Skip to main content
Log in

The psychological foundations of rational ignorance: biased heuristics and decision costs

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Rational ignorance and related models of voter choice have been accused of psychological implausibility or even incoherence. Although such models run counter to folk psychological understandings of choice, this paper argues that they are consistent with widely-accepted dual process theories of cognition. Specifically, I suggest that political ignorance can be explained via a “default-interventionist” account in which a biased intuitive subsystem produces automatic responses which are overridden by rational reflection when the prospective costs of error are significant. This is consistent with rational ignorance and related theories of political ignorance and bias. Providing stronger psychological foundations for rational ignorance also suggests new ways in which the theory might be developed to increase its predictive, analytic, and evaluative power.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Caplan’s suggestion here is a precursor to the argument of this paper. Somin (2016, pp. 84–82, 92–97) provides a more detailed explanation of why it can be rational for people to hold beliefs which they recognize are not fully informed and rational and which could potentially change if they held more information. Caplan and Somin should both be considered important precursors to this paper, but neither connect their ideas to the dual process literature. This is the main contribution of this paper.

  2. “Linda is more likely to be a bank teller than she is to be a feminist bank teller, because every feminist bank teller is a bank teller, but some women bank tellers are not feminists, and Linda could be one of them” (Tversky and Kahneman 1983, p. 299).

  3. The analysis here is based on the formal work of Riker and Ordeshook (1968) and Gersbach (1995).

  4. The analysis could also be extended to the election of candidates, but there are some complicating factors which might make the effects of incentives and feedback different in each case. On one hand, voters can use shortcuts such as candidate party to judge ideological position and simplify voting choices (Lupia 1994; Lupia and McCubbins 1998; Popkin 1995). This would lower the cognitive effort required to reach a better decision. On the other hand, candidates bundle many policies together and this complicates any calculus of instrumental benefits while also limiting learning opportunities with respect to particular issues. The very general conclusion of this paper applies to both issue-based and candidate-based voting, although the strength of incentives and feedback could differ quite a lot. An analysis of these effects would, I think, require careful empirical analysis.

  5. It should be noted that these authors interpret their results as showing that partisan bias is not sincere. This is a possible interpretation, but a dual process interpretation is more plausible given our other psychological knowledge and introspective evidence which suggests partisans really do disagree on matters of fact. See also Prior and Lupia (2008) on the effect of incentives and learning opportunities on survey measurements of political knowledge.

References

  • Alter, A. L., Oppenheimer, D. M., Epley, N., & Eyre, R. N. (2007). Overcoming intuition: Metacognitive difficulty activates analytic reasoning. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General,136(4), 569–576. https://doi.org/10.1037/0096-3445.136.4.569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bar-Hillel, M. (1980). The base-rate fallacy in probability judgments. Acta Psychologica,44(3), 211–233.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bennett, S. E., & Friedman, J. (2008). The irrelevance of economic theory to understanding economic ignorance. Critical Review,20(3), 195–258.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bullock, J. G., Gerber, A. S., Hill, S. J., & Huber, G. A. (2015). Partisan bias in factual beliefs about politics. Quarterly Journal of Political Science,10(4), 519–578.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. F., & Hogarth, R. M. (1999). The effects of financial incentives in experiments: A review and capital-labor-production framework. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty,19(1–3), 7–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. F., & Kunreuther, H. (1989). Decision processes for low probability events: Policy implications. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management,8(4), 565–592.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caplan, B. (2007). The myth of the rational voter. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D. (2001). Rational ignorance, rational voter expectations, and public policy: A discrete informational foundation for fiscal illusion. Public Choice,107(1–2), 35–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D. (2019). Behavioral economics and the Virginia school of political economy: Overlaps and complementarities. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00679-3.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cummings, R. G., Elliott, S., Harrison, G. W., & Murphy, J. (1997). Are hypothetical referenda incentive compatible? Journal of Political Economy,105(3), 609–621.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, S. (2018). Populism and fiscal illusion. Australian Economic Review,51(3), 418–425. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8462.12296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dennett, D. C. (1991). Real patterns. The Journal of Philosophy,88(1), 27–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Druckman, J. N. (2001). The implications of framing effects for citizen competence. Political Behavior,23(3), 225–256. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1015006907312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J., & Landemore, H. (2008). Ideology and dystopia. Critical Review,20(3), 273–289.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, J. S. (2007). Hypothetical thinking: Dual processes in reasoning and judgement (Vol. 3). London: Psychology Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, A. J., & Friedman, J. (2011). “search” Vs. “browse”: A theory of error grounded in radical (not Rational) ignorance. Critical Review,23(1–2), 73–104. https://doi.org/10.1080/08913811.2011.574471.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, A., Goh, J., & White, B. (2012). The effect of performance-based incentive contracts on system 1 and system 2 processing in affective decision contexts: FMRI and behavioral evidence. Available at SSRN 2111452. Retrieved November 20, 2019, from http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2111452.

  • Farrell, A. M., Goh, J. O., & White, B. J. (2014). The effect of performance-based incentive contracts on system 1 and system 2 processing in affective decision contexts: FMRI and behavioral evidence. The Accounting Review,89(6), 1979–2010. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-50852.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, A. J. (1996). A further experimental study of expressive voting. Public Choice,88(1), 171–184.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischhoff, B., Slovic, P., Lichtenstein, S., Read, S., & Combs, B. (1978). How safe is safe enough? A psychometric study of attitudes towards technological risks and benefits. Policy Sciences,9(2), 127–152.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1953). The methodology of positive economics. Essays in positive economics (pp. 3–47). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gelman, A., Silver, N., & Edlin, A. (2009). What is the probability your vote will make a difference? Economic Inquiry,50(2), 321–326. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1465-7295.2010.00272.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gersbach, H. (1995). Information efficiency and majority decisions. Social Choice and Welfare,12(4), 363–370. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00186280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, D. T. (1999). What the mind’s not. In S. Chaiken & Y. Trope (Eds.), Dual-process theories in social psychology (pp. 3–11). New York: Guilford Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grewenig, E., Lergetporer, P., Werner, K., & Smarzynska Javorcik, B. (2019). Incentives, search engines, and the elicitation of subjective beliefs: Evidence from representative online survey experiments (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID 3357133). Retrieved November 20, 2019, from Social Science Research Network website: https://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=3357133.

  • Hindmoor, A. M., & Taylor, B. R. (2015). Rational choice (2nd ed.). Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jamal, K., & Sunder, S. (1991). Money vs gaming: Effects of salient monetary payments in double oral auctions. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes,49(1), 151–166. https://doi.org/10.1016/0749-5978(91)90046-V.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, fast and slow. New York: Farrar Straus & Giroux.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Frederick, S. (2002). Representativeness revisited: Attribute substitution in intuitive judgment. In T. Gilovich, D. Griffin, & D. Kahneman (Eds.), Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment (pp. 49–81). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Peavler, W. S. (1969). Incentive effects and pupillary changes in association learning. Journal of Experimental Psychology,79(2p1), 312.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klayman, J. (1995). Varieties of confirmation bias. Psychology of Learning and Motivation,32, 385–418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klayman, J., & Ha, Y.-W. (1987). Confirmation, disconfirmation, and information in hypothesis testing. Psychological Review,94(2), 211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krupnikov, Y., Levine, A. S., Lupia, A., & Prior, M. (2006). Public ignorance and estate tax repeal: The effect of partisan differences and survey incentives. National Tax Journal,59(3), 425–437.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kunda, Z. (1990). The case for motivated reasoning. Psychological Bulletin,108(3), 480–498.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kunreuther, H., Meyer, R., Zeckhauser, R., Slovic, P., Schwartz, B., Schade, C., et al. (2002). High stakes decision making: Normative, descriptive and prescriptive considerations. Marketing Letters,13(3), 259–268.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, J. (2007). Repetition and financial incentives in economics experiments. Journal of Economic Surveys,21(3), 628–681. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6419.2007.00516.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Libby, R., & Lipe, M. G. (1992). Incentives, effort, and the cognitive processes involved in accounting-related judgments. Journal of Accounting Research,30(2), 249–273.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lodge, M., & Taber, C. S. (2000). Three steps toward a theory of motivated political reasoning. In A. Lupia, M. D. McCubbins, & S. Popkin (Eds.), Elements of reason: Cognition, choice, and the bounds of rationality (pp. 183–213). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G. F., Weber, E. U., Hsee, C. K., & Welch, N. (2001). Risk as feelings. Psychological Bulletin,127(2), 267–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lupia, A. (1994). Shortcuts versus encyclopedias: Information and voting behavior in California insurance reform elections. American Political Science Review,88(1), 63–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lupia, A., & McCubbins, M. D. (1998). The democratic dilemma: Can citizens learn what they need to know?. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mackie, G. (2012). Rational ignorance and beyond. In H. Landemore & J. Elster (Eds.), Collective wisdom: Principles and mechanisms (pp. 290–318). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morewedge, C. K., & Kahneman, D. (2010). Associative processes in intuitive judgment. Trends in Cognitive Sciences,14(10), 435–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morton, R. B. (1999). Methods and models: A guide to the empirical analysis of formal models in political science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, R. H. (2016). The willingness-to-pay for Caplanian irrationality. Rationality and Society,28(1), 52–82. https://doi.org/10.1177/1043463115605478.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Popkin, S. L. (1995). Information shortcuts and the reasoning voter. In B. Grofman (Ed.), Information, participation and choice: An economic theory of democracy in perspective (pp. 17–35). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prato, C., & Wolton, S. (2018). Rational ignorance, populism, and reform. European Journal of Political Economy,55, 119–135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prior, M., & Lupia, A. (2008). Money, time, and political knowledge: Distinguishing quick recall and political learning skills. American Journal of Political Science,52(1), 169–183. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00306.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prior, M., Sood, G., & Khanna, K. (2015). You cannot be serious: The impact of accuracy incentives on partisan bias in reports of economic perceptions. Quarterly Journal of Political Science,10(4), 489–518.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. H., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1968). A theory of the calculus of voting. The American Political Science Review,62(1), 25–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (2003). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shanks, D. R., Tunney, R. J., & McCarthy, J. D. (2002). A re-examination of probability matching and rational choice. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making,15(3), 233–250. https://doi.org/10.1002/bdm.413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shayo, M., & Harel, A. (2012). Non-consequentialist voting. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,81(1), 299–313. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2011.10.021.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slovic, P., Finucane, M., Peters, E., & MacGregor, D. G. (2002). Rational actors or rational fools: Implications of the affect heuristic for behavioral economics. Journal of Socio-Economics,31(4), 329–342.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slovic, P., Finucane, M. L., Peters, E., & MacGregor, D. G. (2007). The affect heuristic. European Journal of Operational Research,177(3), 1333–1352.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L. (2008). Rationality in economics: Constructivst and ecological forms. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L., & Walker, J. M. (1993a). Monetary rewards and decision cost in experimental economics. Economic Inquiry,31(2), 245–261.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L., & Walker, J. M. (1993b). Rewards, experience and decision costs in first price auctions. Economic Inquiry,31(2), 237–244.

    Google Scholar 

  • Somin, I. (2016). Democracy and political ignorance: Why smaller government is smarter (2nd ed.). Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stanovich, K. E. (1999). Who is rational?: Studies of individual differences in reasoning. Mahwah: Elrbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1961). The economics of information. The Journal of Political Economy,69(3), 213–225.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taber, C. S., & Lodge, M. (2006). Motivated skepticism in the evaluation of political beliefs. American Journal of Political Science,50(3), 755–769.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taber, C. S., Lodge, M., & Glathar, J. (2001). The motivated construction of political judgments. In J. H. Kuklinski (Ed.), Citizens and politics: Perspectives from political psychology (pp. 198–226). London: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1973). Availability: A heuristic for judging frequency and probability. Cognitive Psychology,5(2), 207–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science,185(4157), 1124–1131. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.185.4157.1124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1981). The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science,211(4481), 453.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1983). Extensional versus intuitive reasoning: The conjunction fallacy in probability judgment. Psychological Review,90(4), 293.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1986). Rational choice and the framing of decisions. Journal of Business,59(S4), 251.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Simonson, I. (1993). Context-dependent preferences. Management Science,39(10), 1179–1189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (1976). Revenue structure, fiscal illusion, and budgetary choice. Public Choice,25(1), 45–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E., & Weber, W. E. (1977). Wagner’s law, fiscal institutions, and the growth of government. National Tax Journal,30(1), 59–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winkielman, P., Zajonc, R. B., & Schwarz, N. (1997). Subliminal affective priming resists attributional interventions. Cognition and Emotion,11(4), 433–465.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1989). Why democracies produce efficient results. The Journal of Political Economy,97(6), 1395–1424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1995). The myth of democratic failure: Why political institutions are efficient. Chicago: University of Chicago press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Brad R. Taylor.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Taylor, B.R. The psychological foundations of rational ignorance: biased heuristics and decision costs. Const Polit Econ 31, 70–88 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-019-09292-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-019-09292-4

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation