Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

How Corporate–NGO Partnerships Affect Eco-Label Adoption and Diffusion

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In a proposed multistage game, a firm and an environmental nongovernmental organization (NGO) initially partner to develop an eco-label, to attain both the environmental benefits and profits. The partnership enables a compromise, and the partner firm, as well as other competitors in the market, subsequently decide whether to adopt the eco-label. Finally, the firms compete on price or quantity in a homogeneous or vertically differentiated market. By analyzing firms’ incentives to adopt the eco-label, this study predicts outcomes related to the eco-labeling strategies of the NGO and the corporate partner, the diffusion of the eco-label, environmental quality, and welfare, depending on both the nature of the competition (Bertrand or Cournot) and the degree of consumer heterogeneity. The results of the game show that it is always in the interest of the environmental NGO and the firm to form a partnership. The corporate partner’s incentive to adopt the eco-label is stronger in Bertrand than in Cournot competition, but diffusion occurs only with Cournot competition. Paradoxically, the NGO may prefer a less stringent eco-label, to promote its diffusion and the consumption of eco-labeled products. Whereas in Cournot competition, eco-labeling improves all components of welfare, in Bertrand competition, it degrades consumer surplus, even if it improves overall profits and environmental quality.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The GFTN encouraged the use of Forest Stewardship Council-certified products in the supply chain maintained by corporations that partner with WWF; the Forests Forward platform took over from the GFTN in 2021. See https://forestsforward.panda.org/ (accessed 2022/01/24).

  2. See “Sustainable Seafood: The First 20 years. A History of the Marine Stewardship Council,” http://20-years.msc.org/ (accessed 2018/04/19). See also (Wijen and Chiroleu-Assouline 2019) for a socio-economic analysis of the MSC.

  3. (Poret 2019a) offers other examples of corporate–NGO eco-labeling partnerships, such as those between the Rainforest Alliance and Unilever’s tea brand Lipton or the Fair Trade Sourcing Partnership proposed by Fairtrade International to chocolatiers.

  4. A WWF’s webpage, previously entitled “Harnessing forces for conservation,” has been renamed “Changing the Nature of Business.” See https://www.worldwildlife.org/business (accessed 2022/01/24).

  5. Other forms of NGO partnerships also have been investigated. Heyes and Oestreich (2018) consider how a regulator-NGO partnership might impose social pressure on a firm to comply with a standard. Baron et al. (2016) examine a corporate–NGO partnership that results from a bidding game between two firms to be selected by a cooperative activist, such that the non-selected firm would be subject to a negative campaign by a confrontational activist. They focus on the interactions of cooperative and confrontational activists, due to the favoritism of activists toward one firm and a radical flank effect (i.e., positive effect that the presence of a radical NGO has on firms’ perceptions of moderate NGOs).

  6. As Kreps and Scheinkman (1983) show, in industries in which firms choose their production capacities and then set prices, it is appropriate to suppose that firms compete on quantity; in industries in which capacity constraints and production can be quickly adjusted, it is more relevant to anticipate that firms compete on prices. However, empirical literature rarely identifies the nature of competition in different industries (Sutton 2007).

  7. A dynamic version of the model could be developed using the new product adoption and diffusion literature (Fudenberg and Tirole 1985; Bonanno and Haworth 1998; Galasso and Tombak 2014), which would make it possible to analyze the timing of adoption, reflecting firms’ objective to maximize the present value of their profit flows.

  8. The proofs for this section are provided in "Appendix 1"

  9. Without a prior commitment to adopt the eco-label as part of the partnership, the non-deviation condition for the leader would be \(\pi _L^{B1}(q_g)>\pi _F^{B1}(q_g)\). Its adoption of the eco-label would require \(q_b<2{\overline{\theta }}/3\) and \(q_g<\big ( 4{\overline{\theta }}-q_b-\sqrt{(8{\overline{\theta }}-3q_b)q_b} \big ) /2\).

  10. Fig. 1 depicts parameters \({\overline{\theta }}=3\) and \(q_b=1\) such that the assumption \(q_b<{\overline{\theta }}\) is verified.

  11. The proofs for this section are provided in Appendices 2 and 3.

  12. In detail, Motta (1993) shows that, when qualities (denoted \(q_h>q_l\)) are perfectly known to consumers, firms have an interest in producing differentiated qualities: If \({\overline{\theta }}=3\), the equilibrium qualities are \(q_l^*=1.196\) and \(q_h^*=2.459\) in the case of Bertrand competition, and \(q_l^*=1.757\) and \(q_h^*=2.214\) in the case of Cournot competition.

  13. The analytical expression of \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF}\) cannot be given, but in "Appendix 2", we prove the existence and uniqueness of \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF}\) in \([q_b,2{\overline{\theta }}]\).

  14. Since \({\overline{q}}_g^{CL} \ge {\overline{q}}_g^{CF}\), \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF} \ge q_b\) if \(q_b \ge 10{\overline{\theta }}/17\), and \({\overline{q}}_g^{CL} \ge q_b\) if \(q_b \ge 14{\overline{\theta }}/19\), conditions (i.b) and (ii.a) of Proposition 2 can be expressed as \(q_g \in [\max (q_b, {\overline{q}}_g^{CF}),{\overline{q}}_g^{CL}]\); conditions (i.c), (ii.b) and (iii) can be formalized as condition \(q_g > \max (q_b, {\overline{q}}_g^{CL})\), under which no firm has an interest in adopting the eco-label. See Fig. 2 for a plot of \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF}\) and \({\overline{q}}_g^{CL}\) as a function of \(q_b\).

  15. The proofs for this section are provided in "Appendix 4".

  16. See "Appendix 5" for a presentation of the Nash bargaining model and the leader’s take-it-or-leave-it eco-label.

  17. Indices of bargaining power reflect the strengths that each partner can bring to the table to increase the weight allocated to its interests. According to Glasbergen (2012), the bargaining power of firms derives from “material forces” that allow for influence and action, whereas the bargaining power of NGOs derives from “collective group membership and a high degree of societal trust.”

  18. \(\pi _L^{B1}>\pi _L^{B0}\) is always fulfilled when \(E^{B1}>E^{B0}\) because \({\overline{q}}_g^{BL}\equiv \frac{4\theta -q_b}{2}>{\overline{q}}_g^{BN}\equiv \frac{2{\overline{\theta }}-q_b+\sqrt{(2{\overline{\theta }}-q_b)(2{\overline{\theta }}-3q_b)}}{2}\).

  19. Note that if \(E^{C2}>E^{C1}\) then \(E^{C1}>E^{C0}\).

  20. The methodology, implemented using Mathematica software, is explained in "Appendix 6".

  21. Figures 2, 3 and 4 depict parameter \({\overline{\theta }}=3\), but because the different thresholds for \(q_b\) are proportional to \({\overline{\theta }}\), these figures are valid for all values of \({\overline{\theta }}\).

  22. The leader has also an interest in differentiating more under Cournot than under Bertrand competition if the market is large (see "Appendix 5").

  23. The NGO’s eco-label is therefore more stringent than the eco-label that would be set by the leader if the market is large and less stringent otherwise (see "Appendix 5").

  24. For definitions, see "Appendix 7".

  25. Figs. 3 and 4 display the welfare components arising from the environmental quality \(q^{sN*}_g\) (where \(s=C,B\)) as plotted in Fig. 2 for each value of \(q_b\) for a given \({\overline{\theta }}\).

  26. A numerical analysis shows that \(q_g^{BN^*}: \le {\hat{q}}_g\) when \(q_b \le 0.472 {\overline{\theta }}\).

  27. Consumer surplus improves with the NGO’s eco-label when the market is very large, such as when \(q_b \le 0.105 {\overline{\theta }}\).

  28. Chatain and Plaksenkova (2019) analyze the interactions between firms and NGOs to include new “green” suppliers in a supply chain, but they do not model direct negotiations between NGOs and firms or competition in vertically differentiated markets.

  29. We can show that \(\Delta <0\) by studying the sign of the polynomial of degree 3 in brackets, denoted \(Q(q_b)\). The discriminant of \(Q(q_b)\) is negative. Therefore \(Q(q_b)\) has only one real root, which is equal to \(3.0045{\overline{\theta }} > 2 {\overline{\theta }}\). Moreover, we can show that \(Q(2 {\overline{\theta }})<0\) and \(Q'(2 {\overline{\theta }})>0\). Therefore \(Q(q_b)<0\) for all admissible values of \(q_b\).

References

  • Amacher GS, Koskela E, Ollikainen M (2004) Environmental quality competition and eco-labeling. J Environ Econ Manag 47(2):284–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltzer K (2012) Standards vs. labels with imperfect competition and asymmetric information. Econ Lett 114(1):61–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron DP (2011) Credence attributes, voluntary organizations, and social pressure. J Public Econ 95(11):1331–1338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron DP, Neale M, Rao H (2016) Extending nonmarket strategy: Political economy and the radical flank effect in private politics. Strategy Sci 1(2):105–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonanno G, Haworth B (1998) Intensity of competition and the choice between product and process innovation. Int J Ind Organ 16(4):495–510

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonroy O, Constantatos C (2015) On the economics of labels: how their introduction affects the functioning of markets and the welfare of all participants. Am J Agr Econ 97(1):239–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bottega L, De Freitas J (2009) Public, private and nonprofit regulation for environmental quality. J Econ Manag Strategy 18(1):105–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brécard D (2014) Consumer confusion over the profusion of eco-labels: Lessons from a double differentiation model. Resource Energy Econ 37:64–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brécard D (2017) Consumer misperception of eco-labels, green market structure and welfare. J Regul Econ 51(3):340–364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brécard D, Chiroleu-Assouline M (2020) The market for “harmful component-free” products under pressure from the NGOs. FAERE Working Paper 2020.14

  • C&E (2021) Corporate–NGO partnerships barometer

  • Chatain O, Plaksenkova E (2019) Ngos and the creation of value in supply chains. Strateg Manag J 40(4):604–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Espinola-Arredondo A, Stathopoulou E, Munoz-Garcia F (2022) Regulators and environmental groups: better together or apart? Environ Dev Econ 27(1):40–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feddersen TJ, Gilligan TW (2001) Saints and markets: Activists and the supply of credence goods. J Econ Manag Strategy 10(1):149–171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer C, Lyon TP (2014) Competing environmental labels. J Econ Manag Strategy 23(3):692–716

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forlin V (2021) Optimal eco-label standards in an oligopolistic setting. Am J Agr Econ 103(2):682–701

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg D, Tirole J (1985) Preemption and rent equalization in the adoption of new technology. Rev Econ Stud 52(3):383–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galasso A, Tombak M (2014) Switching to green: the timing of socially responsible innovation. J Econ Manag Strategy 23(3):669–691

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glasbergen P (2012) Partnerships for sustainable development in a globalised world: a reflection on market-oriented and policy-oriented partnerships. In: A handbook of globalisation and environmental policy, 2nd ed. Edward Elgar Publishing

  • GlobeScan (2017) Trust and transparency in the supply chain. A globalscan ebrief

  • Heijnen P, Schoonbeek L et al (2008) Environmental groups in monopolistic markets. Environ Resource Econ 39(4):379–396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heyes A, Oestreich AM (2018) A theory of social license when regulatory pressure is jointly produced by an EPA and an NGO. J Regul Econ 54:219–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heyes AG, Maxwell JW (2004) Private vs. public regulation: political economy of the international environment. J Environ Econ Manag 48(2):978–996

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Innes R (2006) A theory of consumer boycotts under symmetric information and imperfect competition. Econ J 116(511):355–381

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kreps DM, Scheinkman JA (1983) Quantity precommitment and bertrand competition yield cournot outcomes. Bell J Econ 14:326–337

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li Y (2020) Competing eco-labels and product market competition. Resource Energy Econ 60:101149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lyon TP (2010) Good cops, bad cops and the new environmental governance. Good Cop/Bad Cop. Environmental NGOs and their Strategies Towards Business, pp 267–271

  • Lyon TP, Maxwell JW (2008) Corporate social responsibility and the environment: a theoretical perspective. Rev Environ Econ Policy 2(2):240–260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Motta M (1993) Endogenous quality choice: price vs. quantity competition. J Ind Econ 41:113–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mussa M, Rosen S (1978) Monopoly and product quality. J Econ Theory 18(2):301–317

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Odziemkowska K, McDonnell M-H (2022) Ripple effects: How collaboration reduces social movement contention. Available at SSRN 3428050

  • ORSE (2012) Partenariats stratégiques ong-entreprises.guide

  • Poret S (2019) Corporate–NGO partnerships through sustainability labeling schemes: motives and risks. Sustainability 11(9):2689

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poret S (2019) Label wars: competition among ngos as sustainability standard setters. J Econ Behav Org 160:1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh N, Vives X (1984) Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly. Rand J Econ 15:546–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stathopoulou E, Gautier L (2019) Green alliances and the role of taxation. Environ Resource Econ 74:1189–1206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sutton J (2007) Market structure: theory and evidence. Handbook of industrial organization 3:2301–2368

  • Van der Made A, Schoonbeek L (2009) Entry facilitation by environmental groups. Environ Resource Econ 43(4):457–472

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wijen F, Chiroleu-Assouline M (2019) Controversy over voluntary environmental standards: a socioeconomic analysis of the marine stewardship council. Org Environ 32(2):98–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • WWF (2014) Making better production everybody’s business. results of 5 years of wwf market transformation work

Download references

Acknowledgements

I thank seminar audiences at the 9th Annual FAERE Conference and the 38th Journées de Microéconomie Appliquée and three anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dorothée Brécard.

Ethics declarations

Conflicts of interest

The author has no relevant financial or non-financial interests to disclose, no conflicts of interest to declare that are relevant to the content of this article, no affiliations with or involvement in any organization or entity with any financial interest or non-financial interest in the subject matter or materials discussed in this manuscript, no financial or proprietary interests in any material discussed in this article.

Ethical Approval

The author declares that: the paper conforms to the ethical standards of Environmental & Resource Economics; the paper is her own original work, which has not been previously published elsewhere; the paper is not currently being considered for publication elsewhere; the paper reflects her own research and analysis in a truthful and complete manner.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendices

All the proofs were performed using Mathematica software. The Mathemica file is available on request from the author.

1.1 Appendix 1: Proof of Proposition 1

To demonstrate Proposition 1, we analyze the profits \(\pi _L^{B1}(q_g)\) and \(\pi _F^{B1}(q_g)\).

1.1.1 The leader’s profit

The derivative of \(\pi _L^{B1}(q_g)\) is defined as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \dfrac{\partial \pi _L^{B1}(q_g)}{\partial q_g}=\dfrac{-24q_g^3+2(8{\overline{\theta }}+11q_b)q_g^2-(12{\overline{\theta }}+5q_b)q_bq_g+8{\overline{\theta }}q_b^2-2q_b^3}{2(4q_g-q_b)^2}x_g^{B1} \end{aligned}$$
(14)

The sign of the derivative is equal to the sign of the polynomial of degree 3, denoted \(P_L^B(q_g)\), in the numerator of Eq. 14. To study the sign of \(P_L^B(q_g)\), we first investigate whether the polynomial has one or three real roots by studying the sign of its discriminant \(\Delta _L^B\), characterized by:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta _L^B=4(8{\overline{\theta }}-3q_b)q_b^2(5997 q_b^3 - 18592 {\overline{\theta }} q_b^2+ 2704 {\overline{\theta }}^2 qb - 2944 {\overline{\theta }}^3). \end{aligned}$$

Because \(\Delta _L^B<0\),Footnote 29\(P_L^B(q_g)\) has only one real root.

We then investigate whether the real root is in the interval of admissible values for \(q_g\), that is \(]q_b,2{\overline{\theta }}]\), by studying the function \(P_L^B(q_g)\). The derivative of \(P_L^B(q_g)\) is defined as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} {P_L^B}'(q_g)= -72 q_g^2 + (44 q_b + 32 {\overline{\theta }})q_g- 12 {\overline{\theta }} q_b-5 qb^2 \end{aligned}$$

The discriminant of \({P_L^B}'(q_g)\) is \({\Delta _L^B}'=16(64 {\overline{\theta }}^2-40{\overline{\theta }}q_b+31q_b^2)>0\). \({P_L^B}'(q_g)\) has therefore two real roots, denoted \(r_1\) and \(r_2\) (with \(r_1<r_2\)) defined by \((8{\overline{\theta }}+11q_b\pm \sqrt{\Delta })/36\), such that \(r_1<q_b\) and \(r_2<2{\overline{\theta }}\). \(r_2 \ge q_b\) only if \(q_b \le 20{\overline{\theta }}/33\). So \(P_L^B(q_g)\) is a decreasing function for \(q_g>r_2\). Moreover, \(P_L^B(q_b)=3(4{\overline{\theta }}-3q_b)q_b^2>0\) and \(P_L^B(2{\overline{\theta }})=-2(64{\overline{\theta }}^3-32{\overline{\theta }}q_b+{\overline{\theta }}q_b^2+q_b^3)<0\). Therefore, the real root of \(P_L^B(q_g)\) is in the interval \([r_2,2{\overline{\theta }}]\). We deduce that \(\pi _L^{B1}(q_g)\) is a bell-shaped function of \(q_g\) that reaches its maximum at \(q_g^{BL^*} \in ]q_b,2{\overline{\theta }}[\), such that \(\partial \pi _L^{B1}/\partial q_g=0\).

1.1.2 The follower’s profit

The derivative of \(\pi _F^{B1}(q_g)\) is defined as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \dfrac{\partial \pi _F^{B1}(q_g)}{\partial q_g}=\dfrac{8q_g^3-8q_bq_g^2+(4{\overline{\theta }}+q_b)q_bq_g+2{\overline{\theta }}q_b^2-q_b^3}{2(4q_g-q_b)^2q_g}q_b x_b^{B1} \end{aligned}$$
(15)

The sign of the derivative is equal to the sign of the polynomial of degree 3, denoted \(P_F^B(q_g)\), in the numerator of Eq. 15. We have:

$$\begin{aligned} {P_F^B}'(q_g)=24q_g^2-16q_bq_g+4{\overline{\theta }}q_b+q_b^2 \end{aligned}$$

of which the discriminant is \({\Delta _F^B}'=-32(12{\overline{\theta }}q_b-5q_b^2)<0\). Therefore, \({P_F^B}'(q_g)>0\) and \(P_F^B(q_g)\) is an increasing function of \(q_g\). Moreover, \(P_F^B(q_b)=6{\overline{\theta }}q_b^2>0\) and \(P_F^B(2{\overline{\theta }})=64{\overline{\theta }}^3-24{\overline{\theta }}^2q_b+4{\overline{\theta }}q_b^2-q_b^3>0\). As a result, \(P_F^B(q_g)>0\) and \(\pi _F^{B1}(q_g)\) is an increasing function of \(q_g\).

1.2 Appendix 2: Proof of Lemma 1

The derivative of \(\pi _F^{C1}\) is defined as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _F^{C1}}{\partial q_g}=\dfrac{2(2q_g^2-q_bq_g-{\overline{\theta }}q_b+q_b^2)q_b}{(4q_g-q_b)^2}x_b^{C1} \end{aligned}$$
(16)

The quadratic function, denoted \(P_F^C(q_g)\), in the numerator of Eq. 16 has a discriminant \(\Delta _F^C = (8{\overline{\theta }}-7 q_b)qb\). With \(q_b<{\overline{\theta }}\), \(\Delta _F^C>0\) and \(P_F^C(q_g)\) has two real positive roots of which only one, equal to \((q_b+\sqrt{8{\overline{\theta }}-7q_b})/4\), is higher than \(q_b\). \(P_F^C(q_g)\) is a decreasing function for \(q_g \le (q_b+\sqrt{8{\overline{\theta }}-7q_b})/4\) and increasing otherwise. Therefore, \(\pi _F^{C1}\) is a U-shaped function of \(q_g\) in the interval \([q_b,2{\overline{\theta }}]\).

The derivative of \(\pi _F^{C2}\) is equal to \((2{\overline{\theta }}-3q_g)/6\). \(\pi _F^{C2}\) is then a bell-shaped function of \(q_g\) which reaches its maximum at \(q_g^{C2^*} \equiv 2{\overline{\theta }}/3\).

Knowing that the leader adopts the eco-label, the follower has an incentive to adopt it too if \(I_F^C(q_g)=\pi _F^{C2}(q_g)-\pi _F^{C1}(q_g) > 0\). \(I_F^C(q_g)\) is defined as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} I_F^{C}(q_g)=\dfrac{(q_g-q_b)q_g(16 q_g^3-(64 {\overline{\theta }}+q_b)q_g^2+4(16{\overline{\theta }}^2-17{\overline{\theta }}q_b+9q_b^2) q_g-4{\overline{\theta }}^2q_b)}{36{\overline{\theta }}(4q_g-q_b)^2} \end{aligned}$$
(17)

\(I_F^C(q_g)\) is a bell-shaped function of \(q_g\) when \(q_b<10{\overline{\theta }}/17\), because \(\pi _F^{C1}(q_g)\) becomes a U-shaped function of \(q_g\), \(\pi _F^{C2}(q_g)\) is a bell-shaped function of \(q_g\), \(I^C_F(q_b)=0\) and

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \dfrac{\partial I_F^C}{\partial q_g}\right| _{q_g=q_b}=\dfrac{(2{\overline{\theta }}-q_b)(10{\overline{\theta }}-17q_b)}{108{\overline{\theta }}}>0 \text { if } q_b<10{\overline{\theta }}/17 \end{aligned}$$

Moreover, \(I_F^C(q_g)\) is positive for \(q_g \in ]q_b,{\overline{q}}_g^{CF}]\), where \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF}\) is such that \(I_F^C({\overline{q}}_g^{CF})=0\). Threshold \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF}\) is the only real root (in the real numbers and greater than \(q_b\)) of the following polynomial of degree 3:

$$\begin{aligned} 16 q_g^3-(64 {\overline{\theta }}+q_b)q_g^2+4(16{\overline{\theta }}^2-17{\overline{\theta }}q_b+9q_b^2) q_g-4{\overline{\theta }}^2q_b=0 \end{aligned}$$
(18)

The discriminant of the polynomial (18), denoted \(P^{CF}(q_g)\), is defined by:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta ^{CF}=-144q_b(8{\overline{\theta }}-7q_b)^2(2{\overline{\theta }}-q_b)(423 q_b^2 - 608 {\overline{\theta }} q_b+ 1024 {\overline{\theta }}^2). \end{aligned}$$

with \(\Delta ^{CF}>0\). The polynomial has three real roots. Its derivative is:

$$\begin{aligned} P^{CF'}(q_g)=48 q_g^2 - 2(64 {\overline{\theta }} +q_b)q_g+4(9q_b^2-17q_b{\overline{\theta }}+16{\overline{\theta }}^2) \end{aligned}$$

The discriminant of \(P^{CF'}(q_g)\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta ^{CF'}=-4 (1727 q_b^2 - 3392 q_b {\overline{\theta }} - 1024 {\overline{\theta }}^2)>0. \end{aligned}$$

\(P^{CF'}(q_g)\) has therefore two real roots, \(r_1<r_2\), such that \(r_i=(64{\overline{\theta }}+q_b\pm \sqrt{\Delta ^{CF}}\))/48, \(r_1<{\overline{\theta }}\), \(r_2>2{\overline{\theta }}\), and \(r_1>q_b\) if \(q_b<16{\overline{\theta }}/41\). Moreover, \(P^{CF}(q_b)=3(2{\overline{\theta }}-q_b)(10{\overline{\theta }}-17q_b)q_b>0\) for \(q_b<10{\overline{\theta }}/17\) (required for \(I_F^C(q_g)>0\)). Therefore, \(P^{CF}(q_g)\) is positive and increases for \(q_g \in [q_b,r_1]\). It decreases for \(q_g \in [r_1,2{\overline{\theta }}]\). Moreover, \(P^{CF}({\overline{\theta }})=(16{\overline{\theta }}-9q_b)({\overline{\theta }}-4q_b){\overline{\theta }}>0\) if \(q_b<{\overline{\theta }}/4\) and \(P^{CF}(2{\overline{\theta }})=-75(2{\overline{\theta }}-q_b){\overline{\theta }}<0\). Therefore, \(P^{CF}(q_g)\) has a unique real root: \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF} \in [{\overline{\theta }},2{\overline{\theta }}]\) if \(q_b<{\overline{\theta }}/4\) or \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF} \in [\max \{r_1,qb\},{\overline{\theta }}]\) if \(q_b \in [{\overline{\theta }}/4,10{\overline{\theta }}/17]\).

Therefore, the follower’s best response to adoption by the leader is to adopt only if \(q_g<{\overline{q}}_g^{CF}\) and \(q_b<10{\overline{\theta }}/17\).

1.3 Appendix 3: Proof of Proposition 2

The derivative of \(\pi _L^{C1}\) is defined as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _L^{C1}}{\partial q_g}=\dfrac{ -24q_g^3+2(8{\overline{\theta }}+5q_b)q_g^2-4({\overline{\theta }}+q_b)q_b q_g+2{\overline{\theta }}q_b^2-q_b^3}{2(4q_g-q_b)^2}x_g^{C1} \end{aligned}$$
(19)

The sign of the derivative is equal to the sign of the polynomial of degree 3, denoted \(P_L^C(q_g)\), in the numerator of Eq. 19. The discriminant of \(P(q_g)\) is characterized by:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta _L^C=32(8{\overline{\theta }}-7q_b)q_b^2(149 q_b^3 - 66 {\overline{\theta }} q_b^2 -30 {\overline{\theta }}^2 qb - 112 {\overline{\theta }}^3). \end{aligned}$$

\(\Delta _L^C<0\) when \(q_b<{\overline{\theta }}\) (by assumption). So \(P_L^C(q_g)\) has only one real root.

The derivative of \(P_L^C(q_g)\) is defined as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} {P_L^C}'(q_g)=-72q_g^2+4(8{\overline{\theta }}+5q_b)q_g-4{\overline{\theta }}q_b-4q_b^2 \end{aligned}$$

The discriminant of \({P_L^C}'(q_g)\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta =16(64{\overline{\theta }}^2+8{\overline{\theta }}q_b-47q_b^2)>0. \end{aligned}$$

\({P_L^C}'(q_g)\) has two real positive roots (denoted \(r_1\) and \(r_2\)), defined by \((8{\overline{\theta }}+5q_b \pm \sqrt{64{\overline{\theta }}^2+8{\overline{\theta }}q_b-47q_b^2})/36\), such that \(r_1<q_b\) and \(r_1<r_2<2{\overline{\theta }}\). \(r_2>q_b\) only if \(q_b<{\overline{\theta }}/2\). Therefore \({P_L^C}'(q_g)>0\) if \(q_b<q_g<r_2\) and \({P_L^C}'(q_g) \le 0\) otherwise. Moreover, \(P_L^C(q_b)=(14{\overline{\theta }}-19q_b)q_b^2>0\) if \(q_b<14{\overline{\theta }}/19\) and \(P_L^C(2{\overline{\theta }})=-128{\overline{\theta }}^3+32{\overline{\theta }}^2q_b-6{\overline{\theta }}q_b^2-q_b^3<0\). Therefore, the real root of \(P(q_g)\) is in the interval \([r_2,2{\overline{\theta }}]\) if \(q_b\le {\overline{\theta }}/2\) and in \([q_b,2{\overline{\theta }}]\) if \({\overline{\theta }}/2<q_b<14{\overline{\theta }}/19\). We deduce that \(\pi _L^{C1}\) is a bell-shaped function of \(q_g\) that reaches its maximum at \(q_g^{CL^*} \in ]q_b,2{\overline{\theta }}[\).

If \(q_b \ge 14{\overline{\theta }}/19\), the real root of \(P_L^C(q_g)\) is lower than \(q_b\), \(\pi _L^{C1}\) is a decreasing function of \(q_g\) in the interval \([q_b,2{\overline{\theta }}]\) and \(P_L^C(q_b)\le 0\). Therefore, the leader has no interest in adopting the eco-label; it still produces the brown product of quality \(q_b\).

The necessary condition for the leader to adopt the eco-label is therefore \(q_b<14{\overline{\theta }}/19\).

The leader has an incentive to adopt the eco-label if \(I_L^C(q_g)=\pi _L^{C1}(q_g)-\pi _L^{C0}(q_g) > 0\). \(I_L^C(q_g)\) is defined as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} I_L^{C}(q_g)=\dfrac{(q_g-q_b)(36 q_g^4-36(4 {\overline{\theta }}- q_b)q_g^3 + 72(2 {\overline{\theta }}- q_b){\overline{\theta }} q_g^2-16(2{\overline{\theta }}-q_b)^2q_b q_g+(2{\overline{\theta }}-q_b)^2q_b^2)}{36{\overline{\theta }}(4q_g-q_b)^2} \end{aligned}$$
(20)

\(I_L^C\) is a bell-shaped function of \(q_g\) when \(q_b<14{\overline{\theta }}/19\), because \(\pi _L^{C1}(q_g)\) is then a bell-shaped function of \(q_g\), \(\pi _L^{C0}\) is independent of \(q_g\), \(I^C_L(q_b)=0\) and

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \dfrac{\partial I_L^C}{\partial q_g}\right| _{q_g=q_b}=\dfrac{(2{\overline{\theta }}-q_b)(14{\overline{\theta }}-19q_b)}{108{\overline{\theta }}}>0 \text { if } q_b<14{\overline{\theta }}/19 \end{aligned}$$

Furthermore, \(I_L^C(q_g)\) is positive for \(q_g \in ]q_b,{\overline{q}}_g^{CL}]\), where \({\overline{q}}_g^{CL}\) is such that \(I_L^C({\overline{q}}_g^{CL})=0\). Threshold \({\overline{q}}_g^{CL}\) is the only real root (in the real numbers and greater than \(q_b\)) of the following polynomial of degree 4:

$$\begin{aligned} 36 q_g^4-36(4 {\overline{\theta }}- q_b)q_g^3 + 72(2 {\overline{\theta }}- q_b){\overline{\theta }} q_g^2-16(2{\overline{\theta }}-q_b)^2q_b q_g+(2{\overline{\theta }}-q_b)^2q_b^2=0 \end{aligned}$$
(21)

The discriminant of this polynomial is positive; the polynomial has four distinct roots which are either all real or form two pairs of conjugate complex numbers. The analytical proof of the uniqueness of \({\overline{q}}_g^{CL}\) in \([q_b,2{\overline{\theta }}]\) is therefore tedious. Using a numerical demonstration, with \(q_b\) from 0 to \({\overline{\theta }}\), we can show that there is always a unique real root, \({\overline{q}}_g^{CL} \in [q_b,2{\overline{\theta }}]\).

Moreover, \(I_L^C(q_g)>I_F^C(q_g)\) for all \(q_g \in [q_b,2{\overline{\theta }}]\), because \(I^C_F(q_b)=0\), \(I^C_L(q_b)=0\) and \(I^C_L(q_g)\) grows faster than \(I_F^C(q_g)\) when \(q_g\) is close to \(q_b\) if \(q_b<10{\overline{\theta }}/17<14{\overline{\theta }}/19\). In addition, \(I_L^C(q_g)-I_F^C(q_g)=(q_g-q_b)P^{I}(q_g)/(36{\overline{\theta }}(4q_g-q_b)^2)\) has the same sign as the polynomial function \(P^I(q_g)\), defined as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} & P^I(q_g)=20 q_g^4-(80 {\overline{\theta }}- 37q_b)q_g^3 + 4(20 {\overline{\theta }}^2-{\overline{\theta }}q_b- 9q_b^2) q_g^2\\ & -4(5{\overline{\theta }}-2q_b)(3{\overline{\theta }}-2q_b)q_b q_g+(2{\overline{\theta }}-q_b)^2q_b^2 \end{aligned}$$

To show that \(P^I(q_g)>0\), we analyze the discriminant of the second derivative of \({P^I}(q_g)\), defined by \({\Delta ^I}^{''}=12(6400{\overline{\theta }}^2-17120{\overline{\theta }}q_b+9867q_b^2)\):

  • If \(q_b>0.545{\overline{\theta }}\), \({\Delta ^I}^{''}<0\) and \({P^I}^{''}(q_g)>0\) because the coefficient of \(q_g^2\) is equal to \(20\times 4 \times 3=240>0\). Therefore, \({P^I}^{'}(q_g)\) and \({P^I}(q_b)\) are positive (since \({P^I}^{'}(q_b)>0\) and \({P^I}(q_b)>0\)) and increasing in the interval \([q_b,2{\overline{\theta }}]\).

  • If \(q_b<0.545{\overline{\theta }}\), \({\Delta ^I}^{''}>0\) and \({P^I}^{''}(q_g)\) has two real roots defined by \(r_i\equiv {\overline{\theta }}-\frac{37q_b}{80} \pm \frac{\sqrt{{\Delta ^I}^{''}}}{80\sqrt{3}}\), with \(q_b<r_1<r_2<2{\overline{\theta }}\). \({P^I}^{''}(q_g)\) is positive outside the roots and negative between the roots. In addition, \({P^I}^{'}(q_b)>0\) for all \(q_b\) and \({P^I}^{'}(r_2)>0\) for \(q_b \in [0.198{\overline{\theta }},0.545{\overline{\theta }}]\). In this case, \({P^I}(q_g)\) is increasing and positive on the interval \([q_b,2{\overline{\theta }}]\).

  • If \(q_b<0.198{\overline{\theta }}\), we can show that the discriminant of \({P^I}^{'}(q_g)\) is positive. \({P^I}^{'}(q_g)\) has then three real roots, including two roots, denoted \(r_3\in ]r_1,r_2]\) and \(r_4 \in ]r_2,2{\overline{\theta }}]\). \({P^I}^{'}(r_2)<0\) is the minimum of \({P^I}^{'}(q_g)\). We can show that \(\partial r_2/\partial q_b>0\) and \(\partial {P^I}^{'}(r_2)/\partial q_b>0\): A higher \(q_b\) reduces the slope of \({P^I}(q_g)\) in its decreasing part, and thus increases \({P^I}(q_g)\) for \(q_g \ge r_2\). In addition \(P^{I}(q_g)=20(2{\overline{\theta }}-q_g)^2q_g^2>0\) for \(q_b=0\) and \({P^I}(r_2)>0\) \(\forall q_b, q_g\). Therefore \({P^I}(q_g)>0\) for \(q_g \in [r_2,2{\overline{\theta }}]\) and thus for all \(q_g\).

As a result, \(I_L^C(q_g)>I_F^C(q_g)\) for all \(q_g \in [q_b,2{\overline{\theta }}]\). Moreover, denoting \({\overline{q}}_g^{CL}\) and \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF}\) the environmental qualities such that, \(I_L^C({\overline{q}}_g^{CL})=0\) and \(I_F^C({\overline{q}}_g^{CF})=0\), we have \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF}<{\overline{q}}_g^{CL}\).

1.4 Appendix 4: Proof of Proposition 3

To prove that \(I_L^B(q_g)>I_L^C(q_g)\), we note that \(I_L^B(q_b)=0\) and \(I_L ^C(q_b)=0\). Moreover, we can express the incentive difference as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} I_L^B(q_g)-I_L^C(q_g)=\dfrac{q_b(q_g-q_b) \Big [4(16q_g-q_b){\overline{\theta }}^2-4(16q_g-q_b)q_b{\overline{\theta }}+(9q_g^2+16q_bq_g-q_b^2)q_b\Big ]}{36{\overline{\theta }}(4q_g-q_b)^2} \end{aligned}$$

The discriminant of the polynomial into brackets, equal to \(\Delta =-144(16q_g-q_b)q_bq_g^2\), is negative, so the polynomial takes the sign of \(4(16q_g-q_b)\), which is positive. Therefore, \(I_L^B(q_g)(q_g)>I_L^C(q_g)\).

1.5 Appendix 5: The Nash bargaining model and the leader’s take-it-or-leave-it eco-label

1.5.1 The Nash bargaining model

Negociations between the NGO and the firm can be described as a Nash bargaining problem. The bargaining over the eco-label stringency consists of the following maximization program:

$$\begin{aligned} \max \limits _{q_g}\left\{ (E^{st}-E^{s0})^\alpha (\pi _L^{st}-\pi _L^{s0}) ^{(1-\alpha )} \text { st } E^{st}>E^{s0} \ \text {and} \ \pi _L^{st}>\pi _L^{s0}\right\} \end{aligned}$$

where \(E^{s0}\) and \(\pi _L^{s0}\) are the status quo or disagreement outcomes for the NGO and the leader respectively. \(E^{st}\) represents environmental quality in Stages t (\(t=0,1,2\)) when firms use strategies s (\(s=C,B\)). \(\alpha\) measures the NGO’s bargaining power and \(1-\alpha\) measures the firm’s bargaining power, such that \(\alpha \in [0,1]\). In the case of Bertrand competition, the negotiations between the partners have a short-term horizon (\(t=1\)) because the follower never adopts the eco-label; in the case of Cournot competition, which allows the diffusion of the eco-label, the horizon can be \(t=2\) if the leader does not impose an exclusivity clause on the eco-label in the negotiations, or \(t=1\) otherwise.

The first-order condition for the maximization program can be expressed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \dfrac{\alpha }{E^{st}-E^{s0}}\dfrac{\partial E^{st}}{\partial q_g}+\dfrac{1-\alpha }{\pi ^{st}-\pi ^{s0}}\dfrac{\partial \pi ^{st}}{\partial q_g}=0 \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, the environmental quality resulting from eco-label bargaining, denoted \(q_g^{s^*}\), is intermediate between green quality \(q_g^{sL^*}\) that maximizes the profit of the leader (when \(\alpha =0\)) and green quality \(q_g^{sN^*}\) that maximizes the quality of the environment (when \(\alpha =1\)).

1.5.2 The leader’s take-it-or-leave-it eco-label

When the leader offers a take-it-or-leave-it eco-label, its objective is to maximize its profit \(\pi _L^{s1}(q_g)\), while ensuring that environmental quality improves. Its program (where \(s=B,C\)) therefore is:

$$\begin{aligned} \max \limits _{q_g} \pi _L^{s1}(q_g) \text { st } E^{s1}(q_g) \ge E^{s0} \text { and } \pi _L^{s1}(q_g) \ge \pi _L^{s0} \end{aligned}$$

In the case of Bertrand competition, there exists a unique eco-label \(q_g^{BL^*}\in [q_b,2{\overline{\theta }}]\) that maximizes the leader’s profit. The NGO’s participation constraint, \(q_g^{BL^*} \le {\overline{q}}_g^{BN}\), is fulfilled if \(q_b \le 2{\overline{\theta }}/3\). When \(q_b\) is higher, the quality of the environment cannot be improved (compared with the initial situation), so no negotiation takes place between the firm and the NGO, and no eco-label emerges. The leader’s eco-label is less stringent than NGO’s eco-label if the market is large (\(q_b \le 0.494 {\overline{\theta }}\)) and more stringent otherwise. In a large market the leader prefers a less demanding eco-label, which leads to a lower price and greater consumption of the green product and, through these effects, to higher profits, without compromising environmental quality. The closer \(q_b\) is to \({\overline{\theta }}\), the more demanding the leader’s eco-label. Thus, the leader tries to keep product differentiation substantial enough to mitigate price competition and ensure its profits are as high as possible.

In the case of Cournot competition, the leader earns a higher profit if the follower chooses not to adopt the eco-label, so the leader implements either a deterrence strategy, by setting \(q_g\) just above \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF}\) when the market is sufficiently large (\(q_b \le 0.444{\overline{\theta }}\)), or a standard profit maximization strategy, by setting \(q_g\) to \(q_g^{CL^*}>{\overline{q}}_g^{CF}\) in the case of a narrower market (\(q_b\in [0.444{\overline{\theta }},{\overline{\theta }}]\)). As a result, the leader’s eco-label is more stringent with Cournot than with Bertrand competition when the market is large (\(q_b \le 0.378{\overline{\theta }}\)) and less stringent otherwise. Moreover, the leader’s eco-label is more stringent than NGO’s eco-label if the market is large (\(q_b \le {\overline{\theta }}/4\)) and less stringent otherwise (\(0.419{\overline{\theta }},{\overline{\theta }} \big ]\)). In a medium market, where \(q_b \in \big [ {\overline{\theta }}/4,0.419{\overline{\theta }} \big ]\), the NGO and the leader set environmental qualities very close to \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF}\), such that \(q_g^{CN^*}<{\overline{q}}_g^{CF}< q_g^{CL^*}\). The interests of the NGO and the leader are opposed, as long as the market is not so narrow as to preclude any diffusion of the eco-label. Whereas the NGO wants to promote the diffusion of the eco-label, the leader prefers to prevent it. Therefore, in a large market, the leader sets a very demanding eco-label, which discourages adoption by the follower, while keeping its own profit higher than it would be in the case of diffusion. Conversely, the NGO sets a less demanding eco-label that leads to the highest possible quality of the environment through the diffusion of the eco-label. In a medium-sized market, paradoxically, the NGO and leader propose similar eco-labels, yet their conflicting interests in terms of diffusion prevent them from agreeing on a single eco-label \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF}\). Therefore, if Cournot competition exists, unless the market is narrow, negotiations between the partners for eco-labeling are particularly challenging.

1.6 Appendix 6: Proof of Proposition 4

1.6.1 Bertrand Competition

The first-order condition (FOC) for environmental quality maximization is characterized as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial E^{B1}}{\partial q_g}=- \frac{ 16q_g^3-2(8{\overline{\theta }}+3q_b)q_g^2+8{\overline{\theta }}q_bq_g+2{\overline{\theta }}q_b^2-q_b^3}{2{\overline{\theta }}(4q_g-q_b)^2}=0 \end{aligned}$$
(22)

The numerator of the FOC implicitly defines the preferred eco-label of the NGO, \(q_g^{BN^*}\), as the real solution of the polynomial of degree 3 in \(q_g\).

The discriminant of the polynomial, denoted \(P_N^B(q_g)\), is defined by:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta _N^B=96q_b^2(8{\overline{\theta }}-3q_b)^2(2{\overline{\theta }}-3q_b)(4{\overline{\theta }}+3q_b) \end{aligned}$$

Under the condition that \(q_b<2{\overline{\theta }}/3\) (required for participation of both partners), \(\Delta _N^B>0\) and the polynomial has three distinct real roots.

The derivative of \(P_N^B(q_g)\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} P{_N^B}'(q_g)=4(4q_g-qb)(2{\overline{\theta }}-3q_g) \end{aligned}$$

such that \(P{_N^B}'(q_g)>0\) for \(q_b<q_g<2{\overline{\theta }}/3\) and \(P{_N^B}'(q_g)\le 0\) for \(2{\overline{\theta }}/3<q_g<2{\overline{\theta }}\). Because \(P_N^B(q_b)=3q_b^2(2{\overline{\theta }}-3q_b)>0\) and \(P_N^B(2{\overline{\theta }})=-(4{\overline{\theta }}-q_b)(16{\overline{\theta }}^2+2q_b{\overline{\theta }}=q_b^2)<0\), there is only one real root in the interval \([2{\overline{\theta }}/3,2{\overline{\theta }}]\).

As a result, \(q_g^{BN^*}\) is in the interval \([\frac{2{\overline{\theta }}}{3},2{\overline{\theta }}]\). We cannot give an analytical definition of \(q_g^{BN^*}\), but we have proved the existence of \(q_g^{BN^*}\) when \(q_b<2{\overline{\theta }}/3\).

1.6.2 Cournot Competition

Assuming \(q_b<{\overline{\theta }}\), we have:

$$\begin{aligned} E^{C1}-E^{C0}=\dfrac{q_g-q_b}{{\overline{\theta }}(4q_g-q_b)} \Big [4{\overline{\theta }}q_g(3q_g-q_b)-(6q_g^2+3q_bq_g-2q_b^2)\Big ] \end{aligned}$$

The term in brackets is positive for \(q_g \in \big [q_b,\dfrac{12{\overline{\theta }}-3q_b+\sqrt{3(48{\overline{\theta }}^2-56{\overline{\theta }}cq_b+19{\overline{\theta }}^2}}{12} \Big ]\). We also have:

$$\begin{aligned}&E^{C2}-E^{C1}=\dfrac{q_g-q_b}{6{\overline{\theta }}(4q_g-q_b)} \Big [4{\overline{\theta }}-2q_g-3q_b)\Big ] \end{aligned}$$

The term in brackets is positive for \(q_b<4{\overline{\theta }}/5\) and \(q_g \in \big [q_b,(4{\overline{\theta }}-3q_b])2 \big ]\), with:

$$\begin{aligned} \dfrac{4{\overline{\theta }}-3q_b}{2}<\dfrac{12{\overline{\theta }}-3q_b+\sqrt{3(48{\overline{\theta }}^2-56{\overline{\theta }}cq_b+19{\overline{\theta }}^2}}{12}. \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, if \(q_b\) and \(q_g\) fulfill the conditions for \(E^{C2}>E^{C1}\), then \(E^{C1}>E^{C0}\).

The maximum of \(E^{C2}\) is reached at \(q_g={\overline{\theta }}\). According to "Appendix 2", \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF} > {\overline{\theta }}\) if \(q_b<{\overline{\theta }}/4\) and \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF} \le {\overline{\theta }}\) when \({\overline{\theta }}/4 \le q_b < 10{\overline{\theta }}/17\).

The FOC for maximizing \(E^{C1}\) is as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial E^{C1}}{\partial q_g}=-\frac{16q_g^3-2(8{\overline{\theta }}+5q_b)q_g^2+2(4{\overline{\theta }}+q_b)q_bq_g-q_b^3=0}{2{\overline{\theta }}(4q_g-q_b)^2}=0 \end{aligned}$$
(23)

The numerator of the FOC implicitly defines the eco-label, \(q_g^{CN^*}\), as the real solution of the polynomial, denoted \(P_N^C(q_g)\). The discriminant of \(P_N^C(q_g)\) is defined by:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta _N^C=16q_b^2(8{\overline{\theta }}-7q_b)(47q_b^3-48q_b^2{\overline{\theta }}-48q_b{\overline{\theta }}^2+128{\overline{\theta }}^3) \end{aligned}$$

Because \(\Delta _N^C>0\), \(P_N^C(q_g)\) has three distinct real roots.

The derivative of \(P_N^C(q_g)\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} {P_N^C}'(q_g)=-4(4q_g-qb)(6q_g-q_b-4{\overline{\theta }}) \end{aligned}$$

such that: \({P_N^C}'(q_g)>0\) for \(q_b<4{\overline{\theta }}/5\) and \(q_g<(q_b+4{\overline{\theta }})/6\); \({P_N^C}'(q_g) \le 0\) otherwise. Because \(P_N^C({\overline{\theta }})=(q_b^2-2q_b{\overline{\theta }}+2{\overline{\theta }}^2)>0\) and \(P_N^C(2{\overline{\theta }})=q_b^3-4q_b^2{\overline{\theta }}+24q_b{\overline{\theta }}^2-64{\overline{\theta }}^3<0\), there is only one real root in the interval \([{\overline{\theta }},2{\overline{\theta }}]\).

As a result, \(q_g^{CN^*}\) is in the interval \([{\overline{\theta }},2{\overline{\theta }}]\). We cannot give an analytical definition of \(q_g^{CN^*}\), but we have proved the existence of \(q_g^{CN^*}\).

1.6.3 Methodology for numerical simulations

To find the threshold of \(q_b\) above which \(E^{C1}(q_g^{CN^*})\ge E^{C2}({\overline{q}}_g^{CF})\), even though \(q_g^{CN^*}\) and \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF}\) have no analytical expressions, we turn to numerical simulations:

  • we set \({\overline{\theta }} \ge 1\);

  • we compute \(q_g^{CN^*}\) and \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF}\) for all admissible values of \(q_b=\gamma {\overline{\theta }}\), with \(\gamma \in [0,1]\), by using the FindRoot function of the Mathematica software, which allows us to numerically find local roots of the conditions \(\partial E^{C1}/\partial q_g=0\) and \(\pi _F^{C2}-\pi _F^{C1}=0\), starting from a value \(q_g={\overline{\theta }}\);

  • we compute the corresponding values for \(E^{C1}(q_g^{CN^*})\) and \(E^{C2}({\overline{q}}_g^{CF})\);

  • we deduce that, regardless the value set for \({\overline{\theta }}\), we have \(E^{C1}(q_g^{CN^*}) \ge E^{C2}({\overline{q}}_g^{CF})\) for \(\gamma \ge 0.41899\).

We thus prove that \(E^{C1}(q_g^{CN^*})\ge E^{C2}({\overline{q}}_g^{CF})\) for \(q_b \ge 0.41899{\overline{\theta }}\) for all \({\overline{\theta }} \ge 1\).

We follow the same methodology to compare \(q_g^{CN^*}\) and \(q_g^{BN^*}\) (Proposition 4 and Fig. 2). Figure 2 plots \(q_g^{BN^*}\), \(q_g^{CN^*}\) and \({\overline{q}}_g^{CF}\) as a function of \(q_b\). We have checked that these results are robust regardless of the value of \({\overline{\theta }}\); in Fig. 2, only the scales of \(q_g^{BN^*}\) and \(q_g^{CN^*}\) change with \({\overline{\theta }}\). We also follow the same methodology to compare \(E^{Ct}\) and \(E^{Bt}\) (Proposition 5 and Fig. 3), \(CS^{Ct}\) and \(CS^{Bt}\), and \(\Pi ^{Ct}\) and \(\Pi ^{Bt}\) (Proposition 6 and Fig. 4).

1.7 Appendix 7: Consumer Surplus

In the case of Bertrand competition, consumer surplus in Periods 0 and 1 are defined by:

$$\begin{aligned} CS_b^{B0}=&\int _{\tilde{\theta }_b}^{{\overline{\theta }}} \dfrac{u_b(\theta )}{{\overline{\theta }}} \,d\theta \ =2{\overline{\theta }}q_b {x_b^{B0}}^2;\\ CS_b^{B1}=&\int _{0}^{{\hat{\theta }}} \dfrac{u_b(\theta )}{{\overline{\theta }}} \,d\theta \ =\dfrac{{\overline{\theta }}q_b}{2} {x_b^{B1}}^2;\\ CS_g^{B1}=&\int _{{\hat{\theta }}}^{{\overline{\theta }}} \dfrac{u_g(\theta )}{{\overline{\theta }}} \,d\theta \ =\dfrac{-2q_g^2+(4{\overline{\theta }}+q_b)q_g+4{\overline{\theta }}q_b-2q_b^2}{4(4q_g-q_b)}q_g x_g^{B1}. \end{aligned}$$

We have:

$$\begin{aligned} \dfrac{\partial CS_b^{B1}}{\partial q_g}=&\dfrac{(4q_g^2-2q_bq_g-2{\overline{\theta }}q_b+q_b^2)q_b}{2(4q_g-q_b)^2};\\ \dfrac{\partial CS_g^{B1}}{\partial q_g}=&\dfrac{q_g}{8{\overline{\theta }}(4q_g-q_b)^3} \Big ( 48q_g^4-4(32{\overline{\theta }}+5q_b)q_g^3+4(16{\overline{\theta }}^2+8{\overline{\theta }}q_b+3q_b^3)q_g^2\\&-3(16{\overline{\theta }}^2-8{\overline{\theta }}q_b+3q_b^2)q_b q_g-4(4{\overline{\theta }}-q_b)(2{\overline{\theta }}-q_b)q_b^2 \Big ). \end{aligned}$$

We deduce that \(\partial CS_b^{B1} / \partial q_g > 0\) if \(q_g>\Big ( q_b+\sqrt{(8{\overline{\theta }}-3q_b)q_b} \Big )/4\) and \(q_b<2{\overline{\theta }}/3\) (such that \(x_b^{B1}\) increases) and negative otherwise. Because the polynomial of degree 4 into bracket in the expression of \(\partial CS_g^{B1} / \partial q_g\) cannot be explicitly solved, we turn to numerical simulations. Simulations show that \(\partial CS_g^{B1} / \partial q_g < 0\) and that \(CS_g^{B1}+CS_b^{B1}\) is a decreasing function of \(q_g\) for all for all admissible values of \(q_b\) and \({\overline{\theta }}\).

In the case of Cournot competition, consumer surplus in Periods 0 and 1 are defined by:

$$\begin{aligned} CS_b^{C0}=&\int _{\tilde{\theta }_b}^{{\overline{\theta }}} \dfrac{u_b(\theta )}{{\overline{\theta }}} \,d\theta \ =2{\overline{\theta }}q_b {x_b^{C0}}^2;\\ CS_b^{C1}=&\int _{0}^{{\hat{\theta }}} \dfrac{u_b(\theta )}{{\overline{\theta }}} \,d\theta \ =\dfrac{{\overline{\theta }}q_b}{2} {x_b^{C1}}^2;\\ CS_g^{C1}=&\int _{{\hat{\theta }}}^{{\overline{\theta }}} \dfrac{u_g(\theta )}{{\overline{\theta }}} \,d\theta \ =\dfrac{-2q_g^2+2(2{\overline{\theta }}+q_b)q_g+2{\overline{\theta }}q_b-3q_b^2}{4(4q_g-q_b)}q_g x_g^{C1}. \end{aligned}$$

We have:

$$\begin{aligned} \dfrac{\partial CS_b^{C1}}{\partial q_g}=&\dfrac{(2q_g^2-q_bq_g-{\overline{\theta }}q_b+q_b^2)q_b}{(4q_g-q_b)^2};\\ \dfrac{\partial CS_g^{C1}}{\partial q_g}=&\dfrac{1}{8{\overline{\theta }}(4q_g-q_b)^3} \Big ( 48q_g^5-4(32{\overline{\theta }}+13q_b)q_g^4 +32({\overline{\theta }}+q_b)(2{\overline{\theta }}+q_b)q_g^3\\&-12(4{\overline{\theta }}^2+2{\overline{\theta }}q_b+q_b^2)q_b q_g^2+8(2{\overline{\theta }}^2-{\overline{\theta }}q_b+q_b^2)q_b^2 q_g +(2{\overline{\theta }}-q_b)(2{\overline{\theta }}-3q_b)q_b^3 \Big ) \end{aligned}$$

We deduce that \(\partial CS_b^{C1} / \partial q_g > 0\) if \(q_g>\Big ( q_b+\sqrt{(8{\overline{\theta }}-7q_b)q_b} \Big )/4\) and \(q_b<2{\overline{\theta }}/3\) (such that \(x_b^{C1}\) increases) and negative otherwise. Because the polynomial of degree 5 into bracket in the expression of \(\partial CS_g^{C1} / \partial q_g\) cannot be explicitly solved, we turn to numerical simulations. Simulations show that \(\partial CS_g^{C1} / \partial q_g\) is U-shaped function of \(q_g\) and that \(CS_g^{C1}+CS_b^{C1}\) is a bell-shaped function of \(q_g\) for all for all admissible values of \(q_b\) and \({\overline{\theta }}\).

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Brécard, D. How Corporate–NGO Partnerships Affect Eco-Label Adoption and Diffusion. Environ Resource Econ 86, 233–261 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-023-00795-1

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-023-00795-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation