Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Adjustment costs and efficiency in Polish agriculture: a dynamic efficiency approach

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper aims to understand the state of adjustment processes and dynamic structure in Polish agriculture. A dynamic cost frontier model using the shadow cost approach is formulated to decompose cost efficiency into allocative and technical efficiencies. The dynamic cost efficiency model is developed into a more general context with a multiple quasi-fixed factor case. The model is empirically implemented using a panel data set of 1,380 Polish farms over the period 2004–2007. Due to regional differences and a wide variety of farm specializations, farms are categorized into two regions and five types of farm production specializations. The estimation results confirm our observation that adjustment was rather sluggish, implying that adjustment costs were considerably high. According to this study, it will take up to 30 years for Polish farmers to reach their optimal level of capital and land input. Allocative and technical efficiency widely differ across regions. Moreover, efficiencies prove rather stable over time and among farm specializations, although the results indicate that the regions with larger farms performed slightly better.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. However, recent studies including Emvalomatis et al. (2011) and Serra et al. (2011) have presented a parametric reduced-form approach in which dynamic efficiency measurements are derived on the basis of production technology and the duality between this function and the optimal value function.

  2. Totally differentiating \( y = F({\mathbf{x}},{\mathbf{q}},{\dot{\mathbf{q}}},t) \) leads to \( \nabla_{{\mathbf{x}}} Fd{\mathbf{x}} + \nabla_{{\mathbf{q}}} Fd{\mathbf{q}} + \nabla_{{{\dot{\mathbf{q}}}}} Fd{\dot{\mathbf{q}}} + \nabla_{t} Fdt = 0 \). Given \( d{\mathbf{q}} = 0 \) and \( dt = 0 \), the slope of the isoquant yields \( - \nabla_{x} F/\nabla_{{{\dot{\mathbf{q}}}}} F = \nabla_{{\mathbf{x}}} {\dot{\mathbf{q}}} \). Differentiating the slope of the isoquant with respect to \( {\mathbf{x}} \) provides \( \nabla_{{{\mathbf{xx}}}} {\dot{\mathbf{q}}} = - \left[ {{{\left( {\nabla_{{{\dot{\mathbf{q}}}}} F\nabla_{{{\mathbf{xx}}}} F - \nabla_{{\mathbf{x}}} F\nabla_{{{\mathbf{\dot{q}\dot{q}}}}} F} \right)} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\left( {\nabla_{{{\dot{\mathbf{q}}}}} F\nabla_{{{\mathbf{xx}}}} F - \nabla_{{\mathbf{x}}} F\nabla_{{{\mathbf{\dot{q}\dot{q}}}}} F} \right)} {\left( {\nabla_{{{\dot{\mathbf{q}}}}} F} \right)^{2} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\left( {\nabla_{{{\dot{\mathbf{q}}}}} F} \right)^{2} }}} \right] < 0 \).

  3. This model assumes that economic agents are risk neutral and that their price expectations are static. However, if these restrictive assumptions are relaxed investments under uncertainty can be derived within the dynamic duality model of intertemporal decision making. In the intertemporal model setting, risks and uncertainties can be defined as stochastic variables about which firms are assumed to have rational expectations regarding the future evolution of these variables. For more details about non-static price expectations and risk in the dynamic dual model of investment, see Luh and Stefanou (1996) and Pietola and Myers (2000).

  4. The Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN), Source: http://ec.europa.eu/agriculture/rica/.

  5. We follow the conventional dynamic analysis of production structures and consider capital as one of the quasi-fixed factors to capture possibly resulting adjustment costs to which the producer can appropriately respond and minimize entailed losses by dividing their investment requirement into several steps. Land was also considered as a quasi-fixed factor, given that farm structures are rather stable, which implies that changing the amount of cultivated acreage will entail considerable costs so that the adjustment of farm structures is only of minor importance/relevance. It is often argued that labor also belongs to the group of quasi-fixed inputs. In Poland, however, labor input reacts rather flexible and thus might considerably change following the overall economic situation. Correspondingly, part-time farming is a widespread phenomenon in Poland, thus implying that labor is more a flexible than a quasi-fixed input (Csaki and Lerman 2001).

  6. The depreciation rate was obtained by relating depreciation to fixed assets. The interest rate was obtained by the relation between interest paid and the amount of proportion of interest paid on long and medium-term loans.

  7. All price indices were taken from national statistics and the EUROSTAT website.

  8. These include dummy variables on specialization, farm size in European Size Units, location by Wojwodship (e.g. region), altitude of the farm, the existence of environmental limitations, the availability of structural funds and the education level of the farmer.

  9. Partial productivity and value shares were computed using the information given in Table 1.

  10. In the context of this study, when firms decide to increase farm land, net investment will not be simultaneously affected; rather, it might take several periods for net investment to adjust. Therefore, the decision to increase farm land is not fully dependent on the decision to increase a firm’s net investment. Over the study period, average land input increased by 4.5 % per year, while farm capital input increased by more than 7.5 %. These differences in the growth rates provide some support for our conjecture.

  11. The behavioral value function in Eq. (25) must satisfy the following regularity conditions: J b(∙) is non-increasing in (k, l); non-decreasing in (w b, p k , p l , y); convex in (k, l); concave in (w b, p k , p l ); and linearly homogenous in (w b, p k , p l ).

  12. In the estimation, dummy variables are incorporated to account for firm’s allocative and technical inefficiency parameters dynamic and variable factors demands. The inclusion of these dummy variables requires the implementation of a restricted version of the fixed effects panel data technique. The full sets of estimated coefficients including these dummy variables are not reported.

  13. As explained in Sect. 2 (Fig. 1), this dissimilarity mainly results from both the different conceptual approaches in the conventional and shadow cost approach as well as the different assumption made in SFA and DEA analysis. Usually DEA efficiency scores are much lower than SFA scores since in DEA there is no two-sided error term to buffer some of the structural differences among farms.

  14. The letter p is used to denote the shadow cost of the quasi-fixed factors \( \left( {\nabla_{{\mathbf{q}}} J} \right) \).

References

  • Caves DW, Christensen LR, Diewert WE (1982) Multilateral comparisons of output, input, and productivity using superlative index numbers. Econ J 92(365):73–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornwell C, Schmidt P, Sickles RE (1990) Production frontiers with cross-sectional and time-series variation in efficiency levels. J Econom 46(1/2):185–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Csaki C, Lerman Z (2001). Land and farm structure in Poland. Discussion Paper No. 10.0. The Center for Agricultural Economic Research, Department of Agricultural Economics and Management, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem

  • Emvalomatis G, Stefanou SE, Lansink AO (2011) A reduced-form model for dynamic efficiency measurement: an application to dairy farms in Germany and the Netherlands. Am J Agric Econ 93:161–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein LG, Denny MGS (1983) The multivariate flexible accelerator model: its empirical restrictions and an application to U.S. manufacturing. Econometrica 51:647–674

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez-Cornejo J, Gempesaw GM, Eltterich JG, Stefanou SE (1992) Dynamic measures of scope and scale economies: an application to German agriculture. Am J Agric Econ 74:329–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goraj L, Hockmann H (2010) Structural change, factor productivity and efficiency: initial conclusions from the Polish FADN data set. IAMO-Working Paper (2010), Halle/Saale, Germany

  • Hansen L (1982) Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators. Econometrica 50:1029–1054

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hockmann H, Pieniadz A (2009) Explaining differences in farms efficiencies in Polish agriculture. International Association of Agricultural Economists (IAAE), XXVII International Conference of Agricultural Economists, Beijing, China

  • Hockmann H, Pieniadz A, Goraj L (2007) Modeling heterogeneity in production models: empirical evidence from individual farming in Poland. Econ Pol Agric 2:55–71

    Google Scholar 

  • Howard HW, Shumway CR (1988) Dynamic adjustment in the U.S. dairy industry. Am J Agric Econ 70:837–847

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huettel S, Narayana R, Odening M (2011) Measuring dynamic efficiency under uncertainty. SiAg-Working Paper 10, Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin, Germany

  • Jorgenson DW (1963) Capital theory and investment behaviour. Am Econ Rev 53:366–378

    Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar SC, Lovell CK (2000) Stochastic frontier analysis. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Latruffe L, Balcombe K, Davidova S, Zawalinska K (2005) Technical and scale efficiency of crop and livestock farms in Poland: does specialization matter? Agric Econ 32:281–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luh YH, Stefanou SE (1991) Productivity growth in U.S. agriculture under dynamic adjustment. Am J Agric Econ 73:1116–1125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luh YH, Stefanou SE (1993) Learning-by-doing and the sources of productivity growth: a dynamic model with application to U.S. agriculture. J Prod Anal 4:353–370

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luh YH, Stefanou SE (1996) Estimating dynamic dual models under nonstatic expectations. Am J Agric Econ 78:991–1003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manera M (1994) Factor demands and substitution in the Italian manufacturing sector: a dynamic duality model. Ricerche Economiche 48:141–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nemoto J, Goto N (2003) Measurement of dynamic efficiency in production: an application of data envelopment analysis to Japanese electric utilities. J Prod Anal 19:191–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newey W, West K (1987) A simple positive semi-definite, heteroscedasticity- and autocorrelation-consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica 55:703–708

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newey W, West K (1994) Automatic lag selection in covariance matrix estimation. Rev Econ Stud 61:631–653

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petrick M (2004) A Microeconometric analysis of credit rationing in the Polish farm sector. Eur Rev Agric Econ 31:23–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pietola K, Myers RJ (2000) Investment under uncertainty and dynamic adjustment in the Finnish pork industry. Am J Agric Econ 82:956–967

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rungsuriyawiboon S, Stefanou SE (2007) Dynamic efficiency estimation: an application to US electric utilities. J Bus Econ Stat 20(2):226–238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sckokai P (2005) Modelling the impact of agricultural Policies on farm investments under uncertainty: the case of the CAP arable crop regime. Working Paper AGR/CA/APM(2005)13/FINAL. OECD, Paris

  • Serra T, Stefanou SE, Gil JM, Featherstone A (2009) Investment rigidity and policy measures. Eur Rev Agric Econ 36(1):103–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Serra T, Lansink AO, Stefanou SE (2011) Measurement of dynamic efficiency, a directional distance function parametric approach. Am J Agric Econ 93:756–767

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silva E, Stefanou SE (2003) Nonparametric dynamic production analysis and the theory of cost. J Prod Anal 19:5–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silva E, Stefanou SE (2007) Nonparametric dynamic efficiency measurement: theory and application. Am J Agric Econ 89:398–419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vasavada U, Chambers RG (1986) Investment in U.S. agriculture. Am J Agric Econ 68:950–960

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zientara W (2000) Land market in Poland in the post-war period. Warsaw Agricultural University, Warsaw

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Thailand Research Fund (TRF), the Commission on Higher Education (CHE), Ministry of Education (Thailand) [TRF-CHE Research Grant for Mid-Career University Faculty], the German Academic Exchange Service (DAAD) and the Leibniz Institute of Agricultural Development in Central and Eastern Europe (IAMO). Usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Supawat Rungsuriyawiboon.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Rungsuriyawiboon, S., Hockmann, H. Adjustment costs and efficiency in Polish agriculture: a dynamic efficiency approach. J Prod Anal 44, 51–68 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-015-0430-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-015-0430-6

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation