Lakes region: 1650–1815. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jeffery A. Jenkins.

Appendix: Logit results for House votes

Appendix: Logit results for House votes

 

Congress

Variable

21

22

23

25

26

27

Intercept

2.32 (0.66)

3.65 (0.86)

2.31 (0.5)

6.53 (1.39)

4.3 (0.83)

2.84 (1.91)

DWNOM1

− 3.72 (0.81)

− 3.24 (0.76)

− 3.65 (0.79)

− 10.72 (3.05)

− 8.36 (1.79)

22.84 (5.42)

DWNOM2

2.81 (1.29)

1.72 (1.36)

− 2.03 (1.47)

− 12.52 (3.89)

− 6.65 (2.69)

− 9.73 (6.61)

ln(Pop. Density)

− 0.16 (0.17)

− 0.11 (0.21)

− 0.26 (0.16)

− 0.48 (0.36)

0.08(0.28)

− 0.67 (0.74)

New England

0.31 (0.81)

− 2.66 (0.97)

− 3.24 (0.83)

− 5.56 (1.82)

− 5.38 (1.62)

− 2.45 (4.51)

Mid Atlantic

− 1.06 (0.72)

− 2.03 (0.9)

− 0.07 (0.69)

− 3.2 (1.35)

− 3.42 (1.44)

− 1.71 (2.38)

South Atlantic

− 3.31 (0.87)

− 3.47 (1.07)

− 1.67 (0.76)

− 7.89 (1.97)

− 5.92 (1.18)

− 3.36 (1.29)

N

158

162

177

160

184

225

  1. Entries are logit model coefficients, with standard errors in parentheses. N is the sample size for each model

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gailmard, S., Jenkins, J.A. Distributive politics and congressional voting: public lands reform in the Jacksonian era. Public Choice 175, 259–275 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0518-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0518-4

Keywords

Navigation