Skip to main content
Log in

Emerging Market Economies’ Challenge: Managing the Yield Curve in a Financially Globalized World

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In a financially globalized world, managing long-term interest rates through short-term interest rates can be difficult. In this paper, we examine whether net capital inflows contribute to weakening the link between short- and long-term interest rates. We find that more financially open economies or those with more developed financial markets tend to have a greater negative relationship between net capital inflows and short- to long-term interest rate pass-through. We also examine whether macroprudential policies can affect the extent of interest rate pass-through and find that broad-based capital macroprudential tools are effective in retaining control of interest rate pass-through.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In her view, the famous monetary trilemma – countries can achieve only two of the three open macro policy goals of monetary independence, exchange rate stability, and financial openness to the full extent – reduces to a dilemma between monetary independence and financial openness. For the trilemma vs. dilemma debate, refer to Aizenman, et al. (2016), Klein and Shambough (2015), Ricci and Shi (2016), and Han and Wei (2018).

  2. Emerging market economies (EMGs) are those classified as either emerging or frontier in 1980–1997 by the International Financial Corporation, plus Hong Kong and Singapore. This group of economies is a subset of the group of less developed countries (LDC). The industrialized countries (IDC) refer to traditional Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) member countries whose IMF numerical codes are below 186 plus Australia and New Zealand.

  3. The VIX measures the implied volatility of U.S. S&P 500 index options and is available from the Chicago Board Options Exchange. For the analyses on the factors that affect cross-border capital flows to EMGs, see Ahmed and Zlate (2013), Forbes and Warnock (2012), Ghosh, et al. (2012), Griffin, et al. (2004), and Fratzscher (2012) among many others.

  4. See Akinci and Olmstead-Rumsey (2017), Buch and Goldberg (2017), Cerutti et al. (2017ab), Ghosh et al. (2014, 2015), Ostry et al. (2012), among many others.

  5. The two dips in the correlations correspond to the time when the U.S. Federal Reserve changed its policy rate rapidly. The Federal Reserve raised the federal fund rate target from 1.00% in June 2004 to 5.25% in June 2006. It lowered the target from 5.25% in September 2007 to the 0.00–0.25 by December 2008.

  6. Negative values mean capital outflows.

  7. For data sources and theoretical predictions of the variables, refer to Appendix 1.

  8. See Appendix 1 for country groups.

  9. This result is consistent with Cottarelli and Kourelis (1994), Mojon (2000), and Sander and Kleimeier (2004).

  10. KAOPEN is based on information regarding restrictions in the IMF’s Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions (AREAER), and is constructed as the first standardized principal component of the variables indicating the presence of multiple exchange rates, restrictions on current account transactions, restrictions on capital account transactions, and the requirement of the surrender of export proceeds. Chinn and Ito (2006, 2008) explain the index in great details.

  11. For more on “financial centers,” see Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2017).

  12. Hence, in the second stage, the time fixed effects capture global financial cycles and the effects of the center economies’ monetary or financial shocks, i.e., “push factors.”.

  13. We continue to use the 2SLS estimation method for the rest of the paper.

  14. In the case of panel (4), the trilemma will not be ‘binding.’ Given that the three policy goals must be linearly related, when both financial openness and exchange rate stability are at low levels, that means policymakers are not optimizing their objective function, which means an inefficient outcome (Ito and Kawai 2014). However, that must indicate the level of monetary independence is higher.

  15. From a slightly different angle, it could be argued that the lack of financial development could lead to high risk premia on the side of emerging markets and make their securities highly correlated with U.S. financial markets because highly leveraged investors may try to recover their losses from investing in risky securities in the U.S. markets. Thought this is not what the estimation results show, it is an important point. We thank Hwee Kwan Chow for raising this point.

  16. Balakrishnan et al. (2012), IMF (2012), and Pradhan et al. (2011) provide comprehensive reviews and analyses pertaining to macro prudential policies implemented in EMGs.

  17. For more details on the dataset, refer to Appendix 2 as well as Cerruti et al. (2017b).

  18. The authors also argue that codifying the degree of intensity would involve a certain degree of subjective judgements.

  19. The variables for inflation and output volatilities as well as the constant term and yearly fixed effects are included in the estimation, though their estimates are not reported in the table to conserve space.

  20. For the EMG subsample, the estimate on the MPI is found to be significantly positive with the p-value of 1%. However, the estimate of net capital inflows becomes insignificant.

References

  • Ahmed S, Zlate A (2013) Capital flows to emerging market economies: A brave new world? Board of governors of the Federal reserve system international finance discussion papers, #1081. Washington, D.C.: Federal Reserve Board (June)

  • Aizenman J, Chinn MD, Ito H (2017) A financial spillovers and macroprudential policies, Forthcoming in open economic review

  • Aizenman J, Chinn MD, Ito H (2016) “Monetary policy spillovers and the trilemma in the new normal: periphery country sensitivity to core Country conditions,” J Int Money Finance 68

  • Aizenman J, Chinn MD, Ito H (2013) The “Impossible Trinity” hypothesis in an era of global imbalances: measurement and testing. Rev Int Econ 21(3):447–458

  • Akinci O, Olmstead-Rumsey J (2017) How effective are macroprudential policies? An empirical investigation. J Financ Intermed

  • Balakrishnan R, Nowak S, Panth S, Wu Y (2012) Surging capital flows to emerging asia: facts, impacts, and responses, IMF working paper WP/12/130. Washington, D.C.: Int Monet Fund (May)

  • Bernanke B (2005) The global saving glut and the U.S. current account. Remarks at the sandridge lecture, Virginia Association of Economics, Richmond, VA, March 10

  • Borio C, Disyatat P (2015) Capital flows and the current account: taking financing (more) seriously, BIS Working Papers, no 525, October

  • Borio C, Disyatat P (2011) Global imbalances and the financial crisis: link or no link? BIS Working Paper 346

  • Buch C, Goldberg L (2017) Cross-border prudential policy spillovers: how much? How Important? Evidence from the international banking research network, Int J Central Banking. March Issue, p. 505–558

  • Byrne JP, Fazio G, Fiess N (2010) Interest rate co-movements, global factors and the long end of the term spread. J Bank Finance 36:183–192

  • Caballero R, Farhi E, Gourinchas PO (2008) An equilibrium model of ‘Global Imbalances’ and Low Interest Rates. Am Econ Rev 98(1) (March):358–393

  • Caballero R, Farhi E, Gourinchas PO (2016) Safe asset scarcity and aggregate demand. American Econ Rev 106(5):513–518

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero R, Farhi E, Gourinchas PO (2017) The safe assets shortage conundrum. J Econ Perspect 31(3):29–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cerutti E, Claessens S, Laeven L (2017a) The use and effectiveness of macroprudential policies: new evidence. J Financial Stab 28(C):203–224

  • Cerutti E, Claessens S, Laeven L (2017b) Changes in prudential policy instruments – A new cross-country database. Int J Central Banking 13(1):477–503

  • Chinn MD, Ito H (2008) A new measure of financial openness. J Comp Policy Anal. Volume 10, Issue 3 (September), p. 309-322

  • Chinn MD, Ito H (2006) What matters for financial development? Capital controls, institutions, and interactions. J Develop Econ (JEDS) Volume 81. Issue 1, Pages 163–192 (October)

  • Clarida R (2005) Japan, China, and the U.S. Current account deficit. CATO Journal Vol. 25, No. 1 (Winter)

  • Cottarelli CA, Kourelis A (1994) Financial structure, bank lending rates and the transmission mechanism of monetary policy, IMF working paper WP/94/39 (Washington: International Monetary Fund)

  • Forbes KJ, Warnock FE (2012) Capital flow waves: surges, stops, flight, and retrenchment. J Int Econ 88(2):235–251

  • Fratzscher M (2012) Capital flows. push versus pull factors and the global financial crisis. J Int Econ, Elsevier 88(2):341–356

  • Ghosh AR, Kim J, Qureshi M, Zalduendo J (2012) Surges. IMF working paper WP/12/22

  • Ghosh AR, Qureshi MS, Sugawara N (2014) Regulating capital flows at both ends: does it work? IMF workinpPaper WP/14/188. Washington, D.C.: Int Monet Fund

  • Ghosh AR, Ostry JD, Qureshi MS (2015) Exchange rate management and crisis susceptibility: A reassessment. IMF Econ Rev 63(1):238–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenspan A (2005a) Current account at advancing enterprise 2005 conference, London, England, February 4

  • Greenspan A (2005b) Mortgage banking at American bankers association annual convention, Palm desert, California, September 26

  • Griffin J, Nardari F, Stulz R (2004) Are daily cross-border equity flows pushed or pulled? Rev Econ Stat 86(3):642–657

  • Han X, Wei SJ (2018) International transmissions of monetary shocks: between a trilemma and a dilemma. J Int Econ 110(C):205–219

  • He D, McCauley RN (2013) Transmitting global liquidity to east Asia: Policy rates, bond yields, currencies and dollar credit. BIS Working Paper No. 431

  • IMF (2012) The liberalization and management of capital flows: An institutional view. Staff Paper. https://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2012/111412.pdf. (Accessed 12 Nov 2012)

  • International Monetary Fund, Financial Stability Board, and Bank for International Settlements (2016) Elements of effective macroprudential policies – Lessons from international experience. Joint Report. https://www.imf.org/external/np/g20/pdf/2016/083116.pdf. Accessed 31 Aug 2016 

  • Ito H, Kawai M (2014) Determinants of the trilemma policy combination. ADBI working paper 456. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute

  • Jordà Ò, Schularick M, Taylor AM, Ward F (2019) Global financial cycles and risk premium. IMF Econ Rev 67(1):109–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein MW, Shambaugh JC (2015) Rounding the corners of the policy trilemma: sources of monetary policy autonomy. Am Econ J Macroecon 7(4):33–66

  • Laeven L Valencia F (2018) Systemic banking crises revisited, IMF working papers WP/18/206, Washington, D.C.: Int Monetary Fund

  • Lane P, Milesi-Ferretti GM (2001) The external wealth of nations: measures of foreign assets and liabilities for industrial and developing countries. J Int Econ 55:263–294

  • Lane P, Milesi-Ferretti GM (2007) The external wealth of nations Mark II: revised and extended estimates of foreign assets and liabilities, 1970–2004. J Int Econ 73(2):223–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane PR, Milesi-Ferretti GM (2017) International financial integration in the aftermath of the global financial crisis, IMF working paper no. 17/115

  • Mojon B (2000) Financial structure and the interest channel of the ECB monetary policy, ECB working paper No. 40 (Frankfurt, Germany: European Central Bank)

  • Obstfeld M (2012) Does the current account still matter? American economic review: Papers & Proceedings 102(3):1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostry J, Ghosh A, Chamon M, Qureshi M (2012) Tools for managing financial-stability risks from capital inflows. J Int Econ 88(2):407–421

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peiris SJ (2010) Foreign participation in emerging markets’. Local currency bond markets, IMF working paper 10/88 (Washington: International Monetary Fund)

  • Pradhan M, Balikrishnan R, Baqir R, Heenan G, Nowak S, Oner C, Panth S (2011) Policy responses to capital flows in emerging markets, paper for the bank of indonesia and IMF joint conference on Coping with Asia’s large capital inflows in a multi-speed global economy (Washington: International Monetary Fund)

  • Rey H (2013) Dilemma not trilemma: The global financial cycle and monetary policy independence, prepared for the Jackson hole meeting

  • Ricci LA, Shi W (2016) Trilemma or dilemma: inspecting the heterogeneous response of local currency interest rates to foreign rates, IMF working paper WP/16/75, Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund

  • Sander H, Kleimeier S (2004) Interest rate pass-through in an Enlarged Europe: the role of banking market structure for monetary policy transmission in transition economies, METEOR research memoranda No. 045, University of Maastricht (Netherlands)

  • Shin HS (2012) Global banking glut and loan risk premium. IMF Econ Rev 60(2):155–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svirydzenka K (2016) Introducing a new broad-based index of financial development, IMF working papers, WP/16/5. Washington, D.C.: Int Monet Fund

  • Warnock FE, Warnock VC (2009) International capital flows and U.S, Interest rates. J Int Money Finance 28:903–919

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

This research was conducted while Ito was a visiting fellow at RIETI. Ito is grateful for their generous support and hospitality. Ito and Tran thank Portland State University for financial support. All errors are ours.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hiro Ito.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1 Data Descriptions and Country Groups

1.1 Theoretical Predictions and Data Sources

KFlow – Net capital flows as a share of GDP. The data are extracted from the International Monetary Fund’s Balance of Payments database. Positive values of net capital inflows mean capital inflows while negative values mean capital outflows.

Relative income – The more developed a country of our concern is, the more smoothly the interest rate channel of monetary transmission should take place, i.e., the linkage between short-term and long-term interest rates gets stronger. Higher per capita income also reflects better institutional development, which can also contribute to smoother monetary transmission. We measure the level of economic development by using the per capita income data from Penn World Table 9.1 and normalizing it as a ratio to the U.S. per capita income level.

Inflation volatility – measured as the 5-year standard deviations of CPI-inflation. High inflation volatility, on the one hand, introduces uncertainty into the market signals that potentially reduces the effectiveness of the monetary policy transmission. Therefore, the coefficient may appear to be negative. On the other hand, more frequent episodes of high inflation volatility may also cause the risk premium to climb in order to incentivize borrowers to hold a risky asset. Consequently, we could also observe the longer end of the yield curve mounting to higher levels in the presence of inflation volatility. In other words, the term risk makes the yield curve often upward sloping. That instead suggests a positive coefficient.

Output volatility – measured as the 5-year standard deviations of real GDP growth rates. To a lesser extent, the same explanation may apply to output volatility, though it seems more reasonable to assume that greater output stability might lead to greater effectiveness of monetary policy due to increased predictability of both economic conditions and economic policy management, leading to smaller risk premium.

Output gap – the difference between the actual real GDP and the Hodrick-Prescott filtered GDP. Output gap may serve as a good proxy for a country’s level of policy rate, indicating whether the economy is on the state of rising or falling policy rate. Given the tendency of the yield curve to be upward sloping, a fall in the policy rate leads to a smaller response in the longer-term interest rate compared to when the policy rate is rising, which suggests that the coefficient on the output gap variable be negative.

Financial crisis – The dummy for a financial crisis is constructed based on Laeven and Valencia’s (2018) database on the occurrences of currency, banking and sovereign crises. The dummy takes the value of one if either or both of currency and banking crisis happen. This dummy might capture noise in the dependent variable since the policy rate disproportionally changes with respect to long-term interest rates in the case of a financial crisis.

Financial development – Financial development may matter for the interest rate pass-through since obviously more developed financial markets should facilitate monetary transmission. To measure the level of financial development, we use Svirydzenka’s (2016) “index of financial development” which is the first principal component of two sub-indexes, one that captures the development of financial markets (FM) and the other that reflects the development of financial institutions (FI).

Country List

Industrialized countries (IDC):

Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, Malta, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, United States.

Emerging Market Economies (EMEs):

Argentina, Bangladesh, Botswana, Brazil, Brunei, Bulgaria, Cote d’Ivoire, Cambodia, Chile, China, Colombia, Czech Republic, Ecuador, Egypt, Arab Rep., Ghana, Hong Kong, China, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Israel, Jamaica, Jordan, Kenya, Korea, Rep., Lithuania, Malaysia, Mauritius, Mexico, Morocco, Nigeria, Pakistan, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Russian Federation, Singapore, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, South Africa, Sri Lanka, Thailand, Trinidad and Tobago, Tunisia, Turkey, Venezuela, RB, Vietnam, Zimbabwe.

Emerging Asia:

China, Hong Kong, China, India, Indonesia, Korea, Rep., Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, Vietnam.

Appedix 2: Macroprudential Policy Index

Variable

Variable Name

Definition

Broad-based capital tools (CAPITAL)

DP

Time-Varying/Dynamic Loan-Loss Provisioning

Dummy for the use of a policy that requires banks to hold more loan-loss provisions during upturns

CTC

General Countercyclical Capital Buffer/Requirement

Dummy for the use of a policy that requires banks to hold more capital during upturns

SIFI

Capital Surcharges on Systematically Important Financial Institutions

Dummy for the use of a policy that requires Systematically Important Financial Institutions to hold a higher capital level than other financial institutions

INTER

Limits on Interbank Exposures

Dummy for the use of a policy that limits the fraction of liabilities held by the banking sector

Sectoral capital and asset-side tools (ASSET)

LTV_CAP

Loan-to-Value Ratio

Dummy for the use of LTV measures used as a strict cap on new loans as opposed to a loose guideline or merely an announcement of risk weights

DTI

Debt-to-Income Ratio

Dummy for the use of a policy that constrains household indebtedness by enforcing or encouraging a limit

LEV

Leverage Ratio

Dummy for the use of a policy that limits banks from exceeding a fixed minimum leverage ratio

CONC

Concentration Limits

Dummy for the use of a policy that limits the fraction of assets held by a limited number of borrowers

Liquidity-related tools (LIQUIDITY)

FC

Limits on Foreign Currency Loans

Dummy for the use of a policy that reduces vulnerability to foreign-currency risks

RR_REV

FX and/or Countercyclical Reserve Requirements

RR is a policy that limits credit growth. It can also be targeted to limit foreign-currency credit growth. RR_REV is a subset of RR that restricts to reserve requirements which i) imposes a specific wedge on foreign currency deposits or are adjusted countercyclically

CG

Limits on Domestic Currency Loans

Dummy for a policy that limits credit growth

TAX

Levy/Tax on Financial Institution

Dummy for taxes on the revenue of financial institutions

MPI

Macroprudential Policy Index (0 – 12)

LTV_CAP + DTI + DP + CTC + LEV + SIFI + INTER + CONC + FC + RR_REV + CG + TAX

  1. Source Table 1 of Cerutti et al. (2017ab), IMF-FSB-BIS (2016), Aizenman et al. (2017)

Appendix 3: Estimates of Net Capital Inflow and Macroprudential Policies, 1999 – 2016 

Dep. Var.: Est. beta

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

Net K-inflow

-1.925

-1.814

-2.226

-1.678

-1.931

-2.014

-1.800

(0.580)***

(0.612)***

(0.665)***

(0.605)***

(0.688)***

(0.601)***

(0.611)***

Loan loss-provision

0.190

      

(0.085)**

      

Countercyclical

 

-0.148

     

k-requirements

 

(0.108)

     

K-surcharge on

  

-0.408

    

SIFI

  

(0.151)***

    

Limits on interbank exposure

   

0.118

   
   

(0.053)**

   

Loan-to-value ratio

    

-0.009

  
    

(0.063)

  

Debt-to-income ratio

     

-0.017

 
     

(0.075)

 

Leverage ratio

      

-0.015

      

(0.080)

Concentration limits

       

Limits on foreign currency loan

       

Countercyclical reserve requirements

       

Limits on domestic currency loan

       

Levy on financial institution

       

Adjusted R 2

0.39

0.39

0.35

0.41

0.38

0.37

0.39

Dep. Var.: Est. beta

(8)

(9)

(10)

(11)

(12)

(13)

Net K-inflow

-1.734

-1.510

-1.891

-1.762

-1.769

-2.245

(0.608)***

(0.546)***

(0.636)***

(0.594)***

(0.595)***

(0.678)***

Loan loss-provision

     

0.161

     

(0.080)**

Countercyclical

     

-0.118

k-requirements

     

(0.144)

K-surcharge on

     

-0.413

SIFI

     

(0.202)**

Limits on interbank exposure

     

0.129

     

(0.056)**

Loan-to-value ratio

     

0.017

     

(0.068)

Debt-to-income ratio

     

-0.098

     

(0.068)

Leverage ratio

     

0.030

     

(0.072)

Concentration limits

0.052

    

-0.000

(0.044)

    

(0.049)

Limits on foreign currency loan

 

0.177

   

0.158

 

(0.073)**

   

(0.081)**

Countercyclical reserve requirements

  

0.074

  

0.053

  

(0.069)

  

(0.070)

Limits on domestic currency loan

   

-0.149

 

-0.218

   

(0.080)*

 

(0.089)**

Levy on financial institution

    

0.082

0.031

    

(0.106)

0.108

Adjusted R 2

0.40

0.43

0.38

0.40

0.39

0.40

  1. The variables for inflation and output volatilities as well as the constant term and yearly fixed effects are included in the estimation, though their estimates are not reported in the table to conserve space

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ito, H., Tran, P. Emerging Market Economies’ Challenge: Managing the Yield Curve in a Financially Globalized World. Open Econ Rev 34, 171–194 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-021-09661-3

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-021-09661-3

Keywords

Navigation