Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Terms of trade volatility, exports, and GDP

  • Published:
Economic Change and Restructuring Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper relates terms of trade volatility to exports and output in a two-sector model where entrepreneurs can produce non-tradable goods or pay a fixed cost in order to export. In order to compensate exporters for the fixed entry cost, the expected return to exporting must exceed the expected return to non-tradable production. As a result, exporters are more risk-exposed and trade volatility decreases entry into the export sector. However, terms of trade insurance and hedging strategies can increase exports, GDP, and welfare.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Berman and Héricourt (2010) find that access to finance is an important determinant of the decision to export in a sample of 5000 developing country and emerging market firms. The effect is concentrated at the time of export initiation, and more productive firms without liquidity are no more likely to initiate exports. The authors conclude that the evidence supports the idea of fixed export costs. Roberts and Tybout (1997) find evidence that Colombian manufacturing plants incur fixed export costs. Partly, currency deprecations and appreciations appear to have asymmetric effects on export participation and partly (p. 550): “[The survey evidence shows that…] to sell in developed-country markets, Colombian producers were often required to invest in product quality upgrading. Second, there was little exporting infrastructure in the form of trading companies or distribution agents. These companies typically provide transportation, customs, and shipping services, as well as information on prices, potential buyers, and product standards or requirements in other countries.”

  2. If the insurance is contingent on the observable international terms of trade, which, by assumption, neither the government nor exporters cannot manipulate, insurance provision should not generate any moral hazard.

  3. In the present paper, technically, since we assume that relative export prices are determined on the world market, we also assume that government cannot influence the terms of trade.

References

  • Agénor PR, Montiel PJ (1999) Development macroeconomics, 2nd edn. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Bacchetta P, Ranciere R, Rogoff K (2009) Exchange rate volatility and productivity growth: the role of financial development. J Monetary Econ 56(4):494–513

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aizenman J, Riera-Crichton D (2008) Real exchange rate and international reserves in an era of growing financial and trade integration. Rev Econ Stat 90(4):812–815

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bahmani-Oskooee M, Hegerty SW, Hosny AS (2015) The effects of exchange-rate volatility on industry trade between the US and Egypt. Econ Change Restruct 48(2):93–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basu P, Gavin WT (2010) What explains the growth in commodity derivatives? Fed Reserve Bank St 93(1):37–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Berman N, Héricourt J (2010) Financial factors and the margins of trade: evidence from cross-country firm-level data. J Dev Econ 93(2):206–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blattman C, Hwang J, Williamson JG (2007) Winners and losers in the commodity lottery: the impact of terms of trade growth and volatility in the periphery 1870–1939. J Dev Econ 82(1):156–179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bleaney MF, Greenaway D (2001) The Impact of terms of trade and real exchange rate volatility on investment and growth in sub-Saharan Africa. J Dev Econ 65(2):491–500

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broda C (2004) Terms of trade and exchange rate regimes in developing countries. J Int Econ 63(1):31–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Combes JL, Renard MF, Tapsoba SJA (2019) Provincial public expenditure in China: a tale of pro-cyclicality. Econ Change Restruct 52(1):19–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A (1999) Commodity prices and growth in Africa. J Econ Perspect 13(3):23–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Devereux MB, Lane PL, Xu J (2006) Exchange rates and monetary policy in emerging market economies. Econ J 116(511):478–506

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dufrénot G, Ospanova A, Sand-Zantman A (2014) A small macro econometric model for Kazakhstan: a retrospective of alternative economic policies undertaken during the transition process. Econ Change Restruct 47(1):1–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards S, Levy-Yeyati E (2005) Flexible exchange rates as shock absorbers. Eur Econ Rev 49(8):2079–2105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fielding D, Lee K, Shields K (2012) Does one size fit all? Modelling macroeconomic linkages in the West African Economic and Monetary Union. Econ Change Restruct 45(1–2):45–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel J (2017) How to cope with volatile commodity export prices: four proposals. In: Arezki R, Boucekkine R (eds) Natural resources, finance and diversification: diagnostics and policies. E-book, World Bank, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel JA, Vegh CA, Vuletin G (2013) On graduation from fiscal procyclicality. J Dev Econ 100(1):32–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann R, Rodrik D (2003) Economic development as self-discovery. J Dev Econ 72(2):603–633

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Task Force (2008) The international task force on commodity risk management in developing countries: activities, findings and the way forward. World Bank, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Kose MA (2002) Explaining business cycles in small open economies: How much do world prices matter? J Int Econ 56(2):299–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuusk A, Staehr K, Varblane U (2017) Sectoral change and labour productivity growth during boom, bust and recovery in Central and Eastern Europe. Econ Change Restruct 50(1):21–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz MJ (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6):1695–1725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz MJ, Ottaviano GI (2008) Market size, trade, and productivity. Rev Econ Stud 75(1):295–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendoza EG (1995) The terms of trade, the real exchange rate, and economic fluctuations. Int Econ Rev 36(1):101–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendoza EG (1997) Terms-of-trade uncertainty and economic growth. J Dev Econ 54(2):323–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moschini G, Hennessy DA (2001) Uncertainty, risk aversion, and risk management for agricultural producers. In: Gardner B, Rausser G (eds) Handbook of agricultural economics 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 87–153

    Google Scholar 

  • Nusair SA, Al-Khasawneh JA (2018) Oil price shocks and stock market returns of the GCC countries: empirical evidence from quantile regression analysis. Econ Change Restruct 51(4):339–372

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Page S, Hewitt A (2001) World commodity prices: still a problem for developing countries?. Overseas Development Institute, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Papapetrou E (2013) Oil prices and economic activity in Greece. Econ Change Restruct 46(4):385–397

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts MJ, Tybout JR (1997) The decision to export in Colombia: an empirical model of entry with sunk costs. Am Econ Rev 87(4):545–564

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD (2017) The state of commodity dependence 2016. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Varangis, P, Larson D (1996) Dealing with commodity price uncertainty. In: World Bank policy research working paper 1667. Washington, DC, World Bank

  • Vivarelli M (2016) The middle income trap: a way out based on technological and structural change. Econ Change Restruct 49(2–3):159–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zmami M, Ben-Salha O (2015) Exchange rate movements and manufacturing employment in Tunisia: Do different categories of firms react similarly? Econ Change Restruct 48(2):137–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thorsten Janus.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

I am very grateful to the two anonymous referees for a series of helpful comments.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Proposition 2

  1. (i)

    When \(f = 0\), (14) implies that \(\delta = 1 - \beta\). Thus, the labor force share of the tradable sector (\(\delta\)) is constant and independent of terms of trade volatility. Since \(\delta\) is in independent of terms of trade volatility, (9) implies that \(\partial E(G)/\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }} = 0\). On the other hand, since (10) is concave, in the terms of trade, \(\partial^{2} \hat{G}/\partial p_{x}^{2} < 0\), we have \(\partial E(\hat{G})/\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} < 0\). Since \(\delta\) is constant, (11) implies that \(\partial E(W)/\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} = K\partial E(\hat{G})/\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} < 0\).

  2. (ii)

    Using (14), define

    $$H(\delta (\sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} ),\sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} ) \equiv \left\{ {\left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }} \right)^{ - \beta } - \left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }} \right)^{1 - \beta } } \right\}E\left( {p_{x}^{1 - \beta } } \right) - f/K = 0.$$

    Then, the implicit function implies that

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \delta }{{\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} }} = \frac{{ - \partial H/\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} }}{\partial H/\partial \delta } & = \frac{{ - \left\{ {\left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }} \right)^{ - \beta } - \left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }} \right)^{1 - \beta } } \right\}\partial E(p_{x}^{1 - \beta } )/\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} }}{{ - \frac{\beta }{{\delta (1 - \delta )^{2} }}\left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }} \right)^{ - \beta } E(p_{x}^{1 - \beta } )}} \\ & = \frac{{\left\{ {1 - \frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }} \right\}\partial E(p_{x}^{1 - \beta } )/\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} }}{{\frac{\beta }{{\delta (1 - \delta )^{2} }}E(p_{x}^{1 - \beta } )}} = \frac{{\left\{ {\frac{1 - \delta - \beta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }} \right\}\overbrace {{\partial E(p_{x}^{1 - \beta } )/\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} }}^{ < 0}}}{{\frac{\beta }{{\delta (1 - \delta )^{2} }}E(p_{x}^{1 - \beta } )}} < 0. \\ \end{aligned}$$
    (15)

Terms of trade volatility therefore decreases the labor force share of the tradable sector. The decline in tradable production decreases GDP in (9) and (10) since

$$\frac{\partial EG}{{\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} }} = \overbrace {{\frac{{\partial \delta /\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} }}{1 - \beta }}}^{ < 0}E(p_{x} ) < 0.$$
(16)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\partial E(\hat{G})}}{{\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} }} & = \frac{\partial }{{\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} }}E\left( {\frac{{\delta^{1 - \beta } (1 - \delta )^{\beta } }}{{(1 - \beta )^{1 - \beta } \beta^{\beta } }}p_{x}^{1 - \beta } } \right) \\ & = \left( {\frac{{\delta^{1 - \beta } (1 - \delta )^{\beta } }}{{(1 - \beta )^{1 - \beta } \beta^{\beta } }}} \right)\overbrace {{\frac{{\partial E(p_{x}^{1 - \beta } )}}{{\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} }}}}^{ < 0} + \frac{1}{{(1 - \beta )^{1 - \beta } \beta^{\beta } }}\frac{{\partial \left( {\delta^{1 - \beta } (1 - \delta )^{\beta } } \right)}}{\partial \delta }\overbrace {{\frac{\partial \delta }{{\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{2} }}}}^{ < 0}E\left( {p_{x}^{1 - \beta } } \right) < 0 \\ & \Leftarrow \, \frac{{\partial \left( {\delta^{1 - \beta } (1 - \delta )^{\beta } } \right)}}{\partial \delta } < 0 \Leftrightarrow (1 - \beta )\delta^{ - \beta } (1 - \delta )^{\beta } + \delta^{1 - \beta } \beta (1 - \delta )^{\beta - 1} > 0 \Leftrightarrow 1 - \delta > \beta { ,} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(17)

(where \(\Leftarrow\) denotes a sufficient condition).In order to show that terms of trade volatility decreases welfare, we differentiate (11),\(W = \delta u_{x} + (1 - \delta )u_{n} - \delta f = K\hat{G} - \delta f\),giving

$$\frac{dE(W)}{{d\sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{{}} }} = \left[ {\frac{\partial E(W)}{{\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{{}} }}} \right] + \left[ {\frac{\partial E(W)}{\partial \delta }\frac{\partial \delta }{{\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{{}} }}} \right]$$
(18)
$$= \left[ {\delta \frac{{\partial E(u_{x} )}}{{\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{{}} }} + (1 - \delta )\frac{{\partial E(u_{n} )}}{{\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{{}} }}} \right] + \left[ {\frac{\partial }{\partial \delta }\left( {\delta E(u_{x} ) + (1 - \delta )E(u_{n} ) - \delta f} \right)} \right]\overbrace {{\frac{\partial \delta }{{\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{{}} }}}}^{ < 0} ,$$
(19)

where Proposition 2(ii) implies that \(\partial \delta /\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{{}} < 0\). The first bracketed expression in (19) is the welfare effect of increasing income volatility conditional on the allocation of labor across sectors. The second bracketed expression is the welfare effect of labor reallocation.

If we only consider a marginal volatility increase starting from the equilibrium labor allocation in (13), however, the second brackets are zero: Although the market cannot eliminate the terms of trade risk, the labor allocation has already adapted to the risk. Formally,

$$\frac{\partial }{\partial \delta }\left( {\delta E(u_{x} ) + (1 - \delta )E(u_{n} ) - \delta f} \right) = \underbrace {{\left[ {E(u_{x} ) - E(u_{n} ) - f} \right]}}_{ = 0} + \left[ {\delta \frac{{\partial E(u_{x} )}}{\partial \delta } + (1 - \delta )\frac{{\partial E(u_{n} )}}{\partial \delta }} \right] = 0,$$
(20)

where the equality follows because

  1. (i)

    Eq. (13) implies that the first brackets are zero.

  2. (ii)

    Substituting the utility expressions in (14) into the second brackets shows that

$$\delta \frac{{\partial E(u_{x} )}}{\partial \delta } + (1 - \delta )\frac{{\partial E(u_{n} )}}{\partial \delta } = 0,$$
(21)
$$\Leftrightarrow \left\{ {\delta \frac{\partial }{\partial \delta }\left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }} \right)^{ - \beta } + (1 - \delta )\frac{\partial }{\partial \delta }\left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }} \right)^{1 - \beta } } \right\}KE\left( {p_{x}^{1 - \beta } } \right) = 0,$$
$$\Leftrightarrow \left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }} \right)^{ - \beta } \frac{(1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta )\beta + \beta \delta (1 - \beta )}{{(1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta )^{2} }}\left\{ { - \delta \beta \left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }} \right)^{ - 1} + (1 - \delta )(1 - \beta )} \right\} = 0,$$
$$\Leftrightarrow - \delta \beta \left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }} \right)^{ - 1} + (1 - \delta )(1 - \beta ) = 0 \Leftrightarrow - (1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta ) + (1 - \delta )(1 - \beta ) = 0,$$
$$\Leftrightarrow (1 - \delta )(1 - \beta ) = (1 - \delta )(1 - \beta ).$$

The welfare effect (19) therefore simplifies to

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dE(W)}{{d\sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{{}} }} & = \left[ {\delta \frac{{\partial E(u_{x} )}}{{\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{{}} }} + (1 - \delta )\frac{{\partial E(u_{n} )}}{{\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{{}} }}} \right] \\ & = K\left[ {\delta \left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }} \right)^{ - \beta } + (1 - \delta )\left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }} \right)^{1 - \beta } } \right]\underbrace {{\frac{{\partial E(p_{x}^{1 - \beta } )}}{{\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{{}} }}}}_{ < 0} < 0, \\ \end{aligned}$$

where \(\frac{{\partial E(p_{x}^{1 - \beta } )}}{{\partial \sigma_{{p_{x} }}^{{}} }} < 0\) by Jensen’s inequality. □

1.2 The welfare effects of exchange rate management and entry subsidies

In this section, we show that the nominal exchange rate does not have any real effects in the model and that entry subsidies cannot increase welfare holding terms of trade volatility constant.

The effects of the nominal exchange rate We can choose the units so the price of the import good is the price of a foreign currency unit. Then, the domestic currency price of the export good is \(p_{x}^{d} = p_{x} /e,\) where \(e\) is the nominal exchange rate (foreign currency per unit of domestic currency). Domestic currency GDP is

$$G^{d} = \delta p_{x}^{d} + (1 - \delta )p_{n}^{d} .$$

where the domestic currency price of non-tradables solves

$$1 - \delta = \beta G^{d} /p_{n}^{d} \Leftrightarrow ,$$
$$p_{n}^{d} = \frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }p_{x}^{d} = \frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }p_{x} /e.$$

The price level in domestic currency is \(P^{d} = (p_{n}^{d} )^{\beta } (1/e)^{1 - \beta } = \left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }p_{x}^{d} } \right)^{\beta } (1/e)^{1 - \beta }\)since an imported good costs \(1/e\) domestic currency units.

In terms of foreign currency or, equivalently, imported goods, however, for each \(\delta\), all of the variable values remain the same as in Eqs. (710) in the paper:

$$G = eG^{d} = \delta p_{x} + (1 - \delta )\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }p_{x} = \delta p_{x} + (1 - \delta )\frac{\beta \delta }{(1 - \delta )(1 - \beta )}p_{x} = \frac{\delta }{1 - \beta }p_{x} ,$$
$$p_{n} = ep_{n}^{d} = \frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }p_{x} ,$$
$$P = eP^{d} = \left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }p_{x} } \right)^{\beta } ,$$
$$\hat{G} = G^{d} /P^{d} = \frac{{\frac{\delta }{1 - \beta }ep_{x}^{d} }}{{\left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{1 - \delta - \beta + \beta \delta }p_{x}^{d} } \right)^{\beta } (1/e)^{1 - \beta } }} = \frac{{\delta^{1 - \beta } (1 - \delta )^{\beta } }}{{(1 - \beta )^{1 - \beta } \beta^{\beta } }}(ep_{x}^{d} )^{1 - \beta } = \frac{{\delta^{1 - \beta } (1 - \delta )^{\beta } }}{{(1 - \beta )^{1 - \beta } \beta^{\beta } }}p_{x}^{1 - \beta } = G/P.$$

Agent incomes in terms of the import good remain \(I_{x} = p_{x}\) and \(I_{n} = p_{n}\). Finally, the labor allocation \(\delta\) is the same since the utility expressions are unchanged from (12):

$$u_{j} = (\beta I_{j}^{d} /p_{n}^{d} )^{\beta } ((1 - \beta )I_{j}^{d} /e)^{1 - \beta } = (\beta eI_{j} /ep_{n} )^{\beta } ((1 - \beta )eI_{j} /e)^{1 - \beta } ,$$
$$= (\beta I_{j} /p_{n} )^{\beta } ((1 - \beta )I_{j} )^{1 - \beta } = KI_{j} /P,$$

and the income (\(I_{j}\), \(j = x,n\)), and price levels (\(P\)) remain unchanged.

The effects of entry subsidies Assume that the government can pay an entry subsidy \(s\) using reserves or lump-sum taxes. Rewriting Eq. (14), which defines the labor allocation, as

$$J(\delta (s),s) = K\left\{ {\left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{(1 - \delta )(1 - \beta )}} \right)^{ - \beta } - \left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{(1 - \delta )(1 - \beta )}} \right)^{1 - \beta } } \right\}E\left( {p_{x}^{1 - \beta } } \right) - (f - s) = 0,$$

the implicit function theorem implies that

$$\frac{\partial \delta }{\partial s} = - \frac{\partial J/\partial f}{\partial J/\partial \delta } = - \frac{1}{\partial J/\partial \delta } > 0$$

so entry increases. The welfare expression is unchanged from (11) in the main paper because the government pays the subsidy cost, that is,

$$W = \delta E(u_{x} ) + (1 - \delta )E(u_{n} ) - \delta (f - s) - \delta s = \delta E(u_{x} ) + (1 - \delta )E(u_{n} ) - \delta f.$$

The welfare effect of a marginal subsidy is

$$\frac{dE(W)}{df} = \frac{\partial E(W)}{\partial \delta }\frac{\partial \delta }{\partial s} = \left[ {\frac{\partial }{\partial \delta }\left( {\delta E(u_{x} ) + (1 - \delta )E(u_{n} ) - \delta f} \right)} \right]\overbrace {{\frac{\partial \delta }{\partial s}}}^{ > 0}.$$

However, equation (20) shows that, starting from the market equilibrium, the bracketed term is zero. More generally, given any fixed labor allocation \(\delta\)

$$\frac{dE(W)}{df} = \frac{\partial E(W)}{\partial \delta }\frac{\partial \delta }{\partial s} = \frac{\partial }{\partial \delta }\left( {\delta E(u_{x} ) + (1 - \delta )E(u_{n} ) - \delta f} \right),$$
$$= \left[ {E(u_{x} ) - E(u_{n} ) - f} \right] + \underbrace {{\left[ {\delta \frac{{\partial E(u_{x} )}}{\partial \delta } + (1 - \delta )\frac{{\partial E(u_{n} )}}{\partial \delta }} \right]}}_{ = 0},$$

where (21) shows that the second brackets are zero. The first brackets are not zero outside of the market equilibrium (13). However, substituting (14) into the first brackets shows that

$$E(u_{x} ) - E(u_{n} ) - f = K\left\{ {\left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{(1 - \delta )(1 - \beta )}} \right)^{ - \beta } - \left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{(1 - \delta )(1 - \beta )}} \right)^{1 - \beta } } \right\}E\left( {p_{x}^{1 - \beta } } \right) - f.$$

This expression—the marginal welfare gain from labor reallocation—is strictly decreasing in \(\delta\) since \(\frac{\partial }{\partial \delta }\left\{ {\left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{(1 - \delta )(1 - \beta )}} \right)^{ - \beta } - \left( {\frac{\beta \delta }{(1 - \delta )(1 - \beta )}} \right)^{1 - \beta } } \right\}KE\left( {p_{x}^{1 - \beta } } \right) < 0\). It equals zero in the market equilibrium allocation defined by (14). Thus, increasing \(\delta\) to any point exceeding its equilibrium value decreases welfare.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Janus, T. Terms of trade volatility, exports, and GDP. Econ Change Restruct 53, 25–38 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-019-09247-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-019-09247-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation