Skip to main content
Log in

Is the Relationship Between Political Responsibility and Electoral Accountability Causal, Adaptive and Policy-Specific?

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Political Behavior Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Will voters hold an incumbent more electorally accountable for the quality of a policy outcome if the incumbent’s political responsibility for the underlying policy increases? To answer this question, this study exploits a reform of labor market regulation in Denmark that exogenously assigned more political responsibility for unemployment services to some municipal mayors. The study finds that in subsequent elections these mayors were held more electorally accountable for unemployment services, but not more accountable for other policy outcomes. This suggests that the relationship between political responsibility and electoral accountability is causal, adaptive and tied to specific policies. On balance, the electorate thus seems to be quite judicious when assigning electoral credit or blame, moderating the extent to which incumbents are held accountable for specific outcomes based on the extent to which these incumbents crafted and implemented the policies that shaped these outcomes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Another set of studies have examined which psychological processes lead voters to attribute certain outcomes to incumbent politicians (e.g., Gomez and Wilson 2001; Tilley and Hobolt 2011). While this literature also examines responsibility in relation to retrospective voting, it does so in a very different way than the literature discussed here. As such, in this more psychological literature, responsibility is a subjective belief that voters hold, whereas in the literature described above, responsibility is an objective condition determined by the mix of political and economic institutions that characterize the nature of policy-making in a specific polity.

  2. It is not theoretically straightforward to predict which of these approaches voters will adopt. On the one hand, adopting a policy-specific strategy seems to be more rational if one simply wants to learn more about the incumbent’s competence (for evidence of this, see the appendix of Achen and Bartels (2016)). On the other hand, voters are often interested in employing heuristics and mental shortcuts (Downs 1957; Kuklinski et al. 2000). One such mental shortcut might be to link responsibility and accountability at an aggregate rather than at a policy-specific level.

  3. Too see this, note that if the relationship between centralization of responsibility and accountability is causal, then voters respond to changes in responsibility by holding incumbents more electorally accountable. If the relationship is policy-specific, then voters are more likely to shift their attention away from policy outcomes that incumbents have little responsibility for and towards outcomes that incumbents have more responsibility for. If the relationship is adaptive, then voters are more likely to act on the current distribution of political responsibility when holding incumbents accountable.

  4. Unemployment services constitute an important part of public service provision in Denmark, and Danish labor market policy has long been premised on the idea that the day-to-day interaction with the unemployed individual is important for reducing structural unemployment (Torfing 1999). This idea is mirrored in spending priorities. According to the OECD, expenditures towards unemployment services (i.e., active labor market policies) represented 1.82% of the Danish GDP in 2013 compared to just 0.23% in the United Kingdom (OECD 2014).

  5. These assumptions roughly correspond to the exclusion and independence (or exogeneity) assumptions laid out by Dunning (2012) and Gerber and Green (2012). Along with the assumption of non-interference between units, they constitute the central assumptions needed to draw causal inferences. We do not discuss the non-interference assumption in detail, because political responsibility could not spillover to neighboring municipalities.

  6. See Sect. S1 of the supplementary materials for some additional evidence of the fact that the reform did not have any important side effects.

  7. Interview with Jan Handeliowitz, former employee at the Ministry of Employment. Author’s translation.

  8. This conclusion is based on an examination of all newspaper stories mentioning the reform in the month following the announcement of the assignment of municipalities to early-implementer status in the three major Danish broadsheets (Jyllands Posten, Politiken and Berlingske).

  9. The 2005 survey differs in this respect as it is not stratified according to municipality.

  10. The survey item on unemployment services was not included in the 2013 survey. Therefore, I cannot measure electoral accountability for unemployment services in the 2013 election.

  11. Support for the mayoral party is used to measure support for the mayor because voters do not elect mayors directly in Denmark. Rather, they elect members of a city council, and the city council then appoints a mayor right after the election (Houlberg and Pedersen 2015). Municipal elections in Denmark are held every 4 years in November. The electoral system is proportional representation and most municipalities have a multi-party system that mirrors the national party system.

  12. In “Alternative Explanations and Potential Mechanisms” this assumption is discussed further and tested empirically (see also Sect. S8 of the supplementary materials).

  13. I also estimated a simpler logistic model, without any controls. The interaction estimate in this simple model is also statistically significant and of roughly the same size as the one presented in column one of Table 2.

  14. I adapt the models in one way, swapping the measure of support for the mayoral party at national elections for a measure of support for the regional/national government party/parties.

  15. In particular, elderly care only directly affects a certain target population (i.e., the elderly), similar to how unemployment services only affect the unemployed. Elderly care is also similar to unemployment services in that it is a public service consisting of direct contact with municipal employees.

  16. Section S7 of the supplementary materials analyzes the robustness of these results by running similar analyses for a number of other policy areas. Among the seven additional policies examined, there is not a single statistically significant difference between the treatment and control municipalities.

References

  • Acemoglu, D. (2005). Constitutions, politics, and economics: A review essay on Persson and Tabellini’s the economic effects of constitutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 43(4), 1025–1048.

    Google Scholar 

  • Achen, C. H., & Bartels, L. M. (2016). Democracy for realists: Why elections do not produce responsive government. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Act 483. 2009. Lov om ændring af lov om ansvaret for og styringen af den aktive beskæftigelsesindsats, lov om en aktiv beskæftigelsesindsats og forskellige andre love samt om ophævelse af lov om supplerende aktiveringstilbud til visse ledige medlemmer af en arbejdsløshedskasse.

  • Aghion, P., Alesina, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Endogenous Political Institutions*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(2), 565–611.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, C. D. (2006). Economic voting and multilevel governance: A comparative individual-level analysis. American Journal of Political Science, 50(2), 449–463.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, C. D. (2009). Institutional change, economic conditions and confidence in government: Evidence from Belgium. Acta Politica, 44(1), 28–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, C. J. (2000). Economic voting and political context: A comparative perspective. Electoral Studies, 19(2), 151–170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arceneaux, K. (2006). The federal face of voting: Are elected officials held accountable for the functions relevant to their office? Political Psychology, 27(5), 731–754.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashworth, S. (2012). Electoral accountability: Recent theoretical and empirical work. Annual Review of Political Science, 15, 183–201.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashworth, S., Bueno de Mesquita, E., & Friedenberg, A. (2017). Accountability and information in elections. American Economic Journal, 9(2), 95–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry, C. R., & Howell, W. G. (2007). Accountability and local elections: Rethinking retrospective voting. The Journal of Politics, 69(3), 844–858.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Case, A. (2000). Unnatural experiments? Estimating the incidence of endogenous policies. The Economic Journal, 110(467), 672–694.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhatti, Y., & Hansen, K. M. (2011). Who marries’ whom? The influence of societal connectedness, economic and political homogeneity, and population size on jurisdictional consolidations. European Journal of Political Research, 50(2), 212–238.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bisgaard, M. (2015). Bias will find a way: Economic perceptions, attributions of blame, and Partisan-motivated reasoning during crisis. The Journal of Politics, 77(3), 849–860.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blom-Hansen, J., Houlberg, K., & Serritzlew, S. (2014). Size, democracy, and the economic costs of running the political system. American Journal of Political Science, 58(4), 790–803.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, D. R. (1978). The expansion of the public economy: A comparative analysis. American Political Science Review, 72(04), 1243–1261.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlin, R. E., & Singh, S. P. (2015). Executive power and economic accountability. The Journal of Politics, 77(4), 1031–1044.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cutler, F. (2008). Whodunnit? Voters and responsibility in Canadian federalism. Canadian Journal of Political Science, 41(03), 627–654.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Vries, C. E., Edwards, E. E., & Tillman, E. R. (2010). Clarity of responsibility beyond the pocketbook: How political institutions condition EU issue voting. Comparative Political Studies, 44(3), 339–363.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Vries, C. E., Van der Brug, W., Van Egmond, M. H., & Van der Eijk, C. (2011). Individual and contextual variation in EU issue voting: The role of political information. Electoral Studies, 30(1), 16–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of political action in a democracy. Journal of Political Economy, 65(2), 135–150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duch, R. M., & Stevenson, R. T. (2008). The economic vote: How political and economic institutions condition election results., Political economy of institutions and decisions New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunning, T. (2012). Natural experiments in the social sciences: A design-based approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ebeid, M., & Rodden, J. (2006). Economic geography and economic voting: Evidence from the US states. British Journal of Political Science, 36(03), 527–547.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elklit, J., & Kjær, U. (2013). KV09: Analyser af kommunalvalget 2009. Denmark: Syddansk Universitetsforlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Erikson, R. S., MacKuen, M. B., & Stimson, J. A. (2002). The macro polity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eskelinen, L. (2008). Jobcentrenes ledelse og organisering. Copenhagen: AKF Forlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fernández-Albertos, J. (2006). Does internationalisation blur responsibility? Economic voting and economic openness in 15 European countries. West European Politics, 29(1), 28–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fossati, D. (2014). Economic vulnerability and economic voting in 14 OECD countries. European Journal of Political Research, 53(1), 116–135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerber, A. S., & Green, D. P. (2012). Field experiments: Design, analysis, and interpretation. New York: WW Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gomez, B. T., & Wilson, J. M. (2001). Political sophistication and economic voting in the American electorate: A theory of heterogeneous attribution. American Journal of Political Science, 45(4), 899–914.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanmer, M. J., & Kalkan, K. O. (2013). Behind the curve: Clarifying the best approach to calculating predicted probabilities and marginal effects from limited dependent variable models. American Journal of Political Science, 57(1), 263–277.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, K. M., & Pedersen, R. T. (2014). Campaigns matter: How voters become knowledgeable and efficacious during election campaigns. Political Communication, 31(2), 303–324.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harding, R. (2015). Attribution and accountability: Voting for roads in Ghana. World Politics, 67(4), 656–689.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hart, A. (2016). Economic voting. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Healy, A., & Malhotra, N. (2013). Retrospective voting reconsidered. Annual Review of Political Science, 16, 285–306.

    Google Scholar 

  • Healy, A., Malhotra, N., et al. (2010). Random events, economic losses, and retrospective voting: Implications for democratic competence. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 5(2), 193–208.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hellwig, T., & Samuels, D. (2007). Voting in open economies the electoral consequences of globalization. Comparative Political Studies, 40(3), 283–306.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hellwig, T. T. (2001). Interdependence, government constraints, and economic voting. The Journal of Politics, 63(04), 1141–1162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hobolt, S., Tilley, J., & Banducci, S. (2013). Clarity of responsibility: How government cohesion conditions performance voting. European Journal of Political Research, 52(2), 164–187.

    Google Scholar 

  • Houlberg, K., & Pedersen, L. H. (2015). Political consensus and fiscal outcomes. Local Government Studies, 41(1), 78–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jakobsen, M. L., & Mortensen, P. B. (2014). Regelstaten: Væksten i danske love og bekendtgørelser 1989–2011. Denmark: Djøf/Jurist-og Økonomforbundet.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jennings, W. (2009). The public thermostat, political responsiveness and error-correction: Border control and asylum in Britain, 1994–2007. British Journal of Political Science, 39(4), 847–870.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johns, R. (2011). Credit where it’s due? Valence politics, attributions of responsibility, and multi-level elections. Political Behavior, 33(1), 53–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, B. D., & Baumgartner, F. R. (2005). The politics of attention: How government prioritizes problems. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kayser, M. A., & Wlezien, C. (2011). Performance pressure: Patterns of partisanship and the economic vote. European Journal of Political Research, 50(3), 365–394.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, G., Keohane, R. O., & Verba, S. (1994). Designing social inquiry: Scientific inference in qualitative research. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kristensen, K. M. (2008). Jobcenterreformen: Som et lyn fra en klar himmel. Aarhus C: Aarhus Universitet.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krosnick, J. A., & Kinder, D. R. (1990). Altering the foundations of support for the president through priming. American Political Science Review, 84(02), 497–512.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuklinski, J. H., Quirk, P. J., et al. (2000). Reconsidering the rational public: Cognition, heuristics, and mass opinion. In A. Lupia, M. D. McCubbins, & S. L. Popkin (Eds.), Elements of reason: Cognition, choice, and the bounds of rationality (pp. 153–182). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Larsen, M. V. (2016). Economic conditions affect support for prime minister parties in Scandinavia. Scandinavian Political Studies, 39(3), 226–241.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lassen, D. D., & Serritzlew, S. (2011). Jurisdiction size and local democracy: Evidence on internal political efficacy from large-scale municipal reform. American Political Science Review, 105(2), 238–258.

    Google Scholar 

  • León, S. (2011). Who is responsible for what? Clarity of responsibilities in multilevel states: The case of Spain. European Journal of Political Research, 50(1), 80–109.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, B. D. (1995). Natural and quasi-experiments in economics. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 13(2), 151–161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Employment. (2006). Press release: 14 pilotcentre er udpeget. Ministry of Employment.

  • Ministry of Employment. (2010). Aftale om et enstrenget kommunalt beskæftigelsessystem. Ministry of Employment.

  • Nadeau, R., Niemi, R. G., & Yoshinaka, A. (2002). A cross-national analysis of economic voting: Taking account of the political context across time and nations. Electoral Studies, 21(3), 403–423.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2014). Public expenditure and participant stocks on LMP. http://stats.oecd.org/ .

  • Order 1400. (2006). Bekendtgørelse om delegation af statens beskæftigelsesindsats til visse kommuner.

  • Pacek, A. C., & Radcliff, B. (1995). Economic voting and the welfare state: A cross-national analysis. The Journal of Politics, 57(1), 44–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker-Stephen, E. (2013). Clarity of responsibility and economic evaluations. Electoral Studies, 32(3), 506–511.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, G. B., & Whitten, G. D. (1993). A cross-national analysis of economic voting: Taking account of the political context. American Journal of Political Science, 37, 391–414.

    Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, A. (2004). Institutions matter? Government and Opposition, 39(4), 527–540.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ritzau. (2006). Kommuner hilser jobcentre velkommen. Ritzaus bureau.

  • Rodrik, D. 1996. Why do more open economies have bigger governments? National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Rosenberg, H., & Feldman, C. S. (2008). No time to think: The menace of media speed and the 24-hour news cycle. New York: A&C Black.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruder, A. I., et al. (2014). Institutional design and the attribution of presidential control: Insulating the president from blame. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 9(3), 301–335.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rudolph, T. J. (2006). Triangulating political responsibility: The motivated formation of responsibility judgments. Political Psychology, 27(1), 99–122.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sances, M. W. (2017). Attribution errors in federalist systems: When voters punish the president for local tax increases. The Journal of Politics, 79, 1286–1301.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singer, M. M. (2013). What goes around comes around: Perceived vulnerable employment and economic voting in developing countries. European Journal of Political Research, 52(2), 143–163.

    Google Scholar 

  • Soroka, S. N., & Wlezien, C. (2005). Opinion-policy dynamics: Public preferences and public expenditure in the United Kingdom. British Journal of Political Science, 35(4), 665–689.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson, R. T., & Duch, R. (2013). The meaning and use of subjective perceptions in studies of economic voting. Electoral Studies, 32(2), 305–320.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stimson, J. A. (2015). Tides of consent: How public opinion shapes American politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tavits, M. (2007). Clarity of responsibility and corruption. American Journal of Political Science, 51(1), 218–229.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilley, J., & Hobolt, S. B. (2011). Is the government to blame? An experimental test of how partisanship shapes perceptions of performance and responsibility. The Journal of Politics, 73(02), 316–330.

    Google Scholar 

  • Torfing, J. (1999). Workfare with welfare: Recent reforms of the Danish welfare state. Journal of European Social Policy, 9(1), 5–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vries, C. E., & Giger, N. (2014). Holding governments accountable? Individual heterogeneity in performance voting. European Journal of Political Research, 53(2), 345–362.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whitten, G. D., & Palmer, H. D. (1999). Cross-national analyses of economic voting. Electoral Studies, 18(1), 49–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wlezien, C. (1995). The public as thermostat: Dynamics of preferences for spending. American Journal of Political Science, 39(4), 981–1000.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

For comments on previous drafts, I would like to thank Marc Andre Bodet, Thad Dunning, Michael Lewis-Beck, Gabriel Lenz, Peter Thisted Dinesen, Peter Bjerre Mortensen, Cecilia Mo, Kasper Møller Hansen, Asmus Leth Olsen, Richard Nadeau, Michael Sances, Søren Serritzlew and Rune Stubager. For their work in collecting the Danish Municipal Election surveys, I would like to thank Ulrik Kjær, Christian-Elmelund Præstekær and Jørgen Elklit. Replication files for this paper are available in the Political Behavior Dataverse (https://dataverse.harvard.edu/dataverse/polbehavior).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Martin Vinæs Larsen.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 613 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Larsen, M.V. Is the Relationship Between Political Responsibility and Electoral Accountability Causal, Adaptive and Policy-Specific?. Polit Behav 41, 1071–1098 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-018-9483-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-018-9483-3

Keywords

Navigation