Skip to main content
Log in

The Owen–Shapley Spatial Power Index in Three-Dimensional Space

  • Published:
Group Decision and Negotiation Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Inspired by Owen’s (Nav Res Logist Quart 18:345–354, 1971) previous work on the subject, Shapley (A comparison of power indices and a non-symmetric generalization. Rand Corporation, Santa Monica, 1977) introduced the Owen–Shapley spatial power index, which takes the ideological location of individuals into account, represented by vectors in the Euclidean space \({\mathbb {R}}^{m}\), to measure their power. In this work we study the Owen–Shapley spatial power index in three-dimensional space. Peters and Zarzuelo (Int J Game Theory 46:525–545, 2017) carried out a study of this index for individuals located in two-dimensional space, but pointed out the limitation of the two-dimensional feature. In this work focusing on three-dimensional space, we provide an explicit formula for spatial unanimity games, which makes it possible to calculate the Owen–Shapley spatial power index of any spatial game. We also give a characterization of the Owen–Shapley spatial power index employing two invariant positional axioms among others. Finally, we calculate this power index for the Basque Parliament, both in the two-dimensional and three-dimensional cases. We compare these positional indices against each other and against those that result when classical non-positional indices are considered, such as the Shapley–Shubik power index (Am Polit Sci Rev 48(3):787–792, 1954) and the Banzhaf-normalized index (Rutgers Law Rev 19:317–343, 1965).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alonso-Meijide JM, Fiestras-Janeiro MG, García-Jurado I (2011) A new power index for spatial games. Modern Mathematical tools and techniques in capturing complexity understandig complex systems, pp 275–285

  • Banzhaf JF (1965) Weighted voting doesn’t work: a mathematical analysis. Rutgers Law Rev 19:317–343

    Google Scholar 

  • Barr J, Passarelli F (2009) Who has the power in the EU? Math Soc Sci 57:339–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benati S, Marzetti GV (2013) Probabilistic spatial power indexes. Soc Choice Welf 40:391–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernardi J (2018) A new axiomatization of the Banzhaf index for games with abstention. Group Decis Negot 27:165–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casey J (1889) A treatise On spherical trigonometry, and its application to geodesy and astronomy with numerous examples. (www.survivorlibrary.com)

  • Carreras F, Albina-Puente M (2015) María Albina Puente Multinomial probabilistic values. Group Decis Negot 24:981–991

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubey P (1975) On the uniqueness of the Shapley value. Int J Game Theory 4:131–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubey P, Einy E, Haimanko O (2005) Compound voting and the Banzhaf index. Games Econ Behav 51:20–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Einy E (1987) Semivalues of simple games. Math Oper Res 12:185–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Einy E, Haimanko O (2011) Characterizations of the Shapley–Shubik power index without the efficiency axiom. Games Econ Behav 73:615–621

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freixas J (2020) The banzhaf value for cooperative and simple multichoice games. Group Decis Negot 29:61–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin M, Nganmeni Z, Tchantcho B (2014) The Owen and Shapley spatial power indices: a comparison and a generalization. Working Paper, THEMA, Cergy Pontoise

  • Peters H, Zarzuelo JM (2017) An axiomatic characterization of the Owen–Shapley spatial power index. Int J Game Theory 46:525–545

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen G (1971) Political games. Nav Res Logist Quart 18:345–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen G (1972) Multilinear extensions of games. Manag Sci 18:64–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen G, Shapley LS (1989) Optimal location of candidates in ideological space. Int J Game Theory 18:229–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Passarelli F, Barr J (2007) Preferences, the agenda setter, and the distribution of power in the EU. Soc Choice Welf 28:41–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapley L S (1977) A comparison of power indices and a non-symmetric generalization. Paper P5872, Rand Corporation, Santa Monica, CA

  • Shapley LS, Shubik M (1954) A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a committee system. Am Polit Sci Rev 48(3):787–792

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shenoy PP (1982) The Banzhaf power index for political games. Math Soc Sci 2:299–315

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to M. J. Albizuri.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

This work has been partially supported by the Ministry of Science and Innovation (PID2019-105291GB-I00), and by UPV/EHU (GIU20/019)

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Lemma 5

By 3DPI, without a loss of generality, we can suppose that \(\measuredangle aed=\measuredangle aec=\pi /2\) (fixing e,  and moving c and d towards or outwards a). By DP and 3DPI, we have to prove

$$\begin{aligned}&\varphi _{0}\left( \left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} ,u_{\left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} },p_{\left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} }\right) \\&\quad =\varphi _{0}\left( \left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} ,u_{\left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} },q_{\left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} }\right) +\varphi _{0}\left( \left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} ,u_{\left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} },s_{\left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} }\right) -\frac{1}{4}. \end{aligned}$$

Let \(d^{\prime }=d+(b-a)\), \(e^{\prime }=e+(b-a)\) and \(c^{\prime }=c+(b-a)\) (Fig. 13). Consider \({\widetilde{N}}=\left\{ 0,1,2,3,4,5\right\} \) and \( {\widetilde{p}},{\widetilde{q}},{\widetilde{s}}\in C ^{{\widetilde{N}}}\) such that \({\widetilde{p}}_{\left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} }=p_{\left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} }\) , \({\widetilde{q}}_{\left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} }=q_{\left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} }\), \( {\widetilde{s}}_{\left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} }=s\), \(\left( {\widetilde{p}}_{4}, {\widetilde{p}}_{5}\right) =\left( c^{\prime },d^{\prime }\right) \), \(\left( {\widetilde{q}}_{4},{\widetilde{q}}_{5}\right) =\left( e^{\prime },d^{\prime }\right) \) and \(\left( {\widetilde{s}}_{4},{\widetilde{s}}_{5}\right) =\left( c^{\prime },e^{\prime }\right) .\)

Fig. 13
figure 13

In this figure c′, d′ and e′ are added

By DP and 3DPI, the equality to prove is

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) =\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) +\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{s}}\right) - \frac{1}{4}. \end{aligned}$$
(6)

Since \(\varphi \) is a power index,

$$\begin{aligned} \sum \limits _{j=0}^{5}\varphi _{j}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}} },{\widetilde{p}}\right) =1. \end{aligned}$$
(7)

By AN and RI, taking Q the plane through \(a+0.5\left( b-a\right) \) with normal vector \(b-a\), equality (7) turns into

$$\begin{aligned} 2\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) +2\varphi _{1}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) +2\varphi _{2}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) =1. \end{aligned}$$
(8)

(i) We obtain another expression for \(\varphi _{2}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{ {\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) \). DP and 3DPI imply

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi _{2}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) =\varphi _{2}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) \text {,} \end{aligned}$$
(9)

and since \(\varphi \) is a power index,

$$\begin{aligned} \sum \limits _{j=0}^{5}\varphi _{j}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}} },{\widetilde{q}}\right) =1. \end{aligned}$$

Again, AN and RI, with Q the plane through \(a+0.5\left( b-a\right) \) with normal vector \(\left( b-a\right) \), transform this equality into

$$\begin{aligned} 2\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) +2\varphi _{1}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) +2\varphi _{2}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) =1. \end{aligned}$$

Taking into account that \(\left( \measuredangle {\widetilde{q}}_{0}\widetilde{q }_{1}{\widetilde{q}}_{2},\measuredangle {\widetilde{q}}_{0}{\widetilde{q}}_{1} {\widetilde{q}}_{4},\measuredangle {\widetilde{q}}_{2}{\widetilde{q}}_{1} {\widetilde{q}}_{4}\right) =\left( \pi /2,\pi /2,\pi /2\right) \), Lemma 4 implies

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi _{1}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) = \frac{1}{8}, \end{aligned}$$

and hence

$$\begin{aligned} 2\varphi _{2}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) = \frac{3}{4}-2\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{q}} \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(10)

Therefore, this equality and (9) imply

$$\begin{aligned} 2\varphi _{2}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) = \frac{3}{4}-2\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{q}} \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(11)

(ii) We obtain another expression for \(\varphi _{1}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{ {\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) \). Similarly, by DP and 3DPI it holds

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi _{1}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) =\varphi _{1}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{s}}\right) , \end{aligned}$$

and reasoning as in (i) we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} 2\varphi _{1}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{s}}\right) = \frac{3}{4}-2\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{s}} \right) . \end{aligned}$$

And hence,

$$\begin{aligned} 2\varphi _{1}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) = \frac{3}{4}-2\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{s}} \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(12)

Substituting (11) and ( 12) in (8), equality (6) is obtained.

Finally, if \(\measuredangle cae=\measuredangle dae\), the equality to prove is

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) =2\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) - \frac{1}{4}. \end{aligned}$$

By AN and RI, with Q the plane through e with normal vector \(c-e\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi _{2}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) =\varphi _{1}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{s}}\right) , \end{aligned}$$

which, together with (10) and ( 12), implies

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) =\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{s}}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Substituting this equality in (6), we get the result we require. \(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 7

By 3DPI, without loss of generality, we can suppose that \(\measuredangle aed=\measuredangle aec=\pi /2\). Let \(a^{\prime }=e+(e-a)\), \(b^{\prime }=b+2(e-a)\), \(c^{\prime }=c+(b-a)\), \(d^{\prime }=d+(b-a)\) and \(e^{\prime }=e+(b-a)\) (Fig. 14), and consider \({\widetilde{N}} =\left\{ 0,1,2,3,4,5,6,7\right\} \), \({\widetilde{p}}\in C ^{{\widetilde{N}} }\) such that \({\widetilde{p}}_{\left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} }=p_{\left\{ 0,1,2,3\right\} }\), \(\left( {\widetilde{p}}_{4},{\widetilde{p}}_{5},{\widetilde{p}} _{6},{\widetilde{p}}_{7}\right) =\left( a^{\prime },b^{\prime },c^{\prime },d^{\prime }\right) \), and \({\widetilde{q}}\in C ^{{\widetilde{N}} \backslash \{1,6\}}\) such that \({\widetilde{p}}_{{\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\}}={\widetilde{q}}_{{\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\}}\).

Fig. 14
figure 14

In this figure a′, b′, c′, d′ and e′ are added

By DP and 3DPI,

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi _{2}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) =\varphi _{2}\left( {\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\},u_{{\widetilde{N}} \backslash \{1,6\}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(13)

RI and AN imply

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) =\varphi _{3}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) =\varphi _{4}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) =\varphi _{5}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi _{2}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) =\varphi _{7}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) ,\varphi _{1}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) =\varphi _{6}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) , \end{aligned}$$

and therefore, taking the definition of a power index into account,

$$\begin{aligned} 2\varphi _{2}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) =1-4\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) -2\varphi _{1}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(14)

RI and AN imply \(\varphi _{2}\left( {\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\},u_{ {\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) =\varphi _{7}\left( {\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\},u_{{\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\}}, {\widetilde{q}}\right) \) and

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\},u_{{\widetilde{N}} \backslash \{1,6\}},{\widetilde{q}}\right)= & {} \varphi _{3}\left( {\widetilde{N}} \backslash \{1,6\},u_{{\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) \\= & {} \varphi _{4}\left( {\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\},u_{{\widetilde{N}} \backslash \{1,6\}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) =\varphi _{5}\left( {\widetilde{N}} \backslash \{1,6\},u_{{\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) , \end{aligned}$$

and hence, taking the definition of a power index into account,

$$\begin{aligned} 2\varphi _{2}\left( {\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\},u_{{\widetilde{N}} \backslash \{1,6\}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) =1-4\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}} \backslash \{1,6\},u_{{\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(15)

Substituting ( 14) and ( 15) in ( 13) , we get:

$$\begin{aligned} -2\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) -\varphi _{1}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}}\right) =-2\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\},u_{{\widetilde{N}} \backslash \{1,6\}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Since \(\varphi _{1}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}},{\widetilde{p}} \right) \ge 0\), then \(\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}}, {\widetilde{p}}\right) \le \varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\},u_{{\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) \). By DP and 3DPI, it holds \(\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}},u_{{\widetilde{N}}}, {\widetilde{p}}\right) =\varphi _{0}\left( N,u_{S},p\right) \) and \(\varphi _{0}\left( {\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\},u_{{\widetilde{N}}\backslash \{1,6\}},{\widetilde{q}}\right) =\varphi _{0}\left( N,u_{S},q\right) \), and hence \(\varphi _{0}\left( N,u_{S},p\right) \le \varphi _{0}\left( N,u_{S},q\right) \). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Albizuri, M.J., Goikoetxea, A. The Owen–Shapley Spatial Power Index in Three-Dimensional Space. Group Decis Negot 30, 1027–1055 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10726-021-09746-x

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10726-021-09746-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation