Skip to main content
Log in

The Effect of Stake Size in Experimental Bargaining and Distribution Games: A Survey

  • Published:
Group Decision and Negotiation Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We review the literature on bargaining and distribution experiments to investigate whether changes in stake size have significant effects on behaviour in laboratory/field settings. We conclude that experiments in this field do not lead to clear/common results. The joint presence of opposing factors (e.g., increasing relative risk aversion and increasing cost of fairness) might be one reason contributing to this. Moreover, we argue that variables such as subjects’ financial conditions, cognitive abilities, risk attitudes, loss-aversion, justice orientations, and relevant personality characteristics should be controlled in laboratory experiments to understand the effect of stake size on behaviour, more clearly. Finally, quasi-experiments using data from (very) high-stake games/events and meta-analysis studies should complement (individual) controlled experiments.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A relatively recent yet influential book by Bardsley et al. (2010) devoted two chapters to these issues.

  2. We do not focus on the effects of a presence (real) versus absence (hypothetical) of financial incentives here (see Hertwig and Ortmann 2001 for a great discussion). Nevertheless, for the sake of giving a more complete picture we will include some studies comparing behavioral patterns in ultimatum, dictator, and trust games with real versus hypothetical stakes.

  3. Bearden (2001) surveyed ultimatum game experiments and he had a section in the survey on the stake size effect. He concluded similarly by saying that the effects found were weaker than he thought and further data is needed for better understanding.

  4. It is worth mentioning that we included also working papers that are not published yet to avoid possible publication biases that may arise in survey studies. We also want to mention that we cover around fifty studies after 1999, which is the publication date of Camerer and Hogarth (1999).

  5. For instance, a proposer who becomes increasingly risk averse as the stake increases may tend to make proportionally more generous offers. On the other hand, if he believes that fairness is a normal good (for the responder) and the cost of behaving fair-mindedly increases as offers become more generous in absolute terms, he may make more generous offers in absolute terms but less generous in relative terms. Hence, the net effect can be indeterminate.

  6. In some of the studies we investigate, the effect of stake-size on individual behaviour is not the main research question. Rather, the authors implement different stake-sizes to test the robustness of their results. When we report such studies, we focus on those parts where they test for stake-size effects.

  7. This hypothesis is empirically supported by studies such as Binswanger (1981), Kachelmeier and Shehata (1992), Bombardini and Trebbi (2005), Andersen et al. (2008), Baltussen et al. (2008) and Post et al. (2008).

  8. This argument (i.e., decision-making has cognitive costs) is supported by recent neuro-scientific research. For further reading, the reader is referred to McGuire and Botvinick (2010).

  9. Their model used Bolton and Ockenfels (2000) inequity averse preferences as a primitive. Note that, Bolton and Ockenfels (2000) and Rabin (1993) both imply that as the stakes increase, rejections of unfair offers will vanish.

  10. This is the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium (SPNE) prediction. Nash equilibrium (NE) concept predicts other outcomes, as well. Nevertheless, SPNE is much more frequently employed in extensive form games (such as the ultimatum game) due to a weakness of NE in capturing sequential rationality.

  11. This article consists of two sections which are the bargaining game and the market game. From the point of the current study, only the bargaining section is explained.

  12. In the dictator game, like in the ultimatum game, first player proposes a division. However, there is no decision to be made for the second player, i.e., the second player cannot accept or reject. In other words, the first player rather dictates the division. Hence the name, dictator game.

  13. Later, Gillis and Hettler (2007) conducted a multiple-round ultimatum game experiment with real versus hypothetical stakes ($10) and found mixed results. In particular, subjects offered—on average—less in the hypothetical stake treatment. However, this effect was not present in the first round of play but became apparent in later rounds.

  14. Another well-known study on ultimatum games where the stake-size is asymmetric information is Nagel and Mitzkewitz (1993). In that study, possible stake sizes were DM1.20, DM2.40, DM3.60, DM4.80, DM6, and DM7.20. The authors reported differences in behaviour across (two versions of the) ultimatum games with different stake sizes.

  15. In the strategy method, subjects declare their decisions for all their possible roles and for all possible situations beforehand. For example, in an ultimatum game, they announce what will be their offer when they are proposer, what will be their answer to all possible offers. After that, roles of players are determined, they are paired up with each other and payoffs are determined according to their strategies.

  16. A recent study by Griffin et al. (2012) also investigated racial differences in ultimatum game behaviour. The authors varied the stake-size between $5 and $100. They concluded that stake-size did not significantly affect responders’ acceptance decisions.

  17. Since the aim of the study is analysing the behaviour of the responders, the possible experimenter demand effects resulting from the mentioned explanation does not pose a problem.

  18. It should be noted that the actual aim of this experiment was not to measure the effects of the amount of money used on the subjects’ behaviour. Accordingly, the change in stakes was implemented only in the last period. Factors such as experience, last period, and boredom effects might have introduced confounds.

  19. The authors used different media (e.g., lab, newspaper, internet) and reached different subject pools (e.g., newspaper readers, business executives, students). They also used different payment methods (e.g., paying everyone their full earnings, randomized payment).

  20. For a comprehensive survey of experiments on bargaining games with joint production, see Karagözoğlu (2012).

  21. “Non-bargaining distribution games” might have been more informative. We are aware of the fact that these games also involve an efficiency component. At the cost of using the label “distribution games” in a way possibly different than the standard one, we use it to differentiate them from bargaining games.

  22. For alternative/opposing arguments, the reader is referred to Bardsley (2008) and List (2007).

  23. There is a lot of important methodological details in Naef and Schupp (2009) study, which we cannot cover here, in this kind of a paper. Hence, the interested reader is referred to the original paper for such details.

  24. For instance, we know that culture plays a role in shaping subjects’ behaviour in social interactions (Henrich et al. 2001; Herrmann et al. 2008), which may make it difficult to generalize these findings. See also Raihani et al. (2013) for a recent study finding behavioural differences across subjects in USA and India in online dictator games with $1, $5, and $10 stakes.

  25. This study and aforementioned Goldreich and Pomorski (2011) study are not experiments conducted in a controlled lab environment. Such experiments are called quasi-experiments in the literature.

  26. In a recent paper very similar to this one, Van den Assem et al. (2012) analysed the cooperative behaviour in the television show, Split or Steal. The stake-size varies between a few dollars and $175,000, averaging over $20,000. The authors found only limited support for the hypothesis that cooperation will decrease as the stakes get larger.

  27. It is worthwhile emphasizing that we are advocating to control only those variables for which there exists some form of theory and/or wide-spread empirical evidence for the link between them and the investigated behaviour.

  28. An important concern here would be anonymity of participants. Nevertheless, this would not be a major issue since (i) participants would be asked to generate participant id’s that conceal their identity and (ii) payment methods that keep participant id’s anonymous to the researcher already exist and are used.

  29. Recently, there has been an increased interest in meta-analysis studies in experimental economics. The reader is referred to Cooper and Dutcher (2011) for ultimatum games, Engel (2011) for dictator games, and Johnson and Mislin (2011) for trust games.

References

  • Amir O, Rand DG, Gal YK (2012) Economic games on the internet: the effect of $1 stakes. Plos ONE 7:e31461

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersen S, Harrison G, Lau M, Rutstroem E (2008) Risk aversion in game shows. In: Cox JC, Harrison GW (eds) Risk aversion in experiments (Research in experimental economics, vol 12). Emerald Group Publishing, Bingley, pp 359–404

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Andersen S, Ertaç S, Gneezy U, Hoffman M, List JA (2011) Stakes matter in ultimatum games. Am Econ Rev 101:3427–3439

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltussen G, Post T, van den Assem M (2008) Risky choice and the relative size of stakes. unpublished manuscript

  • Bardsley N (2008) Dictator game giving: altruism or artefact? Exp Econ 11:1221–1233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bardsley N, Cubitt R, Loomes G, Moffat P, Starmer C, Sugden R (2010) Experimental economics: rethinking the rules. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Bearden JN (2001) Ultimatum bargaining game experiments: the state of the art. Working paper

  • Bellemare C, Sebald A, Suetens S (2013) Heterogeneous guilt aversion and incentive effects. Working paper

  • Ben-Ner A, Kramer A, Levy O (2008) Economic and hypothetical dictator game experiments: incentive effects at the individual level. J Socio-Econ 37:1775–1784

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berg J, Dickhout J, McKabe K (1995) Trust, reciprocity, and social-history. Games Econ Behav 10:122–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binmore K, Shaked A, Sutton J (1985) Testing noncooperative bargaining theory: a preliminary study. Am Econ Rev 75:1178–1180

    Google Scholar 

  • Binswanger HP (1981) Attitudes toward risk: theoretical implications of an experiment in rural India. Econ J 91:867–890

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolle F (1990) High reward experiments without high expenditure for the experimenter? J Econ Psychol 11:157–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton GE (1991) A comparative model of bargaining: theory and evidence. Am Econ Rev 81:1096–1136

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton GE, Ockenfels A (2000) ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. Am Econ Rev 90:166–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton GE, DeBruyn A (2008) Estimating the influence of fairness on bargaining behavior. Manag Sci 54:1774–1797

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bombardini M, Trebbi F (2005) Risk aversion and expected utility theory: A field experiment with large and small stakes. unpublished manuscript

  • Buchan N, Croson R (2004) The boundaries of trust: own and others’ actions in the US and China. J Econ Behav Organ 55:483–504

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C (1990) Behavioral game theory. In: Hogarth R (ed) Insights in decision making. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C (2003) Behavioural game theory: experiments in strategic interaction. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C (2010) Removing financial incentives demotivates the brain. Proc Natl Acad Sci 107:20849–20850

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C, Hogarth RM (1999) The effects of financial incentives in experiments: a review and capital–labor–production framework. J Risk Uncertain 19:7–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C, Nave G, Smith A (2015) Dynamic unstructured bargaining with private information and deadlines: theory and experiment. Caltech HSS working paper

  • Cameron LA (1999) Raising the stakes in the ultimatum game: experimental evidence from Indonesia. Econ Inq 37:47–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter J, Verhoogen E, Burks S (2005) The effect of stakes in distribution experiments. Econ Lett 86:393–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Centorrino S, Djemai E, Hopfensitz A, Milinski M, Seabright P (2015) Honest signalling in trust interactions: smiles rated as genuine induce trust and signal higher earning opportunities. Evol Hum Behav 36:8–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherry TL, Frykblom P, Shogren J (2002) Hardnose the dictator. Am Econ Rev 92:1218–1221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christie R, Geis F (1970) Studies in Machiavellianism. Academic Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper DJ, Dutcher EG (2011) The dynamics of responder behavior in ultimatum games: a meta-study. Exp Econ 14:519–546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dalbert C (1999) The world is more just form me than generally: about the personal belief in a just world scale’s validity. Soc Justice Res 12:79–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dalbert C, Montada L, Schmitt M (1987) Glaube an eine gerechte welt als motiv: Validierungskorrelate zweier Skalen. Psychol Beitr 29:596–615

    Google Scholar 

  • Dickinson DL (2000) Ultimatum decision-making: a test of reciprocal kindness. Theor Decis 48:151–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen T, Falk A, Huffman D, Sunde U, Schupp J, Wagner G (2011) Individual risk attitudes: measurement, determinants, and behavioural consequences. J Eur Econ Assoc 9:522–550

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel C (2011) Dictator games: a meta study. Exp Econ 14:583–610

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk A, Fehr E (2003) Why labour market experiments? Labour Econ 10:399–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Schmidt KM (1999) A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Q J Econ 114:817–868

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Fischbacher U, Tougareva E (2014) Do high stakes and competition undermine fair behaviour? Evidence from Russia. J Econ Behav Organ 108:354–363

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr-Duda H, Bruhin A, Epper TF, Schubert R (2010) Rationality on the rise: why relative risk aversion increases with the stake-size. J Risk Uncertain 40:147–180

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fetchenhauer D, Dunning D (2009) Do people trust too much or too little? J Econ Psychol 30:263–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forsythe R, Horowitz JL, Savin NE, Sefton M (1994) Fairness in simple bargaining games. Games Econ Behav 6:347–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fouraker L, Siegel S (1963) Bargaining and group decision making. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fu T-T, Kong W-H, Yang CC (2007) Monetary stakes and socioeconomic characteristics in ultimatum games: an experiment with nation-wide representative subjects. Working paper

  • Gehrig T, Güth W, Levati V, Levínskı R, Ockenfels A, Uske T, Weiland T (2007) Buying a pig in a poke: an experimental study of unconditional veto power. J Econ Psychol 28:692–703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gillis MT, Hettler PL (2007) Hypothetical and real incentives in the ultimatum game and Andreoni’s public goods game: an experimental study. Eastern Econ J 33:491–510

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser E, Laibson D, Scheinkman JA, Soutter CL (2000) Measuring trust. Q J Econ 115:811–846

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldreich D, Pomorski L (2011) Initiating bargaining. Rev Econ Stud 78:1299–1328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griffin J, Nickerson D, Wozniak A (2012) Racial differences in inequality aversion: evidence from real world respondents in the ultimatum game. J Econ Behav Organ 84:600–617

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guala F (2005) The methodology of experimental economics. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Güth W (2012) Bargaining and negotiations: what should experimentalists explore more thoroughly? In: Croson RT, Bolton GE (eds) Oxford handbook of economic conflict resolution, chap 17. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 241–253

    Google Scholar 

  • Güth W, Tietz R (1987) Ultimatum bargaining for a shrinking cake: an experimental analysis. In: Tietz R, Albers W, Selten R (eds) Bounded rational behaviour in experimental games and markets. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Güth W, Kirchkamp O (2012) Will you accept without knowing what? The Yes–No game in the newspaper and in the lab. Exp Econ 15:656–666

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güth W, Schmittberger R, Schwarze B (1982) An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. J Econ Behav Organ 3:367–388

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güth W, Schmidt C, Sutter M (2007) Bargaining outside the lab—a newspaper experiment of a three-person ultimatum game. Econ J 117:449–469

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich J, Boyd R, Bowles S, Camerer C, Fehr E, Gintis H, McElreath R (2001) In search of homo economicus: behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. Am Econ Rev 91:73–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herrmann B, Thöni C, Gächter S (2008) Antisocial punishment across societies. Science 319:1362–1367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hertwig R, Ortmann A (2001) Experimental practices in economics: a methodological challenge for psychologists? Behav Brain Sci 24:383–451

    Google Scholar 

  • Ho T-H, Weigelt K (2005) Trust building among strangers. Manag Sci 51:519–530

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman E, McKabe K, Schachat K, Smith V (1994) Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining. Games Econ Behav 7:346–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman E, McKabe K, Smith V (1996) On expectations and the monetary stakes in ultimatum games. Int J Game Theory 25:289–301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holm HJ, Nystedt P (2008) Trust in surveys and games—a methodological contribution on the influence of money and location. J Econ Psychol 29:522–542

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holt CA, Laury SK (2002) Risk aversion and incentive effects. Am Econ Rev 92:1644–1655

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansson-Stenman O, Mahmud M, Martinsson P (2005) Does stake size matter in trust games. Econ Lett 88:365–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansson-Stenman O, Mahmud M, Martinsson P (2013) Trust, trust games and stated trust: evidence from rural Bangladesh. J Econ Behav Organ 95:286–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson ND, Mislin AA (2011) Trust games: a meta-analysis. J Econ Psychol 32:865–889

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kachelmeier SJ, Shehata M (1992) Examining risk preferences under high monetary incentives: experimental evidence from People’s Republic of China. Am Econ Rev 82:1120–1141

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47:263–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kang MJ, Rangel A, Camus M, Camerer C (2011) Hypothetical and real choice differentially activate common valuation areas. J Neurosci 31:461–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karagözoğlu E (2012) Bargaining games with joint production. In: Croson RT, Bolton GE (eds) Oxford handbook of economic conflict resolution, chap 24. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 359–372

    Google Scholar 

  • Karagözoğlu E, Riedl A (2015) Performance information, production uncertainty, and subjective entitlements in bargaining. Manag Sci 61:2611–2626

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kocher MG, Martinsson P, Visser M (2008) Does stake-size matter for cooperation and punishment? Econ Lett 99:508–511

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konow J (2005) Blind spots: the effects of information and stakes on fairness bias and dispersion. Soc Justice Res 18:349–390

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kühberger A (2001) Why use real and hypothetical payoffs? Behav Brain Sci 24:419–420

    Google Scholar 

  • Leibbrandt A, Maitra P, Neelim A (2015) On the redistribution of wealth in a developing country: experimental evidence on stake and framing effects. J Econ Behav Organ 118:360–371

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt SD, List JA (2007) What do laboratory experiments measuring social preferences reveal about the real world? J Econ Perspect 21:153–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List JA (2007) On the interpretation of giving in dictator games. J Polit Econ 115:482–493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List JA, Cherry TL (2000) Learning to accept in ultimatum Games: evidence from an experimental design that generates low offers. Exp Econ 3:11–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List JA, Cherry TL (2008) Examining the role of fairness in high stakes allocation decisions. J Econ Behav Organ 65:1–8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz H (1952) The utility of wealth. J Polit Econ 60:151–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCrae RR, Costa PT, Martin TA (2005) The NEO-PI-3: a more readable revised NEO personality inventory. J Personal Assess 84:261–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGuire JT, Botvinick MM (2010) Prefrontal cortex, cognitive control, and the registration of decision costs. Proc Natl Acad Sci 107:7922–7926

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menezes CF, Hanson DL (1970) On the theory of risk aversion. Int Econ Rev 11:481–487

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munier B, Zaharia C (2003) High stakes and acceptance behavior in ultimatum bargaining. Theor Decis 53:187–207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murayama K, Matsumoto M, Izuma K, Matsumoto K (2010) Neural basis of the undermining effect of monetary reward on intrinsic motivation. Proc Natl Acad Sci 107:20911–20916

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson R (1979) Incentive compatibility and the bargaining problem. Econometrica 47:61–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson R (1984) Two-person bargaining problems with incomplete information. Econometrica 52:461–488

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naef M, Schupp J (2009) Measuring trust: experiments and surveys in contrast and combination. IZA discussion paper series #4087

  • Nagel R, Mitzkewitz M (1993) Experimental results on ultimatum games with incomplete information. Int J Game Theory 22:171–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neelin J, Sonnenschein H, Spiegel M (1988) A further test of noncooperative bargaining theory. Am Econ Rev 78:824–836

    Google Scholar 

  • Oberholzer-Gee F, Waldfogel J, White MW (2010) Friend or foe? Cooperation and learning in high-stakes games. Rev Econ Stat 92:179–187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oosterbeek H, Sloof R, van de Kuilen G (2004) Cultural differences in ultimatum game experiments: evidence from a meta-analysis. Exp Econ 7:171–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parco JE, Rapoport A, Stein WE (2002) Effects of financial incentives on the breakdown of mutual trust. Psychol Sci 13:292–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Post T, van den Assem M, Baltussen G, Thaler R (2008) Deal or no deal? Decision making under risk in a large-payoff game show. Am Econ Rev 98:38–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raihani NJ, Mace R, Lamba S (2013) The effect of $1, $5, and $10 stakes in an online dictator game. Plos ONE 8:e73131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rabin M (1993) Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. Am Econ Rev 83:1281–1302

    Google Scholar 

  • Read D (2005) Monetary incentives, what are they good for? J Econ Methodol 12:265–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roth AE, Prasnikar V, Okuno-Fujivara M, Zamir S (1991) Bargaining and market behavior in Jerusalem, Ljubljana, Pittsburgh, and Tokyo: an experimental study. Am Econ Rev 81:1068–1095

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubin Z, Peplau LA (1975) Who believes in a just world? J Soc Issues 31:65–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein A (1982) Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model. Econometrica 50:97–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitt M (1996) Individual differences in sensitivity to befallen injustice. Person Individ Differ 21:3–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sefton M (1992) Incentives in simple bargaining games. J Econ Psychol 13:263–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slonim R, Roth AE (1998) Learning in high stakes ultimatum games: an experiment in the Slovak Republic. Econometrica 66:569–596

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith V, Walker JM (1993) Monetary rewards and decision costs in experimental economics. Econ Inq 31:245–261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sonnegård J (1996) Determination of first movers in sequential bargaining games: an experimental study. J Econ Psychol 17:359–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ståhl S (1972) Bargaining theory. Economic Research Institute, Stockholm School of Economics, Stockholm

    Google Scholar 

  • Straub PG, Murnighan JK (1995) An experimental investigation of ultimatum games: information, fairness, expectations, and lowest acceptable offers. J Econ Behav Organ 27:345–364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sutter M, Kocher MG (2007) Trust and trustworthiness across different age groups. Games Econ Behav 59:364–382

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Telser KG (1993) The ultimatum game: a comment. Mimeo, University of Chicago

  • Thaler RH (1988) Anomalies: the ultimatum game. J Econ Perspect 2:195–209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tompkinson P, Bethwaite J (1995) The ultimatum game: raising the stakes. J Econ Behav Organ 27:439–451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van den Assem MJ, van Dolder D, Thaler R (2012) Split or steal? Cooperative behavior when the stakes are large. Manag Sci 58:2–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vieider FM (2012) Moderate stake variations for risk and uncertainty, gains and losses: methodological implications for comparative studies. Econ Lett 117:718–721

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou Y, Wang Y, Rao L-L, Yang L-Q, Li S (2014) Money talks: neural substrate of modulation of fairness by monetary incentives. Front Behav Neurosci 8:1–11

    Google Scholar 

  • Zwick R, Chen X-P (1999) What price fairness? A bargaining study. Manag Sci 45:804–823

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Emin Karagözoglu thanks The Scientific and Technological Research Council of Turkey (TÜBITAK) for the research grant #111K499. The authors would like to thank two anonymous reviewers and an editor for their comments that improved the paper. The authors would also like to thank Gary Bolton and Urs Fischbacher for their comments and Mirza Trokic for proof-reading the manuscript.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Emin Karagözoğlu.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 5 and 6.

Table 5 Studies reporting stake-size effects
Table 6 Studies reporting no stake-size effects

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Karagözoğlu, E., Urhan, Ü.B. The Effect of Stake Size in Experimental Bargaining and Distribution Games: A Survey. Group Decis Negot 26, 285–325 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10726-016-9490-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10726-016-9490-x

Keywords

Navigation