Skip to main content
Log in

A fuzzy multi-stakeholder multi-criteria methodology for water allocation and reuse in metropolitan areas

  • Published:
Environmental Monitoring and Assessment Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, a fuzzy decision making methodology is proposed to find a socially optimal scenario for allocating effluent of wastewater treatment plants and urban and suburban runoffs to agricultural regions and recharging aquifers. The presented methodology named modified fuzzy social choice (MFSC) considers multi-stakeholder multi-criteria problems under uncertainties inherent in a decision making process utilizing a fuzzy ranking method and the fuzzy social choice (FSC) theory. A set of water and wastewater allocation scenarios are proposed for water quantity and quality management of the study area, while six main stakeholders with conflicting utilities and different negotiation powers are involved. The proposed methodology is applied to Tehran metropolitan area, the capital city of Iran with the population of about 8 million people, to examine its applicability and effectiveness. The results shows that using fuzzy multi-stakeholder multi-criteria decision making method considering equal and different negotiation powers can lead to different outcomes. Based on the results, the MFSC method, which considers a number of decision makers having different negotiation powers, degrees of importance of decision making criteria, and some important uncertainties, performs more promising in real water resources management problems.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Abed-Elmdoust, A., & Kerachian, R. (2012). Regional hospital solid waste assessment using the evidential reasoning approach. Science of the Total Environment, 441, 67–76.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Alizadeh, M. R., Nikoo, M. R., & Rakhshandehroo, G. R. (2017a). Developing a multi-objective conflict-resolution model for optimal groundwater management based on fallback bargaining models and social choice rules: a case study. Water Resources Management, 31(5), 1457–1472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alizadeh, M. R., Nikoo, M. R., & Rakhshandehroo, G. R. (2017b). Hydro-environmental management of groundwater resources: A fuzzy-based multi-objective compromise approach. Journal of Hydrology, 551, 540–554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blin, J. M. (1974). Fuzzy relations in group decision theory. Cybernetics, 4, 17–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blin, J. M., & Whinston, A. B. (1973). Fuzzy sets and social choice. Cybernetics, 3, 28–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brams, S. J., & Fishburn, P. C. (1978). Approval voting. The American Political Science Review, 72, 831–847.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, S.-M., & Wang, C.-H. (2009). Fuzzy risk analysis based on ranking fuzzy numbers using α-cuts, belief features and signal/noise ratios. Expert Systems with Applications, 36(3), 5576–5581.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Condorcet, M. (1785). Essai sur l’application de l’analyse a la probabilite des de’cisions rendues a la pluralite des voix. Paris: Imprimerie Royale.

    Google Scholar 

  • d'Angelo, A., Eskandari, A., & Szidarovszky, F. (1998). Social choice procedures in water-resource management. Journal of Environmental Management, 52(3), 203–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Borda, J.-C. (1781). Memoire sur les elections au scrutin. Paris, France: historie de l’academie royale des Sciences.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Pablo D (2007) Ranking of ecological risks related to wastewater management. In: Zaidi M (ed) Wastewater Reuse–Risk Assessment, Decision-Making and Environmental Security. NATO Science for Peace and Security Series. Springer Netherlands, 111–120. doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4020-6027-4_12

  • Diaby, M., Ferrer, H., & Valognes, F. (2013). A social choice approach to primary resource management: the rubber tree case in Africa. Forest Policy and Economics, 28(0), 8–14. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2013.01.002.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Estalaki, S. M., Kerachian, R., & Nikoo, M. R. (2016). Developing water quality management policies for the Chitgar urban lake: application of fuzzy social choice and evidential reasoning methods. Environmental Earth Sciences, 75(5), 404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • García-Lapresta, J. L., & Martínez-Panero, M. (2002). Borda count versus approval voting: a fuzzy approach. Public Choice, 112(1–2), 167–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghodsi, S. H., Kerachian, R., & Zahmatkesh, Z. (2016a). A multi-stakeholder framework for urban runoff quality management: application of social choice and bargaining techniques. Science of the Total Environment, 550, 574–585.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Ghodsi, S. H., Kerachian, R., Estalaki, S. M., Nikoo, M. R., & Zahmatkesh, Z. (2016b). Developing a stochastic conflict resolution model for urban runoff quality management: application of info-gap and bargaining theories. Science of the Total Environment, 550, 574–585.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Goetz, R. U., Martinez, Y., & Rodrigo, J. (2008). Water allocation by social choice rules: the case of sequential rules. Ecological Economics, 65(2), 304–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kacprzyk J (1984) Collective decision making with a fuzzy majority rule. In: Proc. WOGSC Congress, AFCET, Paris. 153–159.

  • Kacprzyk, J. (1986). Group decision making with a fuzzy linguistic majority. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 18(2), 105–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kacprzyk, J. (1987). On some fuzzy cores and'soft'consensus measures in group decision making. The Analysis of Fuzzy Information, 2, 119–130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kacprzyk, J., Fedrizzi, M., & Nurmi, H. (1992). Group decision making and consensus under fuzzy preferences and fuzzy majority. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 49(1), 21–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kangas, A., Laukkanen, S., & Kangas, J. (2006). Social choice theory and its applications in sustainable forest management—a review. Forest Policy and Economics, 9(1), 77–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kant, S., & Lee, S. (2004). A social choice approach to sustainable forest management: an analysis of multiple forest values in northwestern Ontario. Forest Policy and Economics, 6(3), 215–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laukkanen, S., Kangas, A., & Kangas, J. (2002). Applying voting theory in natural resource management: a case of multiple-criteria group decision support. Journal of Environmental Management, 64(2), 127–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madani, K., Read, L., & Shalikarian, L. (2014). Voting under uncertainty: A stochastic framework for analyzing group decision making problems. Water Resources Management, 28(7), 1839–1856.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahjouri, N., & Abbasi, M. R. (2015). Waste load allocation in rivers under uncertainty: application of social choice procedures. Environmental Monitoring and Assessment, 187(2), 5.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahjouri, N., & Bizhani-Manzar, M. (2013). Waste load allocation in rivers using fallback bargaining. Water Resources Management, 27(7), 2125–2136. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11269-013-0279-2.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahjouri, N., & Pourmand, E. (2017). A social choice-based methodology for treated wastewater reuse in urban and suburban areas. Environmental Monitoring and Assessment, 189(7), 325. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10661-017-6039-7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, W. E., Shields, D. J., Tolwinski, B., & Kent, B. (1996). An application of social choice theory to USDA Forest Service decision making. Journal of Policy Modeling, 18(6), 603–621.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morais, D. C., & de Almeida, A. T. (2012). Group decision making on water resources based on analysis of individual rankings. Omega, 40(1), 42–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nurmi, H. (1981). Approaches to collective decision making with fuzzy preference relations. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 6(3), 249–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nurmi, H., & Kacprzyk, J. (1991). On fuzzy tournaments and their solution concepts in group decision making. European Journal of Operational Research., 51(2), 223–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nurmi, H. (1988). Discrepancies in the outcomes resulting from different voting schemes. Theory and Decision, 25(2), 193–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nurmi H (1999) Voting paradoxes and how to deal with them. Springer.

  • Nurmi, H. (2001). Resolving group choice paradoxes using probabilistic and fuzzy concepts. Group Decision and Negotiation, 10(2), 177–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nurmi, H. (2008). Fuzzy social choice: a selective retrospect. Soft Computing, 12(3), 281–288 2007.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roy, B. (1991). The outranking approach and the foundations of electre methods. Theory and Decision, 31(1), 49–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sheikhmohammady M, Madani K (2008) Bargaining over the Caspian Sea—the largest lake on the earth. Proceeding of the 2008 World environmental and water resources congress, Honolulu, Hawaii:1–9. doi: https://doi.org/10.1061/40976(316)262.

  • Sheikhmohammady, M., Kilgour, D. M., & Hipel, K. W. (2010). Modeling the Caspian Sea negotiations. Group Decision and Negotiation, 19(2), 149–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shields, D. J., Tolwinski, B., & Kent, B. M. (1999). Models for conflict resolution in ecosystem management. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 33(1), 61–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Srdjevic, B. (2007). Linking analytic hierarchy process and social choice methods to support group decision-making in water management. Decision Support Systems, 42(4), 2261–2273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yekom Consulting Engineers (2009) Urban runoff quantity and quality management in the southern part of Tehran- Technical report.

  • Zadeh, L. A. (1983). A computational approach to fuzzy quantifiers in natural languages. Computers & Mathematics with Applications, 9(1), 149–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zolfagharipoor, M. A., & Ahmadi, A. (2016). A decision-making framework for river water quality management under uncertainty: application of social choice rules. Journal of Environmental Management, 183, 152–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank Mr. Mehdi Shafeie-Far, the head of water resources management department of Yekom Consulting Engineers, who kindly provided useful and precise information about the study area.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Najmeh Mahjouri.

Appendix

Appendix

Fuzzy ranking

Assume a DM wants to rank m fuzzy numbers \( {\overset{\sim }{A}}_1,{\overset{\sim }{A}}_2,\dots, {\overset{\sim }{A}}_m \). The kth α-cut \( {\overset{\sim }{A}}_i^{\alpha_k} \) of the fuzzy number \( {\overset{\sim }{A}}_i \) is defined as follows (Chen and Wang 2009):

$$ {\overset{\sim }{A}}_i^{\alpha_k}=\left\{x\ |\ {f}_{{\overset{\sim }{A}}_i}(x)\ge {\alpha}_k,x\in X\right\},{\alpha}_k=\frac{k}{n},k\in \left\{0,1,\dots, n\right\},n\in N $$
(A.1)

where n denotes the number of α-cuts. The minimal value li, k and the maximal value ri, k of the kth α-cut of the fuzzy number \( {\overset{\sim }{A}}_i \) are defined as follows:

$$ {l}_{i,k}=\underset{x\in X}{\mathit{\operatorname{inf}}}\left\{x\ |\ {f}_{{\overset{\sim }{A}}_i}(x)\ge {\alpha}_k\right\} $$
(A.2)
$$ {r}_{i,k}=\underset{x\in X}{\mathit{\sup}}\left\{x\ |\ {f}_{{\overset{\sim }{A}}_i}(x)\ge {\alpha}_k\right\} $$
(A.3)

The maximal barrier U and the minimal barrier L of the m fuzzy numbers \( {\overset{\sim }{A}}_1,{\overset{\sim }{A}}_2,\dots, {\overset{\sim }{A}}_m \) are defined as follows:

$$ U=\underset{\forall i}{\mathit{\max}}\left\{x|x\in {\overset{\sim }{A}}_i^{\alpha },0\le \alpha \le {h}_{{\overset{\sim }{A}}_i},i=1,2,\dots, m\right\} $$
(A.4)
$$ L=\underset{\forall i}{\mathit{\min}}\left\{x|x\in {\overset{\sim }{A}}_i^{\alpha },0\le \alpha \le {h}_{{\overset{\sim }{A}}_i},i=1,2,\dots, m\right\} $$
(A.5)

where \( {h}_{{\overset{\sim }{A}}_i} \) denotes the height of \( {\overset{\sim }{A}}_i \) defined as \( {h}_{{\overset{\sim }{A}}_i}={\mathit{\sup}}_{x\in X}{f}_{{\overset{\sim }{A}}_i}(x) \).

The signal/noise ratio \( {\widehat{\eta}}_{i,k} \) of the kth α-cut of the fuzzy number \( {\overset{\sim }{A}}_i \) proposed in this method is defined as follows:

$$ {\widehat{\eta}}_{i,k}=\frac{m_{i,k}-L}{\delta_{i,k}+c} $$
(A.6)

where mi, k and δi, k denote the middle point and the spread of \( {\overset{\sim }{A}}_i^{\alpha_k} \), respectively, and are defined as follows:

$$ {m}_{i,k}=\frac{\left({r}_{i,k}+{l}_{i,k}\right)}{2} $$
(A.7)
$$ {\delta}_{i,k}={r}_{i,k}-{l}_{i,k} $$
(A.8)

c is a parameter that should be greater than the value of R − L. The ranking index \( RI\left({\overset{\sim }{A}}_i\right) \) of the fuzzy number \( {\overset{\sim }{A}}_i \) is calculated as follows:

$$ RI\left({\overset{\sim }{A}}_i\right)=\frac{h_{{\overset{\sim }{A}}_i}{\sum}_{k=1}^n{\alpha}_k\times {\widehat{\eta}}_{i,k}}{\sum_{k=1}^n{\alpha}_k} $$
(A.9)

where \( {\alpha}_k={h}_{{\overset{\sim }{A}}_i}\times \frac{k}{n},k\in \left\{0,1,\dots, n\right\},n\in N \), and n denotes the number of α-cuts. The larger the value of \( RI\left({\overset{\sim }{A}}_i\right) \), the better the ranking of \( {\overset{\sim }{A}}_i \). Details and examples about this fuzzy ranking method can be found in Chen and Wang (2009).

Fuzzy Borda count

This method is an extension of the classic Borda count method (de Borda 1781). In fuzzy Borda count, each DM assigns the following value to every alternative xi based on its preferences and relative power (García-Lapresta and Martínez-Panero 2002):

$$ {r}_k\left({x}_i\right)={w}^k\sum \limits_{\begin{array}{c}j=1\\ {}{r}_{ij}^k>0.5\end{array}}^n{r}_{ij}^k $$
(A.10)

where wk is the negotiation power of the kth DM. Equation A.10 indicates the sum of the entries greater than 0.5 in the row i which is multiplied by each DM’s power in the fuzzy preference relations. Then, the collective score of alternative xi is obtained as follows:

$$ r\left({x}_i\right)=\sum \limits_{k=1}^m{r}_k\left({x}_i\right) $$
(A.11)

Thus, the highest scored alternative (\( \underset{i}{\max }r\left({x}_i\right) \)) will be chosen. More details and examples of this method can be found in García-Lapresta and Martínez-Panero (2002).

Fuzzy Minimax

Also known as Minimax degree set Q(β); this method is the fuzzy extension of classic Max-Min Winner (Nurmi 1988). For each alternative xi, xj ∈ X and each DM let (Nurmi 1981):

$$ {\upsilon}_D^k\left({x}_j\right)={w}^k\underset{i}{\max }{r}_{ij} $$
(A.12)

where wk is the negotiation power of the kth DM. Then, we define:

$$ {\upsilon}_D\left({x}_j\right)=\underset{k}{\max }{\upsilon}_D^k\left({x}_j\right) $$
(A.13)

Now let:

$$ \underset{j}{\min }{\upsilon}_D\left({x}_j\right)=\beta $$
(A.14)

Then:

$$ Q\left(\beta \right)=\left\{{x}_i|{\upsilon}_D\left({x}_j\right)=\beta \right\} $$
(A.15)

Therefore, the alternative with the value β will be chosen. More details about this method can be found in Nurmi (1981).

Fuzzy linguistic quantifiers

This method utilizes fuzzy logic with linguistic quantifiers for group decision making. Fuzzy linguistic quantifier “most” is employed to represent a fuzzy majority. Also, two direct and indirect solutions, namely core solution and consensus winner solution, are used for selecting the best alternative. In this section, if not otherwise determined, Q = most.

Direct solution (core)

The core is defined as a set of non-dominated alternatives not defeated in pairwise comparisons by “most” DMs (Kacprzyk et al. 1992). The linguistic quantifier “most” was first presented by Zadeh (1983). In this solution, let (Kacprzyk et al. 1992):

$$ {h}_{ij}^k=\left\{\begin{array}{c}1\ if\ {r}_{ij}^k<0.5\ \\ {}0\kern0.75em \mathrm{otherwise}\end{array}\right. $$
(A.16)

where \( {h}_{ij}^k \) is used to define whether alternative xi defeats xj or not, ∀i, j, k. Then,

$$ {h}_j^k=\frac{w^k}{n-1}\sum \limits_{i=1,i\ne j}^n{h}_{ij}^k $$
(A.17)

is the extent to which DM k with the negotiation power of wk is not against alternative xj. Next,

$$ {h}_j=\frac{1}{m}\sum \limits_{k=1}^m{h}_j^k $$
(A.18)

is the extent to which all the DMs are not against xj, and

$$ {\upsilon}_Q^j={\mu}_Q\left({h}_j\right)=\left\{\begin{array}{c}1\kern1.5em for\ {h}_j\ge 0.8\\ {}2{h}_j-0.6\kern0.5em for\ 0.3<{h}_j<0.8\\ {}0\kern1.25em for\ {h}_j<0.3\end{array}\right. $$
(A.19)

is to what extent “most” DMs are not against xj. The fuzzy Q-core is now defined as the fuzzy set:

$$ {C}_{\mathrm{Q}}={\upsilon}_Q^1/{x}_1+\dots +{\upsilon}_Q^n/{x}_n $$
(A.20)

which denotes a fuzzy set of alternatives that are not defeated by “most” DMs. If introducing a threshold on the degree of defeat in Eq. A.16, the fuzzy α/Q-core can be defined. Let

$$ {h}_{ij}^k\left(\upalpha \right)=\left\{\begin{array}{c}1\ if\ {r}_{ij}^k<\upalpha \le 0.5\ \\ {}0\kern0.75em \mathrm{otherwise}\end{array}\right. $$
(A.21)

then, following Eqs. A.17 to A.20, the fuzzy α/Q-core is defined as:

$$ {C}_{\upalpha /Q}={\upsilon}_Q^1\left(\upalpha \right)/{x}_1+\dots +{\upsilon}_Q^n\left(\upalpha \right)/{x}_n $$
(A.22)

which is a fuzzy set of alternatives that are not sufficiently defeated by “most” DMs. Also, the strength of defeat can be introduced into Eq. A.16, and the fuzzy s/Q-core can be defined. Then, the following function is introduced:

$$ {\widehat{h}}_{ij}^k=\left\{\begin{array}{c}2\left(0.5-{r}_{ij}^k\right)\ if\ {r}_{ij}^k<0.5\ \\ {}0\kern0.75em otherwise\end{array}\right. $$
(A.23)

Following Eqs. A.17 to A.20, the fuzzy s/Q-core is defined as:

$$ {C}_{\mathrm{s}/Q}={\widehat{\upsilon}}_Q^1/{x}_1+\dots +{\widehat{\upsilon}}_Q^n/{x}_n $$
(A.24)

Indirect solution (consensus winner)

In this method, first, a social fuzzy preference relation is determined which is defined by R = [rij], and is given by (Kacprzyk et al. 1992):

$$ {r}_{ij}=\left\{\begin{array}{c}\frac{1}{m}\sum \limits_{k=1}^m{w^k{a}^k}_{ij}\kern1em if\ i\ne j\\ {}0\kern5em \mathrm{otherwise}\end{array}\right. $$
(A.25)

where wk is the negotiation power of the kth DM, and

$$ {a^k}_{ij}=\left\{\begin{array}{c}1\ if\ {r}_{ij}^k>0.5\ \\ {}0\kern0.75em \mathrm{otherwise}\end{array}\right. $$
(A.26)

Since the social fuzzy preference relation is calculated, the fuzzy extension of consensus winner method will be applied which is defined by:

$$ {g}_{ij}=\left\{\begin{array}{c}1\ if\ {r}_{ij}^k>0.5\ \\ {}0\kern0.75em \mathrm{otherwise}\end{array}\right. $$
(A.27)

which expresses whether or not xi defeats xj. Then, let:

$$ {g}_i=\frac{1}{n-1}\sum \limits_{j=1,j\ne i}^n{g}_{ij} $$
(A.28)

gi is the mean degree to which alternative xi is preferred to all other alternatives. Then,

$$ {z}_Q^i={\mu}_Q\left({g}_j\right)=\left\{\begin{array}{c}1\kern1.5em for\ {g}_j\ge 0.8\\ {}2{h}_j-0.6\kern0.5em for\ 0.3<{g}_j<0.8\\ {}0\kern1.25em for\ {g}_j<0.3\end{array}\right. $$
(A.29)

is the extent to which xi is preferred to “most” other alternatives. Finally, the fuzzy Q-consensus winner is defined as:

$$ {W}_Q={z}_Q^1/{x}_1+\dots +{z}_Q^n/{x}_n $$
(A.30)

which is a fuzzy set of alternatives that are preferred to “most” other alternatives. Analogously to the case of the core solution, a threshold is introduced as:

$$ {g}_{ij}\left(\upalpha \right)=\left\{\begin{array}{c}1\ if\ {r}_{ij}^k>\upalpha \ge 0.5\ \\ {}0\kern0.75em \mathrm{otherwise}\end{array}\right. $$
(A.31)

Then, following the Eqs. A.28 and A.29, we can define the fuzzy α/Q-consensus winner as:

$$ {W}_{\upalpha /Q}={z}_Q^1\left(\upalpha \right)/{x}_1+\dots +{z}_Q^n\left(\upalpha \right)/{x}_n $$
(A.32)

which is a fuzzy set of alternatives that are preferred to “most” other alternatives. Also, the strength of preference can be introduced into Eq. A.27 by defining:

$$ {\widehat{g}}_{ij}\left(\upalpha \right)=\left\{\begin{array}{c}2\left({r}_{ij}^k-0.5\right)\ if\ {r}_{ij}^k>0.5\ \\ {}0\kern0.75em \mathrm{otherwise}\end{array}\right. $$
(A.33)

Then, following the Eqs. A.28 and A.29, the fuzzy s/Q-consensus winner is defined as:

$$ {W}_{\mathrm{s}/Q}={\widehat{z}}_Q^1/{x}_1+\dots +{\widehat{z}}_Q^n/{x}_n $$
(A.34)

which is a fuzzy set of alternatives that are strongly preferred to “most” other alternatives. More details and examples about fuzzy linguistic quantifiers method can be found in Kacprzyk et al. (1992).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Pourmand, E., Mahjouri, N. A fuzzy multi-stakeholder multi-criteria methodology for water allocation and reuse in metropolitan areas. Environ Monit Assess 190, 444 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10661-018-6813-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10661-018-6813-1

Keywords

Navigation