Skip to main content
Log in

The Mundellian Trilemma and Optimal Monetary Policy in a World of High Capital Mobility

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper proposes that the Mundellian Trilemma remains valid despite the emergence of a world financial cycle. A clear distinction must be made between monetary policy independence and insulation of an open economy’s financial system. A flexible exchange rate allows an optimizing central bank to chart an independent course but does not insulate the domestic financial sector or broader economy from foreign monetary or financial shocks. The gains from a flexible exchange rate may be considerable and vary in accordance with the mandate of the central bank. The Mundellian Trilemma highlights the acute shortage of policy instruments and resulting tradeoffs among policy goals.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Sceptics like Dunn (1983) questioned whether central banks ever embraced freely floating exchange rates. In his view, fear of the cost of highly variable real exchange rates induced central banks to manage exchange rates to a considerable extent. Later in the 1980s following the Plaza Accord in October 1985 and Louvre Accord in February 1987, the G-5 central banks engaged in co-ordinated foreign exchange market intervention to dampen fluctuations in the value of the U.S. dollar, further deviating from exchange rate flexibility.

  2. A clear statement about terminology is useful at the start. By monetary policy independence we mean that a central bank has unimpeded control of its instruments and proximate targets. Insulation of the financial sector is taken to mean that financial markets are shielded from world financial shocks and policy shocks originating in the United States and other major industrial countries. We avoid the terms: monetary independence or autonomy; “monetary” in this context is ambiguous. It is not clear whether these terms refer to central bank actions or to a broader context including banking and credit markets.

  3. Aizenman, Chinn and Ito (2020) estimate this correlation controlling for world economic conditions. They also examine how this measure of policy independence is affected by the implementation of macroprudential policies in the peripheral countries—an additional issue in the recent literature on the Trilemma.

  4. In the original non-stochastic Mundell-Fleming model exchange rate expectations are static so that Eq. (2) reduces to \({r}_{t}={r}_{t}^{f}\). Dornbusch (1976, 1980) introduces an arbitrage condition, essentially a form of the UIP equation, where a difference between the domestic and foreign interest rate is matched by a requisite expected exchange rate adjustment. See also Sohmen (1969, p. 114, fn. 29).

  5. From this point on, for simplicity of exposition, we will refer to \({r}^{f}\) as the U.S. policy rate.

  6. See also Dornbusch (1980; pp. 201–202). Both Mundell and Dornbusch reach this conclusion from analysis within a two-country version of the Mundell-Fleming framework. Sohmen (1969) objects to this characterization of “beggar-thy-neighbor” pointing out that in a system with flexible rates policymakers in the small country “are always perfectly free to adopt whatever expansionary policies they consider appropriate—in contrast with a system of fixed rates, in which their freedom of action may be seriously impaired” (p.214).

  7. This equivalence is consistent with the finding in Friedman (1975).

  8. An authoritative source on this point is Hicks (1946), “The rate of interest in Mr. Keynes General Theory is the long rate.”.

  9. An additional point made by Marston (1985: pp.907–912) is that to analyze foreign shocks, including foreign monetary policy shifts, it is necessary to take account of their context in the foreign economy with implications for the small open economy. Monetary policy shifts do not take place in a vacuum. Monetary policy shifts in major economies may destabilize emerging markets but lack of a policy response to financial shocks in those economies would also have destabilizing effects in emerging markets. In the context of recent U.S. monetary policy, this point is explored in Canzoneri et al. (2021).

  10. In addition to Marston (1985) examples of this literature are Aizenman and Frenkel (1985); Turnovsky (1983), (1987) and Benavie and Froyen (1991).

  11. Obstfeld (2020) notes that the word “insulation” does not appear in Johnson’s (1969) classic “Case for Flexible Exchange Rates.” Marston’s (1985) opinion was that “[f]lexible rates are widely thought to insulate an economy from foreign disturbances, probably because of the insulation achieved in models without capital mobility (p.907).” Capital flows are, however, central to current issues.

  12. In the cases we consider the expected inflation rate will be zero. The distinction between real and nominal interest rates will not be necessary. This follows from the fact that all shocks to the model will be assumed to be white noise. Introducing serially correlated disturbances makes the derivation of the algebraic results reported in this and the next section unnecessarily complex. Solving the model numerically under the assumption of autoregressive disturbances yields the same basic insights as the case of white noise disturbances. The foreign inflation rate will also be assumed to be zero, so there will be no distinction between real and nominal exchange rates.

  13. For the derivation of the open-economy New Keynesian IS equation, see Guender (2006).

  14. The treatment of optimal policy here assumes policy is conducted by discretion. Policy under commitment is an alternative framework [See Woodford (2003) or Froyen and Guender (2019)]. Distinctions between the two frameworks do not bear on the issues considered here.

  15. See, for example, the discussion in Monacelli (2013).

  16. The target rule is derived from constrained optimization. The central bank minimizes the loss function subject to the constraints of the model which, for b > 0, consist of both the Phillips Curve and the IS relation. The real exchanger rate is eliminated from the constraints through substitution of the UIP condition. The choice variables are the target variables – the rate of inflation and the output gap. For b = 0 the only constraint is the Phillips Curve.

  17. Not all versions of the New Keynesian model are based on the assumption of complete markets. Some derivations simply postulate the existence of riskless one-period bond. In general, given the assumption in these models of identical households, Woodford (2003: p.64) points out that “it makes no real difference what one assumes about the number of financial markets that are open.”.

  18. For example, Ravenna and Walsh (2006) consider a cost channel which introduces the interest rate into the Phillips Curve and thus indirectly an exchange rate channel.

  19. In an IMF Monograph, Chamon et al. (2019, p.vii) state that “In practice, inflation targeting central banks in emerging markets continued to closely monitor the exchange rate, not only for its implications for inflation, but because of financial stability risks that sharp exchange rate movements may entail.” This concern with exchange rate volatility, not only affects policy rates but also explains why foreign exchange market interventions have “always been an important component of central bank policy in emerging and developing economies Benes et al. (2015, p.82). Foreign exchange market intervention is considered in Sect. 5.

  20. The study by Eichengreen et al. (2020) is supportive this view,

  21. This was recognized early in the era of flexible exchange rates. See for example Peter Kenen (1985, pp.665–9).

  22. Losses in Tables 1 are calculated for Eq. 11. If Eq. 17 is used instead, the only difference results from the change in scaling of the weights (μ = 0.9524 compared to 1.0). The resulting value of loss function equals 2.49 compared to 2.62.

  23. In the model in Banerjee et al. (2016) the presence of a financial friction also increases the benefits of following an optimal policy that allows for exchange rate flexibility compared to a fixed exchange rate or inflexible inflation targeting.

  24. In economies with strong regulatory institutions, a solution to the instrument problem in an expanded framework is greater use of targeted macro-prudential instruments such as loan-to-value ratios and core funding ratios. The Reserve Bank of Australia in 2019 added an “articulation of the financial stability objective [Debelle (2018, p.55)],” to its existing dual mandate. The New Zealand Reserve Bank Act of 2021 “introduces the overarching objective of financial stability” [New Zealand Treasury (2021)], accompanied by a financial dashboard providing multiple metrics of the soundness of financial intermediaries.

  25. The title of the Farhi and Werning paper is “Dilemma Not Trilemma? Capital Controls, Exchange Rates and Volatile Capital Flows.”.

  26. Engel (2015) considers a role for capital controls to reduce market distortions such as those that lead to overborrowing. Engel (2015) and Cespedes et al. (2012) survey the experience of countries that maintained capital controls during and after the world financial crisis of 2007–2009. The Cespedes et al. study covers six Latin American countries that used selective reserve requirements, taxes and other restrictions to control various categories of capital flows. In the literature these measures are often represented by an interest equalization tax parameter. Landi and Schiavone (2021), in a detailed survey, find that capital controls are effective in restricting the size of the flows and the probability of surges and flights.

  27. In the current context sterilized intervention refers to foreign exchange market intervention accompanied by other central bank actions that leave the policy interest rate unchanged. Changes in that rate are a separate instrument. Intervention may or may not affect the monetary base.

  28. Both Blanchard (2017) and Liu and Spiegel (2015) consider application of an interest equalization tax on capital flows while Adrian et al. (2020) examine the imposition of a tax on capital outflows to limit severe depreciation of the domestic currency that widens a borrowing spread.

References

  • Adrian T, Erceg C, Lindé J, Zabczyk P, Zhou J (2020) A Quantitative model for the integrated policy framework. IMF Work Pap WP/20/122

  • Ando A, Modigliani F (1969) Econometric analysis of stabilization policies. Am Econ Rev 59:296–314

    Google Scholar 

  • Aizenman J (2019) A modern re-incarnation of Mundell-Fleming’s trllemma. Econ Model 81:444–454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aizenman J, Chinn M, Ito H (2013) The “Impossible Trinity” hypothesis in an era of global imbalances: measurement and testing. Rev Int Econ 21:447–458

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aizenman J, Chinn M, Ito H (2020) Financial spillovers and macroprudential policies. Open Econ Rev 31:529–563

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aizenman J, Frenkel J (1985) Optimal wage indexation, foreign exchange intervention, and monetary policy. Am Econ Rev 75:402–423

    Google Scholar 

  • Artis MJ, Currie DA (1981) Monetary targets and the exchange rate: a case for conditional targets. Oxford Econ Pap Suppl 176–200

  • Banerjee R, Devereux M, Lombardi G (2016) Self-oriented monetary policy, global financial markets and excess volatility of international capital flows. J Int Money Financ 68:275–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benavie A, Froyen RT (1991) A note on optimal monetary and wage indexation policies in a small open economy. Aust Econ Pap 334–340

  • Benavie A, Froyen RT (1992) Optimal monetary policy with an interest-equalization tax in a two-country macroeconomic model. J Macroecon 14:449–466

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benes J, Berg A, Portillo RA, Varva D (2015) Modeling sterilized interventions and balance sheet effects of monetary policy in a New Keynesian framework. Open Econ Rev 26:81–108

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke B (2017) Federal Reserve policy in an international context. IMF Econ Rev 65:1–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black SW (1973) International money markets and flexible exchange rates. Stud Int Finance (32) (Princeton University)

  • Blanchard O (2017) Currency wars, coordination and capital controls. Int J Cent Bank 13:283–308

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Dell'Ariccia G, Mauro P (2010) Rethinking macroeconomic policy. J Money, Credit, and Banking 42:199-215

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Adler G, de Carvalho Filho I (2015) Can foreign exchange market intervention stem exchange rate pressure from global capital flow shocks?. Peterson Institute for International Economics, WP 15–18 Washington DC

  • Branson WH, Henderson DW (1985) The specification and influence of asset markets. in R. W. Jones and P. B. Kenen, eds., Handbook on Int Econ 2. Amsterdam: Elsevier Publishers.

  • Brunner K, Meltzer AH (1972) Money, debt and economic activity. J Polit Econ 80:951–977

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero J (2014) Do surges in international capital inflows influence the likelihood of banking crises? Econ J 226:281–316

    Google Scholar 

  • Canzoneri M, Cumby R, Diba B, Kim Y (2021) “Did the unconventional monetary policy of the U.S. hurt emerging markets? Open Econ Rev 32:231–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cespedes LF, Chang R, Velasco A (2004) Balance sheets and exchange rate policy. Am Econ Rev 94:1183–1193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cespedes LF, Chang R, Velasco A (2012) Is inflation still on target. NBER Work Paper (18570), Cambridge MA

  • Chamon M, Hofman D, Magud NE, Werner A (2019) Foreign Exchange Market Intervention in Inflation Targeters. Washington D.C. IMF

  • Clarida R, Gali J, Gertler M (2001) Optimal monetary policy in open versus closed economies: an integrated approach. Am Econ Rev 91:248–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarida R, Gali J, Gertler M (2002) A simple framework for international monetary policy analysis. J Monet Econ 49:879–904

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis JS, Presno I (2017) Capital controls and monetary policy autonomy in small open economies. J Monet Econ 85:114–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debelle G (2018) Twenty-five years of inflation targeting in Australia. In J. Simon and M. Sutton, eds., Central Bank Frameworks: Evolution or Revolution. Canberra: Reserve Bank of Australia

  • deLeeuw F, Gramlich E (1969) The channels of monetary policy. Fed Reserv Bull 55(2):472–491

    Google Scholar 

  • Dornbusch R (1976) Expectations and exchange rate dynamics. J Polit Econ 84:1161–1175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dornbusch R (1980) Open Economy Macroeconomics. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dornbusch R (1986) Special exchange rates for capital market transactions. World Bank Econ Rev 1:3–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunn R Jr (1983) The many disappointments of flexible exchange rates. Essays Int Finance (154), Princeton University, NJ

  • Eichengreen B, Park D, Ramayandi A, Shin K (2020) Exchange rates and insulation in emerging markets. Open Econ Rev 31:565–618

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel C (2015) Macroprudential policy in a world of high capital mobility: policy implications from an academic perspective. NBER Working Paper  (20951), Cambridge MA

  • Farhi E, Werning I (2014) Dilemma not trilemma? Capital controls and exchange rates with volatile capital flows. IMF Econ Rev 62:569–605

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer S (2001) Exchange rate regimes: is the bi-polar view correct? J Econ Perspect 15:3–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer S (2010) 50 years of monetary policy: what have we learned? In Reserve Bank of Australia: 50th Anniversary Symposium, C. Kent and M. Robson, eds., Canberra, 38–41

  • Fleming JM (1962) Domestic financial policies under fixed and under floating exchange rates. IMF Staff Pap 9:369–379

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleming JM (1974) Dual exchange markets and other remedies for disruptive capital flows. IMF Staff Pap 21:1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forbes KJ, Warnock FE (2012) Capital flow waves: surges, stops, flight, retrenchment. J Int Econ 88:235–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forbes KJ, Warnock FE (2020) Capital flow waves-- or ripples? Extreme capital flow movements since the crisis. NBER Work Pap (26851), Cambridge MA

  • Friedman BM (1975) Targets, instruments and indicators of monetary policy. J Monet Econ 1:443–473

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Froyen RT, Guender AV (2019) Optimal Monetary Policy under Uncertainty, 2nd edn. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, U.K.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh AR, Ostry JD, Qureshi MS (2016a) When do capital surges end in tears? American Economic Review 106:581–585

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh AR, Ostry JD, Chamon M (2016b) Two targets, two instruments: money and exchange rate policies in emerging market economies. J Int Money Financ 60:172–196

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guender AV (2006) Stabilizing properties of discretionary monetary policies in a small open economy: domestic versus CPI inflation targets. Economic Journal 116:309–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gurley J, Shaw ES (1960) Money in a Theory of Finance. Washington D.C.: Brookings Inst

  • Hicks J (1946) Value and Capital. Oxford University Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Ilzetzki I, Reinhart CM, Rogoff KS (2017) Exchange arrangements entering the 21st century: which anchors will hold? NBER Work Pap (23134)

  • Johnson HG (1967) Monetary policy in Canada. In Johnson, H. G. Essays Monet Econ. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press

  • Johnson HG (1969) The case for flexible exchange rates. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Rev 12–24

  • Kalemli-Özcan S (2019) US monetary policy and international risk spillovers. Jackson Hole Econ Policy Symp 1–78

  • Kenen PB (1985) Macroeconomic theory and policy: how the closed economy was opened. In: Jones RW, Kenen PB (eds) Handbook Int Econ 2. Elsevier Publishers, Amsterdam, pp 625–677

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein MW, Shambaugh JC (2015) Rounding the corners of the policy trilemma: sources of monetary policy autonomy. Am Econ J Macroecon 7:33–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landi VN, Schiavone A (2021) The effectiveness of capital controls. Open Econ Rev 32:183–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu Z, Spiegel MM (2015) Optimal monetary policy and capital account restrictions in a small open economy. IMF Econ Rev 63:298–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marion N (1981) Insulation properties of a two-tiered market in a portfolio balance model. Economica 48:61–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marston RC (1985) Stabilization policies in open economies. In: Jones RW, Kenen PB (eds) Handbook Int Econ 2. Elsevier Publishers, Amsterdam, 859–916

    Google Scholar 

  • Monacelli T (2013) Is monetary policy fundamentally different in an open economy? IMF Econ Rev 61:6–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mundell RA (1968) International Economics. Macmillan Company, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Mundell RA (1961) Flexible exchange rates and employment policy. Can J Econ Political Sci 27:509–517

    Google Scholar 

  • New Zealand Treasury (2021) Reserve Bank of New Zealand Act of 2021. https://www.treasury.govt.nz/news-and-events/reviews-consultation/reviewing-reserve-bank-act/reserve-bank-new-zealand-act-2021

  • Obstfeld M (2015) Trilemmas and trade-offs: living with financial globalization. Bank Int Settlement Work Pap (480)

  • Obstfeld M (2020) Harry Johnson’s case for flexible exchange rates—50 years later. Peterson Inst Int Econ (20–12) Washington DC

  • Ravenna F, Walsh CE (2006) Optimal monetary policy with the cost channel. J Monet Econ 53:199–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rey H (2013) Dilemma not trilemma: the global financial cycle and monetary policy independence. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City: Jackson Hole Econ Policy Symp 285–335

  • Rey H (2016) International channels of transmission of monetary policy and the Mundellian Trilemma. IMF Econ Rev 64:1–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sohmen E (1969) Flexible Exchange Rates. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, Illinois

    Google Scholar 

  • Svensson LEO (2000) Open economy inflation targeting. J International Econ 50:155-183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin J (1969) A general equilibrium approach to monetary theory. J Money, Credit, Bank 1:15–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin J (1982) Money and finance in the macroeconomic process. J Money, Credit, Bank 14:171–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turnovsky SJ (1983) Wage indexation and exchange market intervention in a small open economy. Can J Econ 16:574–592

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turnovsky SJ (1987) Exchange market intervention under alternative forms of exogenous disturbances. J Int Econ 17:279–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Hagen J (1993) Monetary policy coordination in the European monetary system. In M. Fratianni and D. Salvatore, eds., Monetary Policy in Developed Econ. Westport CT: Greenwood Press

  • Woodford M (2003) Interest and Prices. Princeton University Press, Princeton NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodford M (2011) Optimal monetary stabilization policy. In B.M. Friedman and M. Woodford, eds. Handbook Monet Econ 3B. Amsterdam: Elsevier

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to Stanley W. Black for many helpful comments at various stages in our research for this paper. We are also grateful to an Associate Editor for perceptive comments that improved the paper in important ways.

Funding

The authors have received no funding from outside sources for this research.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Richard T. Froyen.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of Interest

They have no conflicts of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Froyen, R.T., Guender, A.V. The Mundellian Trilemma and Optimal Monetary Policy in a World of High Capital Mobility. Open Econ Rev 33, 631–656 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-021-09662-2

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-021-09662-2

Keywords

JEL

Navigation