Skip to main content
Log in

Multinational Lending Retrenchment after the Global Financial Crisis: The Impact of Policy Interventions

  • Published:
Journal of Financial Services Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Did policy interventions contribute to the gradual segmentation of lending markets starting with the 2007 - 2008 global financial crisis? We investigate this question in an international Cournot duopoly model with equity constraints. Two symmetric multinational banks compete for corporate lending via local affiliates in two separate national lending markets. Their credit risk in each market is determined by their choice of monitoring effort, which is more costly for foreign lending. Under a binding equity constraint, our model predicts the following: Shocks to bank equity, regulatory standards and monetary policy, such as occurred during and after the crisis, increase the lending home bias of multinational banks. We interpret this retrenchment as a flight to informationally closer or better understood lending. Our results under a non-binding equity constraint are largely identical.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. During the period of 1995–2009, the share of foreign owned banks increased by 70% globally (Claessens and Van Horen , 2014). Lending by foreign owned banks has been found to widen and deepen local lending markets as well as provide additional channels of financing in case of an interbank market or local economic shock (see e.g. Allen et al. (2017), Schnabl (2012)).

  2. Works such as De Haas and Van Lelyveld (2014), Cetorelli and Goldberg (2012) or Frey and Kerl (2015) document the post-crisis retrenchment of multinational lending.

  3. Agarwal and Hauswald (2010) show that a greater geographical distance to a loan applicant increases the likelihood of the loan being rejected. Further, the quality of banks’ proprietary information on their existing borrowers decreases with the bank-borrower distance.

  4. See Moody’s Analytics (2018) for an overview of current, advanced economy loan monitoring practices.

  5. As shown by Karceski et al. (2005) and Sapienza (2002), the greater information cost of foreign or geographically distant banks persists even after an acquisition of or merger with a local bank. This can be attributed to a greater ‘hierarchial distance’ between borrower and loan officer within a larger banking organization (Stein , 2002).

  6. Sette and Gobbi (2015) and others show a similar post-crisis retrenchment in lending to informationally distant borrowers within countries.

  7. The existence of such a credit interest rate channel is evidenced by the sharp and persistent increase in banks’ corporate lending margins following the default of Lehman Brothers, see Fig. 2.

  8. Recent contributions to the regulatory literature focus for instance on the cyclicality of the Basel regulations (Chami and Cosimano , 2010; Repullo and Suarez , 2012; Mankart et al. , 2019). Their dynamic modeling frameworks allow for positive equity buffers to emerge endogenously.

  9. Empirical findings corroborate this result in that the lending supply of poorly capitalized banks reacts more severely to negative equity or regulatory shocks (see e.g. Bonaccorsi di Patti and Sette (2012), Fraisse et al. (2020)).

  10. Head and Spencer (2017) give an overview of recent applications of oligopolistic models of international trade.

  11. In our model, we abstract from entry costs in foreign markets as in Faia et al. (2021). This describes an integrated regional banking sector where affiliate subsidiaries are already established and entry costs are sunk.

  12. One rationale for this relationship is that increased bank monitoring reduces the entrepreneurs’ moral hazard problem, inducing him to exert a greater managerial effort (Holmstrom and Tirole , 1997).

  13. In the EU, most private firms report under the Generally Accepted Accounting Principles (GAAP) of their home country. Accordingly, foreign bank affiliates receive financial statements and documentation from their local corporate borrowers in national GAAP. National GAAP rules can be significantly different across European countries (Nobes , 2011).

  14. See Barth et al. (2013) for a recent global overview of deposit insurance schemes.

  15. Due to their inherent opacity, small and young businesses have limited access to capital markets and rely largely on local bank credit for external financing (see Berger and Udell (1998) for a summary of the literature). As shown by Beck et al. (2018), even larger and mature firms are twice as likely to receive credit from domestic than foreign banks.

  16. Equivalently, the greater cost of equity can be interpreted as the significant underpricing required in issuing new equity. Both interpretations capture the idea that equity capital is a particularly costly form of financing (see Dell’Ariccia and Marquez (2006) or Hellmann et al. (2000) for similar assumptions).

  17. Perfect correlation of credit risks is a common assumption in the regulation literature, see e.g. Dell’Ariccia and Marquez (2006) or Boyd and De Nicolo (2005).

  18. For a binding equity constraint, these expressions hold with equality.

  19. In our model, the local credit interest rates depend on the distribution of firms’ gross rather than expected revenue from investment (see Eq. 1). In consequence, the banks’ choice of local monitoring effort and thus credit risk is independent of the local credit volume and their share therein.

  20. A binding constraint on banks’ overall lending volume can potentially give rise to an additional equilibrium in autarky \(\gamma _i=\gamma _j=1\). We find that our model does not support this. Banks’ choice of a greater monitoring effort in the domestic market leads to a greater marginal cost of domestic lending. The cost savings of the first unit of foreign lending subsequently overcompensate a possibly smaller unit revenue, eliminating the possibility of an autarky solution.

  21. In the United States, banks experienced losses as early as 2007, most prominently from direct exposure to mortgage lending. European banks on the other hand experienced losses mostly through the exposure of their securities portfolios to US mortgage backed securities and stocks of US financial intermediaries. Investors priced this devaluation of investments into the banks’ market valuation starting with the Lehman Brothers default.

  22. This is in line with the empirical finding of Albertazzi and Marchetti (2010) of a general ‘flight to quality’ of banks during the crisis.

  23. The negative relationship of equity requirements and credit risk is in opposition to the result of Hakenes and Schnabel (2011). This is due to our modeling of borrower monitoring, which eliminates the entrepreneurs’ choice of project risk.

  24. Similarly, Cappelletti et al. (2019) find that banks respond to increases in equity requirements by shifting their lending to less risky counterparties within the corporate sector.

  25. Unconventional expansionary monetary policy can be modeled as the reduction of a "shadow policy rate" as introduced by Lombardi et al. (2018).

  26. Buch and Dages (2018) document an increase in the cost of equity for banks of all advanced economies during the crisis. This increase was most persistent for European banks, whose cost of equity returned to pre-crisis levels only in 2014.

  27. While banks reduce their lending volume in both markets in response to an increase in \(\rho \), this reduction is less pronounced in the domestic market, leading to an increase in the lending home bias. Indeed, domestic lending \(L_d^{\dagger }\) only decreases only under the assumption of a moderate information cost differential \(b_f-b_d<2b_d\) while the decline of the foreign lending volume \(L_f^{\dagger }\) is unambiguous.

  28. In the following, we make use of the inequality \(\sqrt{a+b}<\sqrt{a}+\sqrt{b}\).

References

  • Acharya VV (2003) Is the international convergence of capital adequacy regulation desirable? J Financ 58(6):2745–2782

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agarwal S, Hauswald R (2010) Distance and private information in lending. Rev Financ Stud 23(7):2757–2788

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aiyar S (2012) From financial crisis to great recession: The role of globalized banks. Am Econ Rev 102(3):225–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albertazzi U, Bottero M (2014) Foreign bank lending: Evidence from the global financial crisis. J Int Econ 92:S22–S35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albertazzi U, Marchetti D (2010) Credit supply, flight to quality and evergreening: An analysis of bank-firm relationships after Lehman. Bank of Italy Temi di Discussione No. 756

  • Allen F, Jackowicz K, Kowalewski O, Kozłowski Ł (2017) Bank lending, crises, and changing ownership structure in Central and Eastern European countries. J Corp Finance 42:494–515

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balsmeier B, Vanhaverbeke S (2018) International financial reporting standards and private firms’ access to bank loans. Eur Account Rev 27(1):75–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bank for International Settlements (2010) Basel III: A global regulatory framework for more resilient banks and banking systems. BCBS Communication No.189

  • Baron M, Verner E, Xiong W (2021) Banking crises without panics. Q J Econ 136(1):51–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barth JR, Phumiwasana T, Lee C (2013) Deposit insurance schemes. In: Lee AC (ed) Lee CF. Encyclopedia of Finance, Springer, pp 207–212

    Google Scholar 

  • Baskaya YS, Di Giovanni J, Kalemli-Özcan Ş, Peydró JL, Ulu MF (2017) Capital flows and the international credit channel. J Int Econ 108:15–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck T, Ioannidou V, Schäfer L (2018) Foreigners vs. natives: Bank lending technologies and loan pricing. Manage Sci 64(8): 3792–3820

  • Berger AN, Klapper LF, Udell GF (2001) The ability of banks to lend to informationally opaque small businesses. J Bank Financ 25(12):2127–2167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger AN, Udell GF (1998) The economics of small business finance: The roles of private equity and debt markets in the financial growth cycle. J Bank Financ 22(6–8):613–673

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonaccorsi di Patti E, Sette E (2012) Bank balance sheets and the transmission of financial shocks to borrowers: Evidence from the 2007-2008 crisis. Bank of Italy Temi di Discussione No. 848. Rome

  • Boyd JH, De Nicolo G (2005) The theory of bank risk taking and competition revisited. J Finance 60(3):1329–1343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander J, Krugman P (1983) A ‘reciprocal dumping’ model of international trade. J Int Econ 15(3–4):313–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bremus FM (2015) Cross-border banking, bank market structures and market power: Theory and cross-country evidence. J Bank Financ 50:242–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brüggemann B, Kleinert J, Prieto E (2012) The ideal loan and the patterns of cross-border bank lending. Graz Economic Papers No.2012-03

  • Buch C, Dages B (2018) Structural changes in banking after the crisis. BIS CGFS Paper No. 60

  • Buch CM, Neugebauer K, Schröder C (2014) Changing forces of gravity: How the crisis affected international banking. ZEW Discussion Papers No.14(6)

  • Cappelletti G, Ponte Marques A, Varraso P, Budrys Ž, Peeters J (2019) Impact of higher capital buffers on banks’ lending and risk-taking: Evidence from the euro area experiments. ECB Working Paper Series No. 2292

  • Cetorelli N, Goldberg LS (2012) Liquidity management of US global banks: Internal capital markets in the great recession. J Int Econ 88(2):299–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chami R, Cosimano TF (2010) Monetary policy with a touch of Basel. J Econ Bus 62(3):161–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Claessens S, Van Horen N (2014) Foreign banks: Trends and impact. J Money Credit Bank 46(1):295–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corbae D, D’Erasmo P (2015) Foreign competition and banking industry dynamics: An application to Mexico. IMF Econ Rev 63(4):830–867

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Blas B, Russ KN (2013) All banks great, small, and global: Loan pricing and foreign competition. Int Rev Econ Finance 26:4–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Haas R, Van Lelyveld I (2014) Multinational banks and the global financial crisis: Weathering the perfect storm? J Money Credit Bank 46(1):333–364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dell’Ariccia G, Marquez R (2006) Competition among regulators and credit market integration. J Financ Econ 79(2):401–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demirguc-Kunt A, Detragiache E, Merrouche O (2013) Bank capital: Lessons from the financial crisis. J Money Credit Bank 45(6):1147–1164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emter L, Schmitz M, Tirpák M (2019) Cross-border banking in the EU since the crisis: What is driving the great retrenchment? Rev World Econ 155(2):287–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank (2010) Financial stability review: June 2010

  • European Central Bank (2013) Financial stability review: May 2013

  • European Central Bank (2020) Financial stability review: May 2020

  • European Parliament and Council (2013). Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR). Regulation No. 575/2013

  • Faia E, Laffitte S, Mayer M, Ottaviano G (2021) Global banking: Endogenous competition and risk taking. Eur Econ Rev 133:103661

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fraisse H, Lé M, Thesmar D (2020) The real effects of bank capital requirements. Manage Sci 66(1):5–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freixas X, Rochet JC (2008) Microeconomics of banking, 2nd edn. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey R, Kerl C (2015) Multinational banks in the crisis: Foreign affiliate lending as a mirror of funding pressure and competition on the internal capital market. J Bank Financ 50:52–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gambacorta L, Shin HS (2018) Why bank capital matters for monetary policy. J Financ Intermediation 35:17–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hakenes H, Schnabel I (2011) Capital regulation, bank competition, and financial stability. Econ Lett 113(3):256–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hartmann P, Smets F (2018) The first twenty years of the European Central Bank: Monetary policy. ECB Working Paper Series No. 2219

  • Haufler A, Maier U (2019) Regulatory competition in capital standards: A ‘race to the top’ result. J Bank Financ 106:180–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haufler A, Wooton I (2021) Multinational banks in regulated markets: Is financial integration desirable? Can J Econ/Revue canadienne d’économique 54(4):1811–1841

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hauswald R, Marquez R (2006) Competition and strategic information acquisition in credit markets. Rev Financ Stud 19(3)

  • Head K, Spencer BJ (2017) Oligopoly in international trade: Rise, fall and resurgence. Can J Econ 50(5):1414–1444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hellmann TF, Murdock KC, Stiglitz JE (2000) Liberalization, moral hazard in banking, and prudential regulation: Are capital requirements enough? Am Econ Rev 90(1):147–165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom B, Tirole J (1997) Financial intermediation, loanable funds, and the real sector. Q J Econ 112(3):663–691

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ivashina V, Scharfstein D (2010) Bank lending during the financial crisis of 2008. J Financ Econ 97(3):319–338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karceski J, Ongena S, Smith DC (2005) The impact of bank consolidation on commercial borrower welfare. J Finance 60(4):2043–2082

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kopecky KJ, VanHoose D (2004) A model of the monetary sector with and without binding capital requirements. J Bank Financ 28(3):633–646

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lombardi MJ, Zhu F et al (2018) A shadow policy rate to calibrate us monetary policy at the zero lower bound. Int J Cent Bank 14(5):305–346

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankart J, Michaelides A, Pagratis S (2019) Bank capital buffers in a dynamic model. Financ Manage 1–30

  • Moody’s Analytics (2018) Redefining loan monitoring and early warning signal detection through an integrated solution. https://www.moodysanalytics.com/articles/2018/redefining-loan-monitoring. Accessed 15 May 2023

  • Morgan PJ (2020) A framework for regional banking regulation in asean. Asian Econ Pap 19(3):111–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niepmann F (2015) Banking across borders. J Int Econ 96:244–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nobes C (2011) Ifrs practices and the persistence of accounting system classification. Abacus 47(3):267–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Remolona EM, Shim I (2015) The rise of regional banking in asia and the pacific. BIS Quarterly Review September

  • Repullo R (2004) Capital requirements, market power, and risk-taking in banking. J Financ Intermediation 13(2):156–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Repullo R, Suarez J (2012) The procyclical effects of bank capital regulation. Rev Financ Stud 26(2):452–490

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sapienza P (2002) The effects of banking mergers on loan contracts. J Finance 57(1):329–367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schnabl P (2012) The international transmission of bank liquidity shocks: Evidence from an emerging market. J Finance 67(3):897–932

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sette E, Gobbi G (2015) Relationship lending during a financial crisis. J Eur Econ Assoc 13(3):453–481

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stein JC (2002) Information production and capital allocation: Decentralized versus hierarchical firms. J Finance 57(5):1891–1921

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van den Heuvel S (2002) Does bank capital matter for monetary transmission? Econ Policy Review 8(1)

  • Walter JR (2019) US bank capital regulation: History and changes since the financial crisis. Econ Q 1Q:1–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Funding

We gratefully acknowledge financial support by the German Research Foundation (DFG) via Grant No. HA 3195/9-1.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Miriam Goetz.

Ethics declarations

Conflicts of interests

There are no other conflicts of interest to disclose.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

This paper has been presented at seminars and conferences in Marseille, Leipzig and Munich. I thank Franziska Bremus, Nicolas Coeurdacier, Gianni De Nicolo, Andreas Haufler, Bernhard Kassner, Jochen Mankart, Monika Schnitzer, Steven Ongena and the anonymous referee for many helpful comments.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A   Derivation of equilibrium monitoring efforts and lending volumes (unconstrained case)

We partially differentiate bank i’s expected profit Eq. 4 with respect to the monitoring efforts and lending volumes, yielding the first order conditions

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _i}{\partial s_{di}}&=L_{di} \left( \left[ \bar{R}-(L_{di}+L_{fj}) \right] - \delta (1-k)-b_ds_{di} \right) =0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _i}{\partial s_{fi}}&=L_{fi} \left( \left[ \bar{R}-(L_{fi}+L_{dj}) \right] - \delta (1-k)-b_ds_{fi} \right) =0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _i}{\partial L_{di}}&=s_{di} \left( \left[ \bar{R}-(L_{fj}+2L_{di}) \right] - (\delta +\rho )k - \delta (1-k)-0.5b_ds_{di}^2 \right) =0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _i}{\partial L_{fi}}&=s_{fi} \left( \left[ \bar{R}-(L_{dj}+2L_{fi}) \right] - (\delta +\rho )k - \delta (1-k)-0.5b_ds_{fi}^2 \right) =0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)

Solving the system of Eqs. A.1A.4 under bank symmetry, we find the equilibrium monitoring efforts and lending volumes

$$\begin{aligned} s_{d}^{\dagger }&=\frac{\bar{R}-\delta (1-k)+\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k}}{4b_d} \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)
$$\begin{aligned} s_{f}^{\dagger }&=\frac{\bar{R}-\delta (1-k)+\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k}}{4b_f} \end{aligned}$$
(A.6)
$$\begin{aligned} L_{d}^{\dagger }&=\frac{(5b_d+b_f)\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] -(3b_d-b_f)\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k}}{8(b_d+b_f)} \end{aligned}$$
(A.7)
$$\begin{aligned} L_{f}^{\dagger }&=\frac{(5b_f+b_d)\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] -(3b_f-b_d)\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k}}{8(b_d+b_f)}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.8)

These results include the assumption that the monitoring efforts must take non-negative values in optimum.

1.2 B   Comparative statics of the credit supply Eqs. 2830

The full equations of the comparative statics Eqs. 2830 of the local credit supply \(L^S\) with regards to \(\rho \), \(\delta \) and k are given by

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial L^S}{\partial \rho }\!&=\!-\frac{k(b_d+b_f)}{\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k}}<0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.9)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial L^S}{\partial k} \!&=\! \frac{\delta \left( 3\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}\!-\!\delta (1\!-\!k)\right] ^2\!+\!8(b_d\!+\!b_f)(\delta \!+\!\rho )k}\!-\!\left[ \bar{R}\!-\!\delta (1\!-\!k)\right] \right) \!-\!4(b_d\!+\!b_f)(\delta \!+\!\rho )}{4\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}\!-\!\delta (1\!-\!k)\right] ^2\!+\!8(b_d\!+\!b_f)(\delta \!+\!\rho )k}} \gtreqless 0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.10)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial L^S}{\partial \delta }\!&=\! \frac{(1\!-\!k)\left( \left[ \bar{R}\!-\!\delta (1\!-\!k)\right] \!-\!3\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}\!-\!\delta (1\!-\!k)\right] ^2\!+\!8(b_d\!+\!b_f)(\delta \!+\!\rho )k}\right) \!-\!4k(b_d\!+\!b_f)}{4\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}\!-\!\delta (1\!-\!k)\right] ^2\!+\!8(b_d\!+\!b_f)(\delta \!+\!\rho )k}}\!<\!0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.11)

While the derivative with regards to \(\rho \) is unambiguously negative we must prove that the derivative by \(\delta \) indeed takes a negative valueFootnote 28. The derivative by k cannot by signed in general. To prove the negative sign of Eq. A.11, we replace the square root in the numerator with square roots of the individual summands yielding the following expression

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{-(1-k)\left( 2\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] +3\sqrt{8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k}\right) -4k(b_d+b_f)}{4\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k}}<0 . \end{aligned}$$
(A.12)

Inequality Eq. A.12 is unambiguously negative. Thereby, also the derivative Eq. A.11 must be negative as the sum of square roots is greater than the square root of the summands.

1.3 C   Comparative statics of the monitoring and lending decision Eqs. 3133 and Eqs. 3436

We present the full equations of the comparative statics Eqs. 3133 of the domestic affiliates’ monitoring effort \(s_{d}^{\dagger }\)

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial s_{d}^{\dagger }}{\partial \rho }&= \frac{1}{b_d}\left( -\frac{\partial L^S}{\partial \rho } \right) \nonumber \\&=\frac{(b_d+b_f)k}{b_d\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k}}>0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.13)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial s_{d}^{\dagger }}{\partial k}&= \frac{1}{b_d}\left( -\frac{\partial L^S}{\partial k}+\delta \right) \nonumber \\&=\frac{1}{4b_d}\left( \frac{\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] \delta +4(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )}{\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k}}+\delta \right) >0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.14)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial s_{d}^{\dagger }}{\partial \delta }&= \frac{1}{b_d}\left( -\frac{\partial L^S}{\partial \delta }-(1-k) \right) \nonumber \\&=\frac{1}{4b_d}\left( \frac{4(b_d+b_f)k-(1-k)\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] }{\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k}}-(1-k)\right) \gtreqless 0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.15)

The derivatives of the foreign affiliates’ monitoring effort \(s_{f}^{\dagger }\) are defined equivalently. The full equations of the comparative statics Eqs. 3436 of the share of domestic lending are given by

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \gamma ^{\dagger }}{\partial \rho }&=\frac{(b_f-b_d)\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] }{2(b_d+b_f)(L^S)^2}\left( -\frac{\partial L^S}{\partial \rho } \right) \nonumber \\&=\frac{(b_f-b_d)\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] k^2\left( \left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k\right) ^{-\frac{1}{2}}}{\left( 3\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] -\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k}\right) ^2}>0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.16)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \gamma ^{\dagger }}{\partial k}&=\frac{(b_f-b_d)}{2(b_d+b_f)(L^S)^2}\left( -\frac{\partial L^S}{\partial k}\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] +\delta L^S \right) \nonumber \\&=\frac{8(b_f-b_d)(\delta +\rho )\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1+k)\right] \left( \left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k\right) ^{-\frac{1}{2}}}{\left( 3\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] -\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k}\right) ^2}>0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.17)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \gamma ^{\dagger }}{\partial \delta }&=\frac{(b_f-b_d)}{2(b_d+b_f)(L^S)^2}\left( -\frac{\partial L^S}{\partial \delta }\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] -(1-k)L^S \right) \nonumber \\&=\frac{8(b_f-b_d)k\left[ \bar{R}+(1-k)(\delta +2\rho )\right] \left( \left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k\right) ^{-\frac{1}{2}}}{\left( 3\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] -\sqrt{\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k}\right) ^2}>0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.18)

with the latter result holding under the condition \(\bar{R}>\delta (1+k)\).

1.4 D   Cross derivative of the monitoring effort

We present the cross derivative of the monitoring effort with regards to \(\delta \) and k for the example of domestic monitoring

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial ^2 s_{d}^{\dagger }}{\partial \delta \partial k} \nonumber \\&=\frac{1}{4b_d}\left( 1+\frac{\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^3+4(b_d+b_f)\left( \left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+4(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k\right) }{\root 3 \of {\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k}} \right. \nonumber \\&\qquad \qquad \qquad +\left. \frac{4(b_d+b_f)\left( \left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] \left[ \delta (1-k)+\rho \right] +\left[ \bar{R}-3\delta (1-k)\right] k(\delta +\rho )\right) }{\root 3 \of {\left[ \bar{R}-\delta (1-k)\right] ^2+8(b_d+b_f)(\delta +\rho )k}}\right) >0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.19)

The cross derivative of foreign monitoring is defined equivalently.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Goetz, M. Multinational Lending Retrenchment after the Global Financial Crisis: The Impact of Policy Interventions. J Financ Serv Res (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-023-00414-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-023-00414-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation