Skip to main content
Log in

Global Trade Flows: Revisiting the Exchange Rate Elasticities

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper contributes to the debate on the magnitude of exchange rate elasticities by providing a set of price and quantity elasticities for 51 advanced and emerging-market economies. Specifically, we report for each of these countries the elasticity of trade prices and trade quantities on the export and on the import side, as well as the reaction of the trade balance. To this aim, the paper uses a large unified database of highly disaggregated bilateral trade flows, covering 5000 products and more than 160 trading partners. We present a range of estimates using not only standard regression techniques but also generated regressors that aim to uncover changes in the exchange rate elasticities due to unobserved marginal costs and competitor prices in the importing market. Our results show that quantity elasticities are significantly below one, pass-through is incomplete and export prices react significantly to exchange rate changes. In spite of low quantity elasticities, the trade balance reacts positively to a depreciation in all countries because export and import prices adjust. Overall, our findings suggest that exchange rate changes can play an important role in addressing global trade imbalances.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The list of countries includes 26 emerging markets and 25 advanced economies and broadly corresponds to that of the IMF External Balance Assessment (EBA); see full list of countries in Table 1.

  2. In Tables 2 and 3 we report other key statistics such as the simple mean, a weighted mean using the relative size of nominal exports and imports, as well as the standard deviation of the coefficients across countries. In Section 4 we comment on selected country-specific results and compare aggregate elasticities between advanced and emerging-market economies.

  3. The coefficients that we estimated in the baseline regression for export and import prices are positively correlated with existing studies, as explained in Section 4.

  4. Note that our specifications are symmetric and linear, so an appreciation is expected to have the same effect as a depreciation, with the opposite sign.

  5. Given this definition of exchange rates, an increase in sijt implies a depreciation of country i’s currency, which improves its competitiveness in foreign markets.

  6. We refer to Friberg (1998) for the seminal contribution on the exchange rate pass-through with risk averse firms. In the robustness section, we analyze the exchange rate pass-through with respect to the forward exchange rate to mitigate the concern that the aggregate pass-through is driven by firms hedging exchange rate risk.

  7. Mumtaz et al. (2006) find evidence that neglecting cross-sector heterogeneity biases pass-through estimates.

  8. See the Appendix for details.

  9. We follow Gaulier et al. (2008) and define the weighting variable as follows:

  10. In the robustness section, we follow Boz et al. (2017) and explicitly distinguish between the bilateral exchange rate variation and the variation of the exporter’s currency to the US dollar.

  11. Note that for any triplet of countries a, b and c, we have \(\log s_{ab}=-\log s_{ba}\) and \(\log s_{ab}=\log s_{ac}-\log s_{cb}\) by arbitrage. The within transformation with time-varying exporter and importer-product fixed effects implies that \(\log s_{ab}-\log s_{ac}-\log s_{cb}\) equals zero. In this sense, the exchange rate is a monadic variable, see Head and Mayer (2014).

  12. The quantity equations are, for example, consistent with a two-tier CES demand system, where changes in GDP capture aggregate demand changes, see among others Imbs and Méjean (2015), and more generally with aggregate exchange rate regressions in the pricing-to-market literature, see Burstein and Gopinath (2014).

  13. In line with the definition of the bilateral exchange rate, a depreciation of the nominal exchange rate of exporter i increases si.

  14. The baseline regressions are nevertheless very informative as they report the reaction of prices and quantities to exchange rate changes as observed in the aggregate data. On the other hand, the fixed-effect regressions shed light on the role of specific factors that determine the aggregate response of trade prices and quantities to changes of the exchange rate.

  15. This finding is consistent with the evidence from Auer and Schoenle (2016), who use detailed US import data and show that the exchange rate pass-through is decreasing when controlling for price changes by competitors.

  16. We do not to report them in order to save space. Detailed results are available upon request.

References

  • Amiti M, Itskhoki O, Konings J (2014) Importers, exporters, and exchange rate disconnect. Am Econ Rev 104:1942–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amiti M, Itskhoki O, Konings J (2016) International shocks and domestic prices: how large are strategic complementarities?, NBER Working Papers, 22119

  • Atkeson A, Burstein A (2008) Pricing-to-market, trade costs, and international relative prices. Am Econ Rev 98:1998–2031

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auer RA (2015) Exchange rate pass-through, domestic competition, and inflation: Evidence from the 2005–08 revaluation of the Renminbi. Journal of Money Credit and Banking 47:1617–1650

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auer RA, Schoenle RS (2016) Market structure and exchange rate pass-through. J Int Econ 98:60–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker M, Fortin NM (2001) Occupational gender composition and wages in Canada, 1987–1988. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d’économique 34:345–376

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bas M, Mayer T, Thoenig M (2017) From micro to macro: Demand, supply, and heterogeneity in the trade elasticity. J Int Econ 108:1–19. (lead article)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berman N, Martin P, Mayer T (2012) How do different exporters react to exchange rate changes? Quarterly J Econ 127:437–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boz E, Gopinath G, Plagborg-Møller M (2017) Global trade and the dollar, Tech. rep., National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Burstein A, Gopinath G (2014) International prices and exchange rates. Handb Int Econ 4:391–451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bussière M (2013) Exchange rate pass-through to trade prices: the role of nonlinearities and asymmetries. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 75:731–758

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bussière M, Callegari G, Ghironi F, Sestieri G, Yamano N (2013) Estimating trade elasticities: Demand composition and the trade collapse of 2008 − 09. Am Econ J Macroeconomics 5:118–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bussière M, Delle Chiaie S, Peltonen TA (2014) Exchange rate pass-through in the global economy: The role of emerging market economies. IMF Econ Rev 62:146–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campa JM, Goldberg LS (2001) Employment versus wage adjustment and the US dollar. Rev Econ Stat 83:477–489

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campa JM, Goldberg LS (2005) Exchange rate pass-through into import prices. Rev Econ Stat 87:679–690

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti G, Dedola L (2005) A macroeconomic model of international price discrimination. J Int Econ 67:129–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti G, Dedola L, Leduc S (2007) Optimal monetary policy and the sources of local-currency price stability. In: International dimensions of monetary policy, University of Chicago Press, pp 319–367

  • Devereux M, Dong W, Tomlin B (2015) Exchange rate pass-through, currency invoicing and trade partners, Bank of Canada Working Paper, 2015–31

  • Feenstra RC, Luck PA, Obstfeld M, Russ KN (2014) In search of the Armington elasticity, NBER Working Papers, 20063

  • Fischer S (2015) The transmission of exchange rate changes to output and inflation, monetary policy implementation and transmission in the post-crisis period conference federal reserve system, Washington, D.C

  • Fitzgerald D, Haller S (2014) Exporters and shocks: Dissecting the international elasticity puzzle, NBER Working Papers, 19968

  • Forbes K (2015) Much ado about something important: How do exchange rate movements affect inflation? Macro and finance research group annual conference, Cardiff, England

  • Friberg R (1998) In which currency should exporters set their prices? J Int Econ 45:59–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friberg R, Wilander F (2008) The currency denomination of exports - a questionnaire study. J Int Econ 75:54–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garetto S (2016) Firms’ heterogeneity, incomplete information, and pass-through. J Int Econ 101:168–179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaulier G, Lahrèche-Révil A, Méjean I (2008) Exchange-rate pass-through at the product level. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d’économique 41:425–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaulier G, Zignago S (2010) BACI: International trade database at the product-level, CEPII Working Paper, 2010–23

  • Gopinath G (2015) The international price system, NBER Working Papers, 21646

  • Gust C, Leduc S, Sheets N (2009) The adjustment of global external balances: Does partial exchange-rate pass-through to trade prices matter? J Int Econ 79:173–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Head K, Mayer T (2014) Gravity equations: Workhorse, toolkit, and cookbook, Handbook of international economics, 4

  • Hooper P, Johnson K, Marquez JR (2002) Trade elasticities for the G-7 countries. Econ J 112:F377–F378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ihrig JE, Marazzi M, Rothenberg AD (2006) Exchange-rate pass-through in the G-7 countries, FRB International Finance Discussion Paper, 851

  • Imbs J, Méjean I (2015) Elasticity optimism. Am Econ J Macroeconomics 7:43–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knetter MM (1989) Price discrimination by US and German exporters. Am Econ Rev 79:198–210

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1986) Pricing to market when the exchange rate changes. National Bureau of Economic Research, Tech. rep.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Leigh D, Lian W, Poplawski-Ribeiro M, Tsyrennikov V (2015) Exchange rates still matter for trade, vol. WEO October Chapter 3, International Monetary Fund

  • Mantega G (2010) Brazil in currency war, Financial Times, Interview

  • Mishra P, Spilimbergo A (2011) Exchange rates and wages in an integrated world. Am Econ J Macroeconomics 3:53–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mumtaz H, Oomen O, Wang J (2006) Exchange rate pass-through into UK import prices, Bank of England working paper, 312

  • Ossa R (2015) Why trade matters after all? J Int Econ 97:266–277

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pagan A (1984) Econometric issues in the analysis of regressions with generated regressors. Int Econ Rev 25:221–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Redding S, Venables AJ (2004) Economic geography and international inequality. J Int Econ 62:53–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmalensee R, Joskow PL (1986) Estimated parameters as independent variables: An application to the costs of electric generating units. J Econ 31:275–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yellen J (2015) Inflation dynamics and monetary policy, philip gamble memorial lecture university of massachusetts. Amherst, Massachusetts

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Matthieu Bussière.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We would like to thank an anonymous referee, Olivier Blanchard, Emine Boz, Meredith Crowley, Linda Goldberg, Jean Imbs, Oleg Itskhoki, Oleksiy Kryvtsov, Philippe Martin, Thierry Mayer, Isabelle Méjean, Kadee Russ, Cyrille Schwellnus, Vincent Vicard and seminar participants at the 2018 ASSA meetings, Deutsche Bundesbank, the Banque de France, the Bank of Canada, Michigan State University and at the Paris School of Economics for helpful comments and discussions. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Banque de France of the Eurosystem and the Bank of Canada.

Appendix

Appendix

To show that the import and the export exchange rate pass−through are linked, consider the following simplified example. Suppose there are three countries: France, the United Kingdom and the United States. Based on Eq. 5, we can write the import exchange rate pass−through for the United States as follows:

$$ \log\left( \frac{p_{US,i,t}}{p_{US,i,t-1}}\right)=\beta_{US}^{M}\log\left( \frac{s_{US,i,t}}{s_{US,i,t-1}}\right), $$

where pUS,i,t is the import price of the United States from exporter i at the time t and \(\beta _{US}^{M}\) is the import price elasticity. Equivalently, we can write the change in the import price to the United States as a function of the export price elasticity of all i countries, i.e., France and the United Kingdom. Consider the export price of France to the United States in US dollars:

$$ \log\left( \frac{p_{US,FR,t}}{p_{US,FR,t-1}}\right)=\beta_{FR}^{X}\log\left( \frac{s_{US,FR,t}}{s_{US,FR,t-1}}\right) $$

Then the import price of the United States can be written as the trade−weighted average of the changes in the bilateral import prices with France and the bilateral import prices with the United Kingdom:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&w_{US,FR,t}\log\left( \frac{p_{US,FR,t}}{p_{US,FR,t-1}}\right)+w_{US,UK,t}\log\left( \frac{p_{US,UK,t}}{p_{US,UK,t-1}}\right)\\&=&\beta_{US}^{M}\left( w_{US,FR,t}\log\left( \frac{s_{US,FR,t}}{s_{US,FR,t-1}}\right)+w_{US,UK,t}\log\left( \frac{s_{US,UK,t}}{s_{US,UK,t-1}}\right)\right), \end{array} $$

where wUS,i,t is the import share of country i in total US imports. Substituting the equation of the export elasticity into the import elasticity, we get:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&w_{US,FR,t}\beta_{FR}^{X}\log\left( \frac{s_{US,FR,t}}{s_{US,FR,t-1}}\right)+w_{US,UK,t}\beta_{UK}^{X}\log\left( \frac{s_{US,UK,t}}{s_{US,UK,t-1}}\right)\\ &=&\beta_{US}^{M}\left( w_{US,FR,t}\log\left( \frac{s_{US,FR,t}}{s_{US,FR,t-1}}\right)+w_{US,UK,t}\log\left( \frac{s_{US,UK,t}}{s_{US,UK,t-1}}\right)\right). \end{array} $$

Thus, the import pass−through coefficient is a weighted average of all export pass−through coefficients of all trading partners. More generally, we can write the link between the import and elasticity for an arbitrary number of trading partners J:

$$ \prod\limits_{j=1}^{J}\left( \frac{s_{US,j,t}}{s_{US,j,t-1}}\right)^{w_{US,j,t}{\beta_{j}^{X}}}=\left( \prod\limits_{j=1}^{J}\left( \frac{s_{US,j,t}}{s_{US,j,t-1}}\right)^{w_{US,j,t}}\right)^{\beta_{US}^{M}} $$

Next, suppose that the US dollar depreciates by 10% against all other currencies, i.e., \(\frac {s_{US,j,t}}{s_{US,j,t-1}}=1.1 \forall j\), then \({\sum }_{j=1}^{J}w_{US,j,t}{\beta _{j}^{X}}=\beta _{US}^{M}\) and the import pass−through is an arithmetic mean of the export pass−through coefficient of trading partners.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bussière, M., Gaulier, G. & Steingress, W. Global Trade Flows: Revisiting the Exchange Rate Elasticities. Open Econ Rev 31, 25–78 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-019-09573-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-019-09573-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation