Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Game theoretic analysis of a three-stage interconnected forward and reverse supply chain

  • Published:
Environment, Development and Sustainability Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The dynamic economic scenario of today ensures that industrial and environmental policies that contribute to greener supply chain are incorporated. This paper considers an interconnected three-stage forward and reverse supply chain, which provides green products to a green conscious market. The procurement of raw materials is responsible for the first stage of the supply chain; the second manufacturing/remanufacturing process; and the third stage of marketing the products to the consumer. There is one supplier, one manufacturer, and one retailer in the forward supply chain. New raw materials are used in this supply chain, and new products are manufactured and sold. There is also a market for remanufactured products, and in this market, the same retailer also sells remanufactured products. There is one collector, one remanufacturer, and one retailer in the reverse supply chain. From consumers, the collector collects used products, processes and sells the remanufacturable ones to the remanufacturer. If the raw materials supplied by the collector are not adequate to satisfy the demand, the remanufacturer purchases the remainder from the seller. Both the manufacturer and the remanufacturer use green manufacturing processes. Two models, namely centralized model and decentralized model, are formulated. A numerical example is taken to illustrate the two model and perform sensitivity analysis.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14
Fig. 15

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Almehdawe, E., & Mantin, B. (2010). Vendor managed inventory with a capacitated manufacturer and multiple retailers: Retailer versus manufacturer leadership. International Journal of Production Economics, 128(1), 292–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Awan, U. (2020). Industrial ecology in support of sustainable development goals. In Responsible consumption and production (pp. 370–380). Springer.

  • Awan, U., Kraslawski, A., & Huiskonen, J. (2019). Progress from blue to the green world: Multilevel governance for pollution prevention planning and sustainability. In Handbook of environmental materials management.

  • Awan, U., Kraslawski, A., & Huiskonen, J. (2018). the effects of an ambidextrous leadership on the relationship between governance mechanism and social sustainability. Procedia-Social and Behavioral Sciences, 238, 398–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bag, S., Anand, N., & Pandey, K. K. (2017). Green supply chain management model for sustainable manufacturing practices. In: Green supply chain management for sustainable business practice (pp. 153–189). IGI Global.

  • Chaab, J., & Rasti-Barzoki, M. (2016). Cooperative advertising and pricing in a manufacturer–retailer supply chain with a general demand function; A game-theoretic approach. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 99, 112–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dastidar, K. G. (2004). On stackelberg games in a homogeneous product market. European Economic Review, 48(3), 549–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Fuente, M. V., Ros, L., & Cardos, M. (2008). Integrating forward and reverse supply chains: Application to a metal-mechanic company. International Journal of Production Economics, 111(2), 782–792.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dhir, A., Malodia, S., Awan, U., Sakashita, M., & Kaur, P. (2021). extended valence theory perspective on consumers’e-waste recycling intentions in Japan. Journal of Cleaner Production, 312, 127443.

  • Diabat, A., & Govindan, K. (2011). An analysis of the drivers affecting the implementation of green supply chain management. Resources, Conservation and Recycling, 55(6), 659–667.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doan, L. T. T., Amer, Y., Lee, S.-H., Phuc, P. N. K., & Dat, L. Q. (2019). A comprehensive reverse supply chain model using an interactive fuzzy approach-a case study on the Vietnamese electronics industry. Applied Mathematical Modelling, 76, 87–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dong, C., Shen, B., Chow, P.-S., Yang, L., & Ng, C. T. (2016). Sustainability investment under cap-and-trade regulation. Annals of Operations Research, 240(2), 509–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubey, R., Bag, S., Ali, S. S., & Venkatesh, V. G. (2013). Green purchasing is key to superior performance: An empirical study. International Journal of Procurement Management, 6(2), 187–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh, P. K., Manna, A. K., Dey, J. K., & Kar, S. (2021). Supply chain coordination model for green product with different payment strategies: A game theoretic approach. Journal of Cleaner Production, 290, 125734.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golroudbary, S. R., Zahraee, S. M., Awan, U., & Kraslawski, A. (2019). Sustainable operations management in logistics using simulations and modelling: A framework for decision making in delivery management. Procedia Manufacturing, 30, 627–634.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gorji, M.-A., Jamali, M.-B., & Iranpoor, M. (2020). A game-theoretic approach for decision analysis in end-of-life vehicle reverse supply chain regarding government subsidy. Waste Management, 120, 734–747

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, S. L. (1997). Beyond greening: Strategies for a sustainable world. Harvard Business Review, 75(1), 66–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, M., Song, M., Lee, L. H., & Ching, W. K. (2013). Analysis for strategy of closed-loop supply chain with dual recycling channel. International Journal of Production Economics, 144(2), 510–520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jafari, H., Hejazi, S. R., & Rasti-Barzoki, M. (2017). Sustainable development by waste recycling under a three-echelon supply chain: A game-theoretic approach. Journal of Cleaner Production, 142, 2252–2261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar, S., Teichman, S., & Timpernagel, T. (2012). A green supply chain is a requirement for profitability. International Journal of Production Research, 50(5), 1278–1296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, W., & Chen, J. (2018). Backward integration strategy in a retailer stackelberg supply chain. Omega, 75, 118–130.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, H., Long, H., & Li, X. (2020). Identification of critical factors in construction and demolition waste recycling by the grey-dematel approach: A Chinese perspective. Environmental Science and Pollution Research, 27(8), 8507–8525.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, B., Zhu, M., Jiang, Y., & Li, Z. (2016). Pricing policies of a competitive dual-channel green supply chain. Journal of Cleaner Production, 112, 2029–2042.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luthra, S., Garg, D., & Haleem, A. (2016). The impacts of critical success factors for implementing green supply chain management towards sustainability: An empirical investigation of Indian automobile industry. Journal of Cleaner Production, 121, 142–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mokhtar, A. R. M., Genovese, A., Brint, A., & Kumar, N. (2019). Improving reverse supply chain performance: The role of supply chain leadership and governance mechanisms. Journal of Cleaner Production, 216, 42–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagurney, A., & Nagurney, L. S. (2010). Sustainable supply chain network design: A multicriteria perspective. International Journal of Sustainable Engineering, 3(3), 189–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prahinski, C., & Kocabasoglu, C. (2006). Empirical research opportunities in reverse supply chains. Omega, 34(6), 519–532.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sasikumar, P., & Kannan, G. (2008). Issues in reverse supply chains, part II: Reverse distribution issues—An overview. International Journal of Sustainable Engineering, 1(4), 234–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sheu, J.-B., & Chen, Y. J. (2012). Impact of government financial intervention on competition among green supply chains. International Journal of Production Economics, 138(1), 201–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Srivastava, S. K. (2007). Green supply-chain management: A state-of-the-art literature review. International Journal of Management Reviews, 9(1), 53–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taleizadeh, A. A., & Sadeghi, R. (2019). Pricing strategies in the competitive reverse supply chains with traditional and e-channels: A game theoretic approach. International Journal of Production Economics, 215, 48–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Hoof, B., & Thiell, M. (2014). Collaboration capacity for sustainable supply chain management: Small and medium-sized enterprises in Mexico. Journal of Cleaner Production, 67, 239–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, S.-L., & Zhou, Y.-W. (2006). Two-echelon supply chain models: Considering duopolistic retailers’ different competitive behaviors. International Journal of Production Economics, 103(1), 104–116.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

Prof.(Dr.) Dipak Kumar Jana has formulated the models. Mr. Manojit Das has solved the models and compared the solutions of the models and drawn the figures. Dr. Shariful Alam has done the Numerical part. This paper is written by Mr. Manojit Das.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dipak Kumar Jana.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

There have been no conflicts of interest declared by the authors.

Ethical approval

Any of the authors’ investigations with human participants or living creatures are not included in this article.

Informed consent

Each individual participant in the research has given their informed consent.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1

The Hessian matrix of the objective function \(\pi _{\mathrm{SC}}(p_1, p_2,\theta _1, \theta _2)\) of the centralized model given in Eq. (7) is calculated as

$$\begin{aligned} H(p_1, p_2,\theta _1, \theta _2) = \begin{bmatrix} \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial p_1^2} &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial p_1 \partial p_2} &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial p_1 \partial \theta _1} &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial p_1 \partial \theta _2}\\ \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial p_2 \partial p_1} &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial p_2^2} &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial p_2 \partial \theta _1} &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial p_2 \partial \theta _2}\\ \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial \theta _1 \partial p_1} &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial \theta _1 \partial p_2} &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial \theta _1^2} &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial \theta _1 \partial \theta _2}\\ \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial \theta _2 \partial p_1} &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial \theta _2 \partial p_2} &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial \theta _2 \partial \theta _1} &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{SC}}}{\partial \theta _2^2} \end{bmatrix} =\begin{bmatrix} -2 b &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad d_1 &{}\quad 0\\ 0 &{}\quad -2 b &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad d_2\\ d_1 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad -2 I &{}\quad 0\\ 0 &{}\quad d_2 &{}\quad 0 &{}\quad -2 I \end{bmatrix} \end{aligned}$$

The leading principal minors \(\Delta _k\) of \(H(p_1, p_2,\theta _1, \theta _2)\) of order k are given by

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta _1 = -2b, \Delta _2 = 4 b^2, \Delta _3 = - 2 b (4 b I - d_1^2), \Delta _4 = (4 b I - d_1^2) (4 b I - d_2^2) \end{aligned}$$

From assumptions 3(i) and 3(ii), we get \(4 b I - d_1^2>0\) and \(4 b I - d_2^2>0\). Therefore, \((- 1)^k\Delta _k>0\) for all leading principle minors of \(H(p_1, p_2,\theta _1, \theta _2)\). Thus, \(H(p_1, p_2,\theta _1, \theta _2)\) is negative definite and \(\pi _{\mathrm{SC}}(p_1, p_2,\theta _1, \theta _2)\) is strictly concave. Using the first order conditions of Eq. (7) simultaneously, we get the unique global optimal solution to the centralized model as given in Eqs. (8)–(11). Putting the Eqs. (7)–(10) into Eq. (1), we get the optimal values of demands for the new and remanufactured products as given in Eqs. (12)–(13). Finally, putting the Eqs. (8)–(10) into Eq. (7), we get the optimal profit of the entire supply chain as given in Eq. (14).

Appendix 2

In decentralized model, first we consider retailer’s profit function. The Hessian matrix of the objective function \(\pi _\mathrm{R}(p_1, p_2)\) given in Eq. (2) is calculated as

Table 4 Change of unit selling prices and market demand w.r.t. % change of \(a, b,\ldots\)
Table 5 Change of unit selling prices and market demand w.r.t. % change of \(d_1, d_2\)
Table 6 Change of different profit functions w.r.t. % change of \(a, b,\ldots\)
Table 7 Change of different profit functions w.r.t. % change of \(d_1, d_2\)
$$\begin{aligned} H(p_1, p_2) =\begin{bmatrix} \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{R}}{\partial p_1^2} &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{R}}{\partial p_1 \partial p_2 } \\ \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{R}}{\partial p_2 \partial p_1 } &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{R}}{\partial p_2^2} \end{bmatrix} =\begin{bmatrix} -2 b &{}\quad 0\\ 0 &{}\quad -2 b \end{bmatrix} \end{aligned}$$

The leading principal minors \(\Delta _k\) of \(H(p_1, p_2)\) of order k are given by,

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta _1 = -2 b, \Delta _2 = 4 b^2 \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, \((- 1)^k\Delta _k>0\) for all leading principle minors of \(H(p_1, p_2)\). Thus, \(H(p_1, p_2)\) is negative definite and \(\pi _\mathrm{R}(p_1, p_2)\) is strictly concave. Using the first order conditions of Eq. (2) with respect to \(p_1\) and \(p_2\), we get the retailer’s optimum response functions as given in Eqs. (15)–(16).

Next, we consider the manufacturer’s and the remanufacturer’s profit functions. We first substitute the retailer’s optimum response function given in Eq. (15) into the manufacturer’s profit function given in Eq. (3). The Hessian matrix of the objective function \(\pi _\mathrm{M}(\theta _1, w_1)\) given in Eq. (3) is calculated as

$$\begin{aligned} H(\theta _1, w_1) =\begin{bmatrix} \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{M}}{\partial \theta _1^2} &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{M}}{\partial \theta _1 \partial w_1} \\ \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{M}}{\partial w_1 \partial \theta _1} &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{M}}{\partial w_1^2} \end{bmatrix} =\begin{bmatrix} -2 I &{}\quad \frac{d_1}{2}\\ \frac{d_1}{2} &{}\quad -b \end{bmatrix} \end{aligned}$$

The leading principal minors \(\Delta _k\) of \(H(\theta _1, w_1)\) of order k are given by,

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta _1 = -2 I, \Delta _2 = 2 b I - \frac{d_1^2}{4} \end{aligned}$$

From assumptions 3(i), we get \(2 b I - \frac{d_1^2}{4}>0\). Therefore, \((- 1)^k\Delta _k>0\) for all leading principle minors of \(H(\theta _1, w_1)\). Thus, \(H(\theta _1, w_1)\) is negative definite and \(\pi _\mathrm{M}(\theta _1, w_1))\) is strictly concave. Using the first order conditions of Eq. (3) with respect to \(\theta _1\) and \(w_1\), we get the manufacturer’s optimum response functions as given in Eqs. (17)–(18).

In a similar way, we substitute the retailer’s optimum response function given in Eq. (16) into the remanufacturer’s profit function given in Eq. (4). The Hessian matrix of the objective function \(\pi _{\mathrm{RM}}(\theta _2, w_2)\) given in Eq. (4) is calculated as

$$\begin{aligned} H(\theta _2, w_2) = \begin{bmatrix} \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{RM}}}{\partial \theta _2^2} &{} \quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{RM}}}{\partial \theta _2 \partial w_2 } \\ \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{RM}}}{\partial w_2 \partial \theta _2 } &{}\quad \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{RM}}}{\partial w_2^2} \end{bmatrix} =\begin{bmatrix} -2 I &{}\quad \frac{d_2}{2}\\ \frac{d_2}{2} &{}\quad -b \end{bmatrix} \end{aligned}$$

The leading principal minors \(\Delta _k\) of \(H(\theta _2, w_2)\) of order k are given by,

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta _1 = -2 I, \Delta _2 = 2 b I - \frac{d_2^2}{4} \end{aligned}$$

From assumptions 3(ii), we get \(2 b I - \frac{d_2^2}{4}>0\). Therefore, \((- 1)^k\Delta _k>0\) for all leading principle minors of \(H(\theta _2, w_2)\). Thus, \(H(\theta _2, w_2)\) is negative definite and \(\pi _{\mathrm{RM}}(\theta _2, w_2))\) is strictly concave. Using the first order conditions of Eq. (4) with respect to \(\theta _2\) and \(w_2\), we get the remanufacturer’s optimum response functions as given in Eqs. (19)–(20).

In the last step, we consider the supplier’s and the collector’s profit functions. We first substitute the optimum response functions of the retailer, manufacturer, remanufacturer given in Eqs. (15)–(20) into the supplier’s profit function given in Eq. (5). Then, the second order derivative of the supplier’s objective function \(\pi _{\mathrm{S}}(s_1)\) given in Eq. (5) with respective to \(s_1\) is calculated as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{S}}}{\partial s_1^2} = - \frac{4 b^2 I}{8 b I - d_1^2} - \frac{4 b^2 I (1 - \beta )^2}{8 b I - d_2^2} \end{aligned}$$

From assumptions 3(i) and 3(ii), we get \(8 b I - d_1^2>0\) and \(8 b I - d_2^2>0\). And since \(I>0\), it can be seen that \(- \frac{4 b^2 I}{8 b I - d_1^2} - \frac{4 b^2 I (1 - \beta )^2}{8 b I - d_2^2}<0\). Therefore, \(\frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{S}}}{\partial s_1^2}<0\), i.e. \(\pi _{\mathrm{S}}(s_1)\) is a strictly concave function.

In a similar way, we first substitute the optimum response functions of the retailer, remanufacturer given in Eqs. (16), (19) and (20) into the collector’s profit function given in Eq. (6). Then, the second order derivative of the collector’s objective function \(\pi _{\mathrm{C}}(s_2)\) given in Eq. (5) with respective to \(s_2\) is calculated as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{C}}}{\partial s_2^2} = - \frac{4 b^2 I \beta ^2}{8 b I - d_2^2} \end{aligned}$$

From assumptions 3(ii), we get \(8 b I - d_2^2>0\). And since \(I>0\), it can be seen that \(- \frac{4 b^2 I \beta ^2}{8 b I - d_2^2}<0\). Therefore, \(\frac{\partial ^2 \pi _{\mathrm{C}}}{\partial s_2^2}<0\), i.e. \(\pi _{\mathrm{C}}(s_2)\) is a strictly concave function.

Finally, simultaneously solving the first order condition of Eq. (5) with respect to \(s_1\) and first order condition of Eq. (6) with respect to \(s_2\) gives the optimal unit selling prices of the supplier and the collector as given in Eqs. (21) and (22). Putting the Eqs. (15)–(22) into Eq. (1), we get the optimal values of demands for the new and remanufactured products as given in Eqs. (23)–(24). Finally, putting the Eqs. (15)–(22) into Eq. (7), we get the optimal profit of the overall supply chain as given in Eq. (25).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Das, M., Jana, D.K. & Alam, S. Game theoretic analysis of a three-stage interconnected forward and reverse supply chain. Environ Dev Sustain 24, 7976–8007 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-021-01770-w

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-021-01770-w

Keywords

Navigation