Skip to main content
Log in

Robust Political Economy and the Lender of Last Resort

  • Published:
Journal of Financial Services Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Of the leading versions of lender of last resort policy, which is to be preferred in a world of realistic incentive and information imperfections? The three most prominent versions of lender of last resort policy are: the Classical system of central bank lending on good collateral at a penalty rate, the Richmond Federal Reserve system of open market operations to prevent liquidity drains, and the New York Federal Reserve system of commitment to taking any and all action necessary to prevent the spread of financial contagion. We compare these policies to the mechanisms that developed in free banking systems. Free banking systems had no formal lender of last resort, but instead developed institutions that lessened the possibility of systemic panic in the first place. We find that free banking weakly dominates the Classical system. Free banking also outperforms the New York Fed and Richmond Fed systems on the incentive margin, but is weaker on the information margin. In addition, the paper discusses how the New York Fed doctrine is the only stable activist policy, since the limited responses necessitated by the Classical and Richmond Fed policies are not credible.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See for example Ahrend (2010); Beckworth (2012); Benes and Kumhof (2012); Boettke and Smith (2013a, b, c); Diamond and Rajan (2009); Dowd and Hutchinson (2010); Espinosa (2012); Hetzel (2012); Horwitz and Luther (2010); Jarocinski and Smets (2008); Leamer (2007); Mehrling (2010); O’Driscoll (2012); Kling (2010); Kotlikoff (2010); Roberts (2010); Selgin et al. (2012); Sumner (2011, 2012); Taylor (2007, 2009); White (2008, 2009, 2012); Woodford (2012); Woolsey (2012).

  2. This is not the only explanation of the financial crisis put forth. For a sample of opinions on the causes of the financial crisis see Critical Review Vol. 21, No. 2–3.

  3. The former explanation draws on the Austrian theory of the trade cycle (Garrison 2000; Horwitz 2000) whereas draws on the Monetarist story of Friedman and Schwartz (1963). These theories are not irreconcilable, and may in fact be complementary (Boettke and Luther 2009).

  4. Moral hazard explanations also feature prominently in these works. See especially Espinosa (2012), Roberts (2010), and White (2012a, b).

  5. The lender of last resort in these models is assumed to be an actor of a different kind from the profit-seeking bankers.

  6. An approach similar to the one advocated here can be found in Calomiris (2013). While concerned with banking panics rather than last-resort lending per se, Calomiris considers similar historical cases and reaches similar conclusions to those to be discussed later in the paper.

  7. While the range of human behavior is perhaps better captured by a continuum rather than the discrete categories presented above, these categories highlight the essential feature of robust political economy: comparing best-case to worst-case scenarios. Robust political economy is fundamentally a search for those institutions that function well even in these worst-case scenarios. As Boettke and Leeson (2004: 100) recognize, “Many systems can stand up tothe test of the easy case, but very few remain standing when confronted with the hard case.”

  8. In a slightly different vein, Anna Schwartz (1987) examined the efficacy of the lender of last resort under different economic and regulatory conditions. This can be considered a proto-exercise in robust political economy analysis of monetary institutions.

  9. Stability is important for robustness because ambiguity with respect to the lender of last resort arrangement the monetary authority uses is costly. In particular, market actors will be forced to invest greater resources in understanding the “true” last-resort lending rule, will err in decisions predicated on a given last-resort lending rule when another is effect, or some combination of both. Recent research (e.g. Baker et al. 2013) has highlighted how uncertainty can negatively impact economic outcomes; uncertainty with respect to the underlying monetary rule during times of financial turbulence raises similar problems, and ought be avoided wherever possible.

  10. More specifically, this means preventing the spread of contagion by ensuring the continued viability of illiquid, but still solvent, organizations.

  11. Of course, the different versions of last resort lending doctrine will propose different means by which the end of financial stability is best achieved.

  12. The following is a condensed summary of the process described by white (1999: chapter 1), which the interested reader should consult for a more in-depth discussion.

  13. Clearinghouses in the U.S. during the National Banking Era provided a unique way to ameliorate a crisis. Member banks of a single clearinghouse would suspend individual operation, suppress information concerning the solvency of individual banks, and issue certificates redeemable by the clearinghouse as a whole. This was an important source of emergency liquidity in a system constrained by regulations that prohibited branch banking and, due to collateral requirements, rendered the conversion of currency to deposits artificially inelastic (Smith 1990). This had the benefit of substituting the solvency of the system as a whole for the solvency of individual member banks during a panic. However, the uniqueness of the U.S. case makes it inappropriate for drawing general inferences, so it will not be treated in detail here. Interested readers should consult Gorton (1985, 2010), Gorton and Mullineaux (1987), and Timberlake (1984).

  14. Because the inside money-outside money distinction is intrinsic to the operation of all free banking systems, it is impractical to discuss any specific historical case in this subsection as is done in others. Readers interested in specific historical details should consult the free banking literature cited above.

  15. Evidence of this stability can be seen by comparing Canada’s laissez-faire approach with that of the U.S. during the National Banking Era. While in the U.S. there were little seasonal variations in note circulation and large fluctuations in interest rates come the harvest season, in Canada note circulation was around 20 % higher in the autumn relative to its own mid-winter seasonal lows and there were no noticeable seasonal interest rate fluctuations (Schuler 1992: 88; Selgin and White 1994b).

  16. In Upper Canada, the governor threatened to shut down banks that suspended payments. As a result banks suffered reserve drains and were forced to contract their loans more than banks in other provinces. The crisis in Upper Canada was said to be worse “than anywhere else in North America” (Schuler 1992: 83).

  17. This historical example suggests clearinghouses also had a way of dealing with problem posed by Diamond and Dybvig (1983). This suggests that under panic condition the suspension of payments, contrary to Diamond and Dybvig, was welfare-enhancing (Selgin 1993).

  18. Interestingly, Bagehot himself preferred free banking, what he called “the natural system—that which would have sprung up if Government had let banking alone” (Bagehot 1896[1873]), to central banking. He advocated his now-orthodox rules for last-resort lending because he believed the political constraints prevented a transition to the kind of banking system that existed in Scotland.

  19. The exception is the United States, which will be discussed further below.

  20. Goodfriend (2012) argues that the Bank of England’s adherence to Bagehot’s rules was due to the incentives provided by shareholder residual claimancy.

  21. The response of the Federal Reserve to the recent crisis will be explored more fully in the section covering the development of the New York Fed doctrine.

  22. It is also important to note that Bagehot’s recommendations do not specify any punishment mechanism for central bankers who overstep their bounds, and none of the historical cases where Bagehot’s rules were expected to be followed exhibited institutional fixes to rectify this oversight.

  23. Obviously, the penalty rate also must be below whatever rate prevails on the market during times of trouble, or else nobody would borrow using the discount window. This has not been a concern historically since during panics liquidity dries up, and banks can hardly afford to be making loans when they need liquidity to solidify their own short-term position. This makes loans between banks an exceedingly risky proposition even at high interest rates.

  24. Congdon (2009), along these lines, argues the Bank of England should be privatized so that it will lend more freely during times of turbulence.

  25. This is, of course, conditional upon market agents perceiving the limited response as credible, which we have seen is not the case. Nevertheless, exploring the information issues is important for the purposes of theoretical exposition.

  26. The interaction between incentive and information effects yields insight as to why banks load up on exotic, high-risk, high-return assets: The informational point is moot, since the lender of last resort will likely bail them out in the event of trouble anyway.

  27. Bordo (1986, 1990) provides evidence, in the form of the number of panics, that European central banks acting as Bagehotian lender of last resorts outperformed contemporaneous U.S. system. Also, Bordo (1990: 24) compares further the unique U.S. system to the Bank of England. In each of the crisis years common to both countries, the negative deviation from trend real output was greater in the U.S. than in Britain, and in three out of six cases from 1873 to 1932 the crisis evolved into a full panic in the U.S., whereas none of the crises evolved into panics in Britain.

  28. Again, this is due in part to the differing monetary-institutional environment between the modern Fed and European central banks in the late 19th century. Residual claimancy is especially important (Goodfriend 2012).

  29. This view is endorsed also by Friedman (1960), Kaufman (1991), and Schwartz (1992).

  30. Supply-side factors will be an important part of the New York Fed doctrine, which will be explored in the next subsection. Remember also the private clearinghouse response in the U.S. avoided potential supply-side problems by grouping under a single organization for the duration of the crisis; Bagehot’s rules avoided them by committing to intervene on a bank-by-bank basis.

  31. Why wouldn’t these supply-side factors also be a problem for adherents to Bagehot’s rules? After all, the end result—illiquid banks stay open at a cost, insolvent banks close—is the same. The answer lies in the monetary authority’s lack of a hard budget constraint. This frees the monetary authority from the worries that private agents must confront in times of trouble, such as evaluating the soundness of other agents’ underwriting standards (Flannery 1996).

  32. Remember Bernanke’s (1983) theoretical explanation for why a banking panic may occur even without a collapse in the monetary aggregates, although we have yet to observe such an event.

  33. Though rarely discussed, the legality of these actions is somewhat ambiguous. See Todd (2002) for a lawyer’s perspective on the legality of lender of last resort activities.

  34. The list of current primary dealers can be found at http://www.newyorkfed.org/markets/pridealers_current.html

  35. The Fed relies on repo contracts mainly as a way to conduct temporary monetary policy, e.g. meeting seasonal demands for currency during the holidays. See Selgin (2012: 303–308) for an overview and Tuckman (2010) for a detailed explanation in the context of the financial crisis.

  36. For example, JPMorgan Chase refused to process Lehman’s payments, freezing $17 billion of its assets on the eve of its collapse (Duffie 2009: 39).

  37. The PDCF was basically a “new and improved” discount window for primary dealers. By the time the Fed closed the PDCF in February 2010, total accumulated lending through the program was approximately $9 trillion; Merrill Lynch, Citigroup, and Morgan Stanly each received approximately $2 trillion (Sheridan 2011: 14).

  38. These are not the only steps the Fed took to prevent the spread of financial contagion; we limit the discussion to the mechanisms above because they are the most relevant to this paper. For a more detailed account see Hummel (2012) and Stewart (2009).

  39. While quantitative easing is usually considered a tool of monetary policy (albeit an unconventional one) rather than a lender of last resort activity, the Fed’s targeting of MBS points to systemic concerns as well.

  40. This process is described in detail by Gorton (2010). The only “anomaly” with the above story is the failure of Lehman Brothers, which was on the list of primary dealers in 2007. Hummel (2012: 189–190) suggest the limited initial response of the Fed can be explained by worries over inflation, since commodity (and especially oil) prices were rising in 2007–08, just as the crisis was unfolding.

  41. Although the passage of Dodd-Frank does seem to ratify TBTF in the U.S. See e.g. Wilmarth (2011).

  42. See Sumner (2011, 2012) for the theory behind a nominal income target, especially in the context of the financial crisis.

References

  • Ahrend R (2010) Monetary ease: a factor behind the financial crisis? Some evidence from OECD countries. Econ Open Access Open Assess J 4:1–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagehot, W (1896 [1873]) Lombard Street: a description of the money market. Homewood: Richard D. Irwin, Inc

  • Baker SR, Bloom N, Davis SJ (2013) Measuring economic policy uncertainty. Chicago Booth Research Paper No. 13–02

  • Beckworth D (2012) How the Fed’s mishandling of the productivity boom helped pave the way for the housing boom. In: Beckworth D (ed) Boom and bust banking: the causes and cures of the great recession. Independent Institute, Oakland

    Google Scholar 

  • Benes J, Kumhof M (2012) The Chicago plan revisited. IMF Working Paper WP/12/02

  • Bernanke BS (1981) Bankruptcy, liquidity, and recession. Am Econ Rev 71(2):155–159

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke BS (1983) Nonmonetary effects of the financial crisis in the propagation of the great depression. Am Econ Rev 73(3):257–276

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke PJ, Leeson PT (2004) Liberalism, socialism, and robust political economy. J Mark Morality 7(1):99–111

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke PJ, Luther WJ (2009) The ordinary economics of an extraordinary crisis. In: Kates S (ed) Macroeconomic theory and its failings: alternative perspectives on the global financial crisis. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke PJ, Smith DJ (2013a) A Century of accommodation: an anecdotal history of compromised federal reserve independence . GMU Working Paper in Economics No. 12–40. Available online at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2135232

  • Boettke PJ, Smith DJ (2013b) Federal reserve independence: a centennial review. GMU Working Paper in Economics No. 12–42. Available online at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2135233

  • Boettke PJ, Smith DJ (2013c) Monetary policy and the Nobel quest for robust political economy. Working Paper

  • Bordo MD (1986) Financial crises, banking crises, stock market crashes and the money supply: some international evidence, 1870–1933. In: Capie F, Woods GE (eds) Financial crises and world banking systems. Macmillian, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Bordo MD (1990) The lender of last resort: alternative views and historical experience. Fed Reserv Bank Richmond Econ Rev 76(1):18–29

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan J (2012) The constitutionalization of money. Cato J 30(2):251–258

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan J, Tullock G (1962) The calculus of consent: logical foundations of constitutional democracy. University of Michigans Press, Ann Arbor

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Calomiris CW (2013) The political foundations of scarce and unstable credit. Paper presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, 2013 Financial Markets Conference. Available online at: http://www.frbatlanta.org/documents/news/conferences/13fmc_calomiris.pdf

  • Congdon T (2009) Central banking in a free society. Institute of Economic Affairs, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond DW, Dybvig PH (1983) Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. J Polit Econ 91(3):401–419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond DW, Rajan RG (2009) Illiquidity and interest rate policy. NBER Working Paper No. 15197. Available online at: http://www.nber.org/papers/w15197

  • Dowd K (1991) Option clauses and bank suspensions. Cato J 10(3):761-773

  • Dowd K (1994) A proposal to end inflation. Econ J 104(425):828–840

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dowd K, Hutchinson M (2010) Alchemists of loss: how modern finance and government regulation crashed the financial system. Wiley, Chichester

    Google Scholar 

  • Duffie D (2009) The failure mechanics of dealer banks. Working Paper, Stanford University

  • Espinosa D (2012) Chain reaction: how the Fed’s asymmetric policy in 2003 lead to a panic in 2008. In: Beckworth D (ed) Boom and bust banking: the causes and cures of the great recession. Oakland, Independent Institute

    Google Scholar 

  • Federal Reserve (2008) Press release: November 25, 2008. http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20081125b.htm. Accessed 19 Jan 2015

  • Federal Reserve (2010a) Credit and liquidity programs and the balance sheet: lending to primary dealers. http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/bst_lendingprimary.htm Accessed 10 Oct 2012

  • Federal Reserve (2010b) FAQs: MBS purchase program. http://www.newyorkfed.org/markets/mbs_faq.html. Accessed 29 Oct 2012

  • Federal Reserve (2012) Press release: September 13, 2012. http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20120913a.htm. Accessed 29 Oct 2012

  • Fink A (2011) Free banking as an evolving system: The Case of Switzerland Reconsidered. Working Paper. Available online at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1751832

  • Flannery MJ (1996) Financial crises, payment system problems, and discount window lending. J Money Credit Bank 28(4):804–824

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freixas X, Parigi BM, Rochet J-C (2004) The lender of last resort: a 21st century approach. J Eur Econ Assoc 2(6):1085–1115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1960) A program for monetary stability. Fordham University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (2002 [1962]) Capitalism and freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press

  • Friedman, M (2007) January 22. Milton Friedman @ rest. The Wall Street Journal. Accessed 29 Aug 2012. Available online at: http://online.wsj.com/public/article/SB116942792191783271-ZAcsMDZOCPy0yCR3ADsShGbx2vk_20070128.html?mod=blogs

  • Friedman M, Schwartz AJ (1963) A monetary history of the United States, 1867–1960 Princeton. Princeton University Press, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrison RW (2000) Time and money: the macroeconomics of capital structure. Routledge, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Goodfriend M (2012) The elusive promise of independent central banking. Keynote Lecture, 2012 BOJ-IMES Conference. Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan. Available online at: http://www.tcmb.gov.tr/yeni/konferans/Goodfriend.pdf

  • Goodfriend M, King R (1988) Financial deregulation, monetary policy, and central banking. In: Haraf W, Kushmeider RM (eds) Restructuring banking and financial services in America. University Press of America, Lanham

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodfriend M, Lacker JM (1999) Limited commitment and central bank lending. Fed Reserv Bank Richmond Econ Q 85(4):1–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart CAE (1985) The evolution of central banks. London School of Economics and Political Science, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart CAE (1987) Why do banks need a central bank? Oxf Econ Pap 39(1):75–89

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart CAE, Huang H (2005) The lender of last resort. J Bank Finance 29:1059–1082

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gorton G (1985) Clearinghouses and the origins of central banking in the United States. J Econ Hist 45(2):277–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gorton G (1988) Banking panics and business cycles. Oxf Econ Pap 40(4):751–781

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorton G (2010) Slapped by the invisible hand: the panic of 2007. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorton G, Mullineaux DJ (1987) The joint production of confidence: endogenous regulation and nineteenth century commercial-bank clearinghouses. J Money Credit Bank 19(4):457–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1948) Individualism and economic order. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1960) The constitution of liberty. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1967) Studies in philosophy, politics, and economics. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1973) Law, legislation, and liberty, vol 1. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1978) Denationalisation of money: the argument refined. The Institute of Economic Affairs. Available online at: http://mises.org/books/denationalisation.pdf Accessed 29 Aug 2012

  • Hetzel RL (2008) The monetary policy of the federal reserve: a history. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hetzel RL (2012) The great recession: market failure or policy failure? Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Horwitz SG (2000) Microfoundations and macroeconomics: an Austrian perspective. Routledge, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Horwitz SG, Luther WJ (2010) The great recession and its aftermath from a monetary equilibrium theory perspective. Mercatus Center Working Paper10-63

  • Huerta de Soto J (2012) Money, bank credit, and economic cycles, 3rd edn. Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn

    Google Scholar 

  • Hummel JR (2012) Ben Bernanke Versus Milton Friedman: The federal reserve’s emergence as the U.S. Economy’s Central Planner. In: Beckworth D (ed) Boom and bust banking: the causes and cures of the great recession. Independent Institute, Oakland

    Google Scholar 

  • Humphrey TM (1989) Lender of last resort: the concept in history. Fed Reserv Bank Richmond Econ Rev March/April: 8–16

  • Ikeda SJ (2004) The dynamics of interventionism. Adv Aust Econ 8:21–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jarocinski M, Smets FR (2008) House prices and the stance of monetary policy. Fed Reserv Bank St Louis Rev 90(4):339–365

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaufman GG (1988) The truth about bank runs. In: England C, Huertas T (eds) The financial services revolution. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaufman GG (1991) The lender of last resort: a contemporary perspective. J Financ Serv Res 5(2):95–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kling A (2010) The case for auditing the Fed is Obvious. Cato Briefing Papers No. 118

  • Kotlikoff LJ (2010) Jimmy Stewart is dead: ending the world’s ongoing financial plague with limited purpose banking. Wiley, Hoboken

    Google Scholar 

  • Kotlikoff LJ, Leamer E (2009) A banking system we can trust. Forbes. Available online at: http://www.forbes.com/2009/04/22/loan-mortgage-mutual-fund-wall-street-opinions-contributors-bank.html Accessed 1 Sept 2012

  • Kydland FE, Prescott EC (1977) Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans. J Polit Econ 85(3):473–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leamer EE (2007) Housing is the business cycle. NBER Working Paper Series. Available online at http://www.nber.org/papers/w13428

  • Leeson PT, Robert Subrick J (2006) Robust political economy. Rev Aust Econ 19(2):107–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li M, Milne F, Qiu J (2013) Central bank screening, Moral hazard, and the lender of last resort policy. Queen’s Economics Department Working Paper No. 1317

  • Lipsey RG, Lancaster K (1956) The general theory of second best. Rev Econ Stud 24(1):11–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehrling P (2010) The New Lombard street: how the Fed became the dealer of last resort. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer AH (1986) Financial failures and financial policies. In: Kaufman GG, Kormendi RC (eds) Deregulating financial service: public policy in flux. Ballinger Publishing Company, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer AH (2003) A history of the federal reserve, volume 1: 1913–1951. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Mises L von (1988) Interventionism: an economic analysis. Irvington-on-Hudson: Foundation for Economic Education

  • O’Driscoll GP (2012) Central Banks: reform or abolish? Working Paper

  • O’Driscoll GP, Rizzo MJ (2014) Austrian economics re-examined: the economics of time and ignorance. London: Routledge

    Google Scholar 

  • Pennington M (2011) Robust political economy: classical liberalism and the future of public policy. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Roberts R (2010) Gambling with other People’s money: how perverted incentives created the financial crisis. Center at George Mason University, Mercatus

    Google Scholar 

  • Rochet J-C, Vives X (2004) Coordination failures and the lender of last resort: was Bagehot right after All? J Eur Econ Assoc 2(6):1116–1147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard MN (2008) The mystery of banking, 2nd edn. Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard MN (2009) Man, economy, and state with power and market: the scholar’s edition, 2nd edn. Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn

    Google Scholar 

  • Schuler K (1992) Free banking in Canada. In: Kevin Dowd K (ed) The experience of free banking. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz AJ (1986) Real and pseudo—financial crises. In: Capie F, Woods GE (eds) Financial crises and the world banking system. Macmillian, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz AJ (1987) The lender of last resort and the federal safety net. J Financ Serv Res 1(1):1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz AJ (1992) The misuse of the Fed’s discount window. Fed Reserv Bank St Louis Rev 58–69

  • Sechrest LJ (2008) Free banking: theory, history, and a laissez-faire model. Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin G (1988) The theory of free banking: money supply under competitive note issue. Rowman and Littlefield, Totowa

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin G (1989) Legal restrictions, financial weakening, and the lender of last resort. Cato J 9(2):429–469

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin G (1993) In defense of bank suspension. J Financ Serv Res 7:347–364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selgin G (1994) Free banking and monetary control. Econ J 104(427):1449–1459

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selgin G (2010) The futility of central banking. Cato J 30(3):465–473

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin G (2012) L street: bagehotian prescriptions for a 21st-century money market. Cato J 32(2):303–332

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin G, White LH (1994a) How would the invisible hand handle money? J Econ Lit 32(4):1718–1749

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin G, White LH (1994b) Monetary reform and the redemption of national bank notes, 1863–1913. Bus Hist Rev 68(2):205–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selgin G, Lastrapes WD, White LH (2012) Has the Fed been a failure? J Macroecon 34(3):569–596

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sheridan B (2011) Lender of last resort: an examination of the federal reserve’s primary dealer credit facility. Working Paper, University of Note Dame

  • Sinkey JF Jr (1977) Identifying large problem/failed banks: the case of franklin national bank of New York. J Financ Quant Anal 12(5):779–800

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith V (1990) The rationale of central banking and the free banking alternative. Liberty Fund, Indianapolis

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1982) On the lender of last resort. In: Kindleberger CP, Laffargue JP (eds) Financial crises: theory, history and policy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Stewart JB (2009) Eight days: the battle to save the american financial system. The New Yorker 85(September 21):58–81

    Google Scholar 

  • Sumner S (1989) Using futures instrument prices to target nominal income. Bull Econ Res 41(2):157–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sumner S (1995) The impact of futures price targeting on the precision and credibility of monetary policy. J Money Credit Bank 27(1):89–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sumner S (2011) Re-targeting the Fed. National Affairs 9(Fall). Available online at: http://www.nationalaffairs.com/doclib/20110919_Sumner.pdf

  • Sumner S (2012) How nominal GDP targeting could have prevented the crash of 2008. In: Beckworth D (ed) Boom and bust banking: the causes and cures of the great recession. Independent Institute, Oakland

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor JB (2007) Housing and monetary policy. NBER Working Paper Series. Available online at: http://www.nber.org/papers/w13682

  • Taylor JB (2009) Getting off track: how government actions and intervention caused, prolonged, and worsened the financial crisis. Hoover Institution Press, Stanford

    Google Scholar 

  • Thorton H (1939 [1802]) An enquiry into the nature and effects of the paper credit of Great Britain. FA Hayek, Introduction and eds. New York: Rinehart and Co

  • Timberlake RH Jr (1984) The central banking role of clearinghouse associations. J Money Credit Bank 16(1):1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Todd WF (2002) Central banking in a democracy: the problem of the lender of last resort. In: McCoy PA (ed) Financial modernization after Gramm-leach-Bliley. Newark, LexisNexis (Matthew Bender)

    Google Scholar 

  • Tuckman B (2010) Systemic risk and the Tri-Party Repo Clearingbanks. Center for Financial Stability Policy Paper (February)

  • Volcker P (2008) Speech before the economic club of New York. April 8. Cited in Selgin 2012:311

  • White LH (1989) Competition and currency: essays on free banking and money. New York University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • White LH (1995) Free banking in Britain: theory, experience, and debate, 1800–1845, 2nd eds. Institute of Economic Affairs, London

    Google Scholar 

  • White LH (1999) The theory of monetary institutions. Blackwell, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • White, LH (2008) How did we get into this financial mess? Cato Briefing Papers No. 110

  • White LH (2009) Federal reserve policy and the housing bubble. Cato J 29(1):115–125

    Google Scholar 

  • White LH (2010) The rule of law or the rule of central bankers? Cato J 30(3):451–463

    Google Scholar 

  • White LH (2012a) Monetary policy and the financial crisis. In: Beckworth D (ed) Boom and bust banking: the causes and cures of the great recession. Oakland, Independent Institute

    Google Scholar 

  • White LH (2012b) Making the transition to a new gold standard. Cato J 32(2):411–421

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilmarth AE Jr (2011) The Dodd-frank Act: a flawed and inadequate response to the too-Big-to-fail-problem. Or Law Rev 89:951–1057

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodford M (2012) Methods of policy accommodation at the interest-rate lower bound. Paper presented at the Jackson Hole Symposium, “The Changing Policy Landscape.” Available online at: http://kansascityfed.org/publicat/sympos/2012/mw.pdf?sm=jh083112-4

  • Woolsey WW (2012) The great recession and monetary disequilibrium. In: Beckworth D (ed) Boom and bust banking: the causes and cures of the great recession. Oakland, Independent Institute

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alexander William Salter.

Additional information

Alexander William Salter is an Assistant Professor of Economics at Berry College.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Salter, A.W. Robust Political Economy and the Lender of Last Resort. J Financ Serv Res 50, 1–27 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-015-0219-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-015-0219-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation