Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Bi-demographic and current account dynamics using SVAR model: evidence from Saudi Arabia

  • Published:
Economic Change and Restructuring Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The study explores the impacts of the bi-demographic structure on the current account and gross domestic product (GDP) growth. Using structural vector autoregressive modeling (SVAR), we track the dynamic impacts on these underlying variables. New insights about the dynamic interrelation between bi-population age dependency rate, current account, and GDP growth have been developed. In the short and medium terms, the reactions of GDP growth to both shocks of native and immigrant working-age populations move unsteadily in opposite directions. However, in the long run, both effects become moderately positive. Additionally, the positive long-run contribution of immigrant workers to the current account growth largely compensates for the negative contribution of the native population. We find a negative hump-shaped reaction of Saudi Age Dependency Rate to immigration policy shocks during a generation. When the shocks emanate from immigrants’ working age, there is a complex mechanism from the complementarity process to the substitutability process between immigrants and the Saudi workforce. In the short and medium term, the immigrant workers are more complement than substitutes for native workers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The term immigrant is more appropriate in our case since the vast majority of foreign people has restricted visas and are connected to the persons or companies where they work through a sponsorship system (named Kafala, i.e., cautioner system).

  2. The term of bi-demographic structure is justified by the wide size of the immigrant to the native population. In 2016, the immigrant working-age population was about 8.8 million, and the native active population reached 9.4 million.

  3. The dependency rate refers to the ratio of children (below 25 years) and old aged (above 65 years) to the working age population (from 25 to 65 years). We can use the active age structure ratio which is the inverse of the age-dependency rate as in Fair and Dominguez (1991).

  4. The overlapping generation framework supposes that the representative agent lives for four periods: childhood, young working age, old working age and retirement.

  5. The first official population census of Saudi Arabia was in 1974, this explains the starting year of our dataset. During the period 1974–2016, there are many events and stylized facts that impacted and continue to impact the economic and demographic factors. First, the revenues from oil exports are the major financial sources of Saudi Arabia economy, such returns affect the CAB. Consequently, any perturbation in oil revenues leads to multiple shocks. Also, the reliance on foreign demand and foreign supply labor make the Saudi economy vulnerable to any international or regional or local crisis as the international financial crisis, regional wars, progressive changes in behaviors, and demographic changes in terms of ages or immigrant flows.

  6. The sources of data are General Authority for Statistics (GaStat, Statistics library, https://www.stats.gov.sa/en), Saudi Monetary Authority (SAMA, Economic reports and statistics, http://www.sama.gov.sa/en-US/Pages/default.aspx).

  7. The proportion of age structure are calculated within each group of the citizens and immigrants.

  8. According to GaStat and the ministry of Labor (2015) and during the last decade 2005–2014, the immigrant labor force in the private sector reached in average 87%, and only 8% in the government sector.

  9. For more details see the links: https://www.worldbank.org/en/topic/labormarkets/brief/migration-and-remittances or https://www.knomad.org/data/remittances.

  10. Following the GaStat (Demographic Survey 2016), we define the immigrant age-dependency rate by considering the immigrant residents in Saudi Arabia.

  11. According to the Saudi Ministry of Labor (Labor market report July 2016, page 15), most immigrant workers are low-skilled and habitually employed with low wages in construction, retail and wholesale trade, personal services, and manufacturing.

  12. Differently to ADF test, KPSS test can check for the stationarity in the presence of a deterministic trend. It is a one-sided test because the parameter value of null hypothesis of stationarity is for the variance of random walk. We also apply Zivot and Andrews (2002) test to consider the structural breaks in the series (see Table 3, “Appendix 1”).

  13. This leads to a significant reduction in the size distortion of the test in the relevant case of a highly autoregressive process.

  14. PSS (2001) used dummy variables in their empirical work, they indicate that the inclusion of such variables does not affect the asymptotic associated critical values when the fraction of nonzero dummy variables tends to zero as the sample size increases. Nevertheless as in PSS (2001), the critical values are valid as even if the dummies appear in the CEC equation, but they are not in the levels-equation, i.e., long-run relationship.

  15. Unfortunately and even if it allows for a maximum number of five breaks, we cannot apply the Bai and Perron (1998) test for multiple structural breaks dates selected endogenously, because it is not reliable for small sample size as it requires at least 100 observations.

  16. In the case 2 where the ECT includes the intercept, the bounds cointegration test assumes the null hypothesis that \({b}_{0}={b}_{i}={a}_{0}=0, \forall i\). In the cases 4 and 5 where the ECT contains the trend, we test the null hypothesis that \({b}_{0}={b}_{i}={a}_{1}=0, \forall i\) and that \({b}_{0}={b}_{i}=0, \forall i\), respectively.

  17. For more details on the ARDL strategy in testing and diagnosing the bounds cointegration, see the article of Philips (2018).

  18. To save space, we have not displayed all ARDL outputs in Appendix, but all output are available upon request.

  19. As indicated by Sachs (1982), it is important to develop a small theoretical model that focuses on few fundamental stochastic variables in analyzing the CAB. We have in progress a theoretical research project that distinguish native and immigrant population in the framework of present value modeling using overlapping generations.

  20. As suggested by anonymous referee, we assess that we can employ other explanatory factors that could influence the nexus CA-population age structure such as the real exchange rate as raised by Aloy and Gente (2009), the world oil prices (Cooper 2008), and international liquidity. These factors are interrelated, and we hope to investigate the relationship of these variables in future studies. Nevertheless, it appears that the SAMA adopts a quasi-fixed nominal exchange rate to the US dollar. But it remains that the USD volatility directly impacts the price level in Saudi economy, and indirectly its CAB. Also, in the long run, it is expected that the changes in the real oil price would influence the real exchange rate (Habib and Kalamova 2007). However, within the VAR approach, it is already enough to work with four variables in managing the economic and financial meaning of the impulse response functions.

  21. According to Ogaki (1993), the null of cointegration is harder to construct than the null of no cointegration. Additionally, he indicates that the empirical estimation of long-run covariances parameters, by using VAR pre-whitening method, can substantially improve the properties of CCR estimators in small samples.

  22. The matrices A and B are both unknown constraints and parameters based on economic analysis and economic hypotheses. They serve to shift from reduced errors to structural errors that have economic meaning.

  23. The Lagrange multiplier statistic of Breusch–Pagan (1980) can be determined by \(LM=T\sum_{k=2}^{K}\sum_{l=1}^{k-1}{r}_{kl}^{2}\) where \({r}_{kl}\) is the residual correlation coefficient between equations \(k\) and \(l\) defined by \({\widehat{\sigma }}_{kl}/{\left({\widehat{\sigma }}_{kk}{\widehat{\sigma }}_{ll}\right)}^{1/2}\). The limiting distribution of this statistic is \({\chi }_{q}^{2}\) as for the LR statistic. The LM statistic is easier to calculate because it does not require the maximum likelihood estimates of \({\Omega }_{\upvarepsilon }\). From Table 3.2 (“Appendix 1”), we obtain that \(LM=20.33\) which is greater than the critical value of 12.59, leading also to reject the null hypothesis of diagonal covariance matrix.

  24. The test of Brown and Forsythe (1974) provides that BF-statistic is about 33.42 with a p value of 6.54E−17, meaning a strong evidence of heteroskedasticity between residuals-VAR variances.

  25. The number of non-redundant elements of variance–covariance matrix \({\Omega }_{\upvarepsilon }\) is \(K\left(K+1\right)/2\), where \(K\) is the number of variables in the VAR. Accordingly, we can identify just \(K\left(K+1\right)/2\) parameters of the structural VAR. Since there is \({2K}^{2}\) elements in the matrices \(A\) and \(B\), the number of required restrictions to identify the full AB-model is \({2K}^{2}-K\left(K+1\right)/2\) which is equal to \({\mathrm{K}}^{2}+\mathrm{K}\left(\mathrm{K}-1\right)/2\). If the matrix \(A\) or \(B\) is set to be the identity matrix, then \(K\left(K-1\right)/2\) restrictions remain to be imposed.

  26. By definition, an increase in active age population corresponds to a decrease in age-dependency rate (ADR), and vice versa.

  27. The trade-off between the just-identification and the statistical significance of the parameters in AB-model leads to prefer an over-identification, requires to test the null hypothesis of the restrictions validity using likelihood ratio (LR) statistic. This is asymptotically distributed as \({\chi }_{\left({q}_{u}-{q}_{r}\right)}^{2}\) where \({q}_{u}\) and \({q}_{r}\) are the number of restrictions under just-identification and over-identification, respectively. In our case, we find that \({\chi }_{\left(10-8\right)}^{2}=0.0425\) with a p value 0.979, meaning that there is no statistical significance between outcomes of restricted and unrestricted identification.

  28. For more details on SVAR identification and related algebra, see Lucchetti (2006).

  29. Because, as the young and elderly population do not regress, a decrease in the Saudi ADR means more Saudi working-age population that occupy jobs in the labor market.

  30. According to McKinsey Global Institute Report (2015), the complementarity holds mostly in the private sector where the immigrants are predominantly employed, but they appear more substitutes than complements in the public sector dominated by Saudi nationals.

  31. All data and empirical outputs are available upon request.

  32. By considering the OECD countries, Ortega and Peri (2009) emphasize that there is no evidence of crowding-out of natives by the immigrants.

References

  • Aloy M, Gente K (2009) The role of demography in the long-run Yen/USD real exchange rate appreciation. J Macroecon 31(4):654–667

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amisano G, Giannini C (1997) Topics in structural VAR econometrics, 2nd edn. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Amuedo-Dorantes C (2014) The good and the bad in remittance flows. IZA World Labor 97:1–10

    Google Scholar 

  • Asharaf AS, Mouselhy MA (2013) Ageing in Saudi Arabia: impact of demographic transition. Bold Q J Int Inst Ageing 24(1):13–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Altayligil YB, Çetrez M (2020) Macroeconomic, institutional and financial determinants of current account balances: a panel data assessment. J Econ Struct 9(49):1–23. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40008-020-00225-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai J, Perron P (1998) Estimating and testing linear models with multiple structural changes. Econometrica 66:47–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ, Giavazzi F (2002) Current account deficits in the euro area: the end of the Feldstein–Horioka puzzle? Brook Pap Econ Act 33(2):147–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas GJ (2019) Immigration and economic growth. NBER working paper no. 25836.

  • Boubtane E, Ch DJ, Rault Ch (2016) Immigration and economic growth in the OECD countries, 1986–2006. Oxf Econ Pap 68(2):340–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boubtane E, Coulibaly D, Rault Ch (2013) Immigration, growth, and unemployment: panel VAR evidence from OECD countries. Labour 27(4):399–420

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonham C, Wiemer C (2013) Chinese savings dynamics: the impact of GDP growth and the dependent share. Oxf Econ Pap 65:173–196. Demogr Res 29(23):617–640

  • Bracke T, Fidora M (2008) Global liquidity glut or global savings glut? Working paper series. European Central Bank, pp 1–29. https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/scpwps/ecbwp911.pdf

  • Breitung J, Brüggemann R, Lütkepohl H (2004) Structural vector autoregressive modelling. Chapter 4. In: Lütkepohl H, Kratzig M (eds) Applied time series econometrics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Brooks R (2000) Population aging and global capital flows in a parallel universe. In: IMF working paper 151, International Monetary Fund

  • Brown MB, Forsythe AB (1974) Robust tests for the equality of variances. J Am Stat Assoc 69(346):364–367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castles S, Miller MJ (2009) The age of migration: international population movements in the modern world, 4th edn. Palgrave MacMillan, Basingstoke

    Google Scholar 

  • Cerrato M, Kalyoncu H, Naqvi NH, Tsoukis Ch (2015) Current accounts in the long run and the intertemporal approach: a panel data investigation. World Econ J 38(2):340–359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper RN (2008) Global imbalances: globalization, demography, and sustainability. J Econ Perspect 22(3):93–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Das DK (2016) Determinants of current account imbalance in the global economy: a dynamic panel analysis. J Econ Struct 5(8):1–24. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40008-016-0039-6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dustmann C, Fabbri F, Preston I (2005) The impact of immigration on the British labour market. Econ J 115:324–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dynan EK, Edelberg W, Palumbo MG (2009) The effects of population aging on the relationship between aggregate consumption, saving, and income. Am Econ Rev 99(2):380–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enders W (2004) Applied econometric time series. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Engle RF, Granger CWJ (eds) (1991) Long run economic relations: readings in cointegration. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Engle RF, Granger CWJ (1987) Co-integration and error correction: representation, estimation and testing. Econometrica 55:251–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fair RC, Dominguez KM (1991) Effects of the changing U.S. age distribution on macroeconomic equations. Am Econ Rev 81:1276–1294

    Google Scholar 

  • Feroli M (2006) Demography and the U.S. current account deficit. The North American. J Econ Finance 17(1):1–16

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghassan H, Drissi R (2019) Intertemporal modelling of the current account. Turk Econ Rev 6(3):185–199

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (2012) Econometric analysis 7th International Edition. Pearson Education Limited

  • Gregory AW, Nason JM, Watt DG (1996) Testing for structural breaks in cointegrated relationships. J Economet 71:321–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman JB (1982) The substitutability of natives and immigrants in production. Rev Econ Stat 64:596–603

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gudmundsson GS, Zoega G (2014) Age structure and the current account. Econ Lett 123(2):183–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Habib MM, Kalamova MM (2007) Are there oil currencies? The real exchange rate of oil exporting countries. In: European Central Bank working paper series 839, December

  • Hansen BE (1990) A powerful, simple test for cointegration using cochrane-Orcutt. Rochester Center for Economic Research, Working Paper #230:1–36.

  • Hansen BE (1992) Tests for parameter instability in regressions with I(1) processes. J Bus Econ Stat 10:321–335

    Google Scholar 

  • Hasanov FJ (2019) Theoretical framework for industrial electricity consumption revisited: empirical analysis and projections for Saudi Arabia. Discussion Paper 66. King Abdullah Petroleum Studies and Research Center (KAPSARC) Riyadh, Saudi Arabia.

  • Hassan AFM, Salim R, Bloch H (2011) Population age structure, saving, capital flows and the real exchange rate: a survey of the literature. J Econ Surv 25(4):708–736

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Higgins M (1998) Demography, national savings and international capital flows. Econ Rev 39(2):343–369

    Google Scholar 

  • Hobijn B, Franses PH, Ooms M (2004) Generalizations of the KPSS-test for stationarity. Stat Neerl 58:483–502

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hondroyiannis G, Papapetrou E (2005) Fertility and output in Europe: new evidence from panel cointegration analysis. J Policy Model 27(2):143–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hondroyiannis G, Papapetrou E (2004) Demographic changes and economic activity in Greece. Rev Econ Household 2(1):49–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hondroyiannis G, Papapetrou E (2002) Demographic transition and economic growth: empirical evidence from Greece. J Popul Econ 15(2):221–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karras G (2009) Demographic change and the current account: theory and empirical evidence. J Econ Asymmetries 6(1):1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiefer NM, Vogelsang TJ (2005) A new asymptotic theory for heteroskedasticity-autocorrelation robust tests. Economet Theor 21(06):1130–1164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilian L (2013) Structural vector autoregressions. In: Handbook of Research Methods and Applications in Empirical Macroeconomics. Hashimzade N. and MA. Thornton (Eds.), Edward Elgar.

  • Kim S, Lee JW (2008) Demographic changes, saving, and current account: an analysis based on a panel VAR. Jpn World Econ 20(2):236–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kwiatkowski D, Phillips P, Schmidt P, Shin Y (1992) Testing the null hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of a unit root. J Econom 54:159–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li H, Zhang J, Zhang J (2007) Effects of longevity and dependency rates on saving and growth: evidence from a panel of cross countries. J Dev Econ 84(1):138–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucchetti R (2006) Identification of covariance structures. Economet Theor 22(2):235–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lütkepohl H (2007) New introduction to multiple time series analysis, 2nd edn. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Marchiori L (2011) Demographic trends and international capital flows in an integrated world. Econ Model 28(5):2100–2120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKinsey Global Institute MGI (2015) Saudi Arabia beyond oil: investment and productivity transformation. Employment and Growth Report, December

  • Narayan S, Sriananthakumar S (2020) Are the current account imbalances on a sustainable path? J Risk Financ Manag 13(9):201. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm13090201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Narayan PK (2005) The saving and investment nexus for china: evidence from cointegration tests. Appl Econ 37(17):1979–1990

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naufal G, Genc I (2012) Remittance outflows. In: Expats and the labor force. The economics of the Middle East. Palgrave Macmillan, New York, pp 77–95. https://doi.org/10.1057/9781137117854_5

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ogaki M (1993) Unit roots in macroeconometrics: a survey. Bank of Japan’s Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies (IMES). Monet Econ Stud 11:131–154

    Google Scholar 

  • Ortega F, Peri G (2009) The causes and effects of international migrations: evidence from OECD Countries 1980–2005. In NBER working paper no. 14833

  • Park JY (1992) Canonical cointegrating regressions. Econometrica 60:119–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peri G (2016) Immigrants, productivity and labor markets. J Econ Perspect 30(4):3–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran MH, Shin Y, Smith RJ (2001) Bounds testing approaches to the analysis of level relationships. J Appl Economet 16(3):289–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peterson EWF (2017) The role of population in economic growth. Sage Open J. https://doi.org/10.1177/2158244017736094

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Philips AQ (2018) Have your cake and eat it too? Cointegration and dynamic inference from autoregressive distributed lag models. Am J Polit Sci 62(1):230–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phillips PCB, Hansen BE (1990) Statistical inference in instrumental variables regression with I(1) processes. Rev Econ Stud 57:99–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prskawetz A, Kogel T, Sanderson WC, Scherbov S (2004) The effects of age structure on economic growth: an application of probabilistic forecasting to India. In: Working paper 03, Vienna Institute of Demography

  • Sachs JD (1982) Aspects of the current account behavior of OECD economies. In: NBER working papers 859. https://doi.org/10.3386/w0859

  • Sachs JD, Cooper RN, Fischer S (1981) The current account and macroeconomic adjustment in the 1970s. Brook Pap Econ Act 1:201–282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon C, Belyakov AO, Feichtinger G (2012) Minimizing the dependency ratio in a population with below replacement fertility through immigration. Theor Popul Biol 82(3):158–169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sims CA (1980) Macroeconomics and reality. Econometrica 48:1–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sims CA (1977) Macro-economics and reality. Center for economic research. In: Discussion Paper 77–91, December:1–77

  • Stock JH, Watson MW (2001) Vector auto-regressions. J Econ Perspect 15(4):101–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Watson MW (1996) Evidence on structural instability in macroeconomic time series relations. J Bus Econ Stat 14(1):11–30

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor AM (1995) Debt, dependence, and the demographic transition: Latin America into the next century. World Dev 23(5):869–879

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor AM, Williamson J (1994) Capital flows to the new world as an intergenerational transfer. J Polit Econ 102(2):348–371

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank Group (2016) Migration and remittances, fact book 2016, 3rd ed. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/23743/9781464803192.pdf

  • Eric Z, Andrews DWK (2002) Further evidence on the great crash, the oil-price shock, and the unit-root hypothesis. J Bus Econ Stat 20(1):25–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank the Deanship of Scientific Research of King Faisal University for granting this research paper under the number 170034. The authors thank the two anonymous referee.

Funding

This study was funded by Deanship of Scientific Research of King Faisal University (Grant Number 170034).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hassan B. Ghassan.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

Author A (Hassan Ghassan) declares that there is no conflict of interest. Author B (Hassan AlHajhoj) declares that there is no conflict of interest. Author C (Faruk Balli) declares that there is no conflict of interest.

Ethical approval

This requirement is not applicable for our research paper. (And/or in case humans were involved) Ethical approval: This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1

See Tables 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12.

Table 2 Correlation: CA-to-GDP and age population sharing from 1974 to 2016
Table 3 Descriptive statistics with 42 observations (1974–2016)
Table 4 KPSS stationarity tests
Table 5 Zivot–Andrews (ZA) unit root tests
Table 6 Bounds test for cointegration with break points (k = 3)
Table 7 Narayan critical values (k = 3, n = 45)
Table 8 Diagnostic tests
Table 9 VAR lag-order selection criteria
Table 10 VAR residual serial correlation LM tests
Table 11 Residual variance–covariance matrix
Table 12 Residual correlation matrix

Notes on ARDL Bound test

The ARDL approach introduced and revised by Pesaran et al. (2001) is mostly used in empirical research when the regressors have a different order of integration or are all I(1) or all I(0). The ARDL bound model is based on the conditional error correction (CEC) model, which is formulated as follows (PSS 2001):

$$\Delta y_{t} = a_{0} + a_{1} t + a_{2} D_{t} + b_{0} y_{{t - 1}} + \sum\limits_{{i = 1}}^{k} {b_{i} } x_{{i,t - 1}} + {\text{ }}\sum\limits_{{i = 1}}^{{p - 1}} {\psi _{i}^{\prime } } \Delta z_{{t - i}} + \omega ^{\prime } \Delta x_{t} + u_{t}$$

where \(y_{t}\) is a random scalar process that is conditionally modeled given the k-vector of random variables \(x_{t}\) and the past values \(z_{t - i} = \left( {y_{t - 1} ,{ }x_{t - i}^{^{\prime}} } \right)^{^{\prime}}\), and \(u_{t}\) is the error term. The deterministic components are the intercept and the trend \(t\), which are associated to a drift parameter \(a_{0}\) and a time trend parameter \(a_{1}\), respectively. When the deterministic components contribute to the error correction term, they are implicitly projected onto the span of the cointegrating vector, implying that \(a_{0}\) and \(a_{1}\) in the CEC model must be restricted.

Narayan (2005) does not consider the critical value (CV) bounds of the t Statistic for the cases 1, 3 and 5. For the case 5, PSS (2001) provide that at 5% of significance, the lower stationary bound and the upper bound are − 3.410 and − 4.160, respectively; and at 1% of significance − 3.960 and − 4.730, respectively. If the computed F-Statistic is higher than the upper bound of CV, then the null of no cointegration is rejected. The lower bound is based on the assumption that all of the variables are I(0), while the upper bound that all of the variables are I(1).

Appendix 2

Figures 4, 5, 6, 7, and 8.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ghassan, H.B., Alhajhoj, H.R. & Balli, F. Bi-demographic and current account dynamics using SVAR model: evidence from Saudi Arabia. Econ Change Restruct 55, 1327–1363 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-021-09348-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-021-09348-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation