Skip to main content
Log in

Value of loan credit insurance in the capital-constrained supply chain

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Supply chain finance (SCF) solutions open financing channels for small and medium-sized suppliers. However, in uncertain market conditions, payment defaults by supply chain members may affect SCF systems sustainability. To mitigate default risks, financial service providers utilize loan credit insurance (LCI) to transfer the risk to insurers. LCI, purchased by lenders, covers unpaid losses resulting from debtor insolvency, bankruptcy, or political upheaval. In case retailers fail to meet payment obligations, insurers will compensate the lender within the policy terms. Using a game-theoretical approach, we examine LCI’s value for lenders and capital-constrained suppliers. We find that lenders benefit from LCI with higher insurance deductibles and lower insurer loading factors. Moreover, capital-constrained suppliers with higher capital investments and lower production costs can benefit from LCI. Furthermore, suppliers are more likely to obtain extra profits when the insurance scale and loading factor are relatively low. However, when the insurance scale and loading factor are relatively high, the supplier’s capacity investment efficiency is greater. Numerical analysis indicates that LCI with relatively high coverage is advantageous for lenders, particularly full coverage. Another numerical finding is that when the insurance scale is large and the loading factor is high, suppliers achieve greater cost contribution efficiency. Our study highlights LCI’s value in capital-constrained supply chains, benefiting both lenders and suppliers by enhancing profits and encouraging suppliers to increase capital investment and reduce costs. It underscores the role of lender-purchased credit insurance in SCF risk management, providing theoretical support and practical guidance for LCI implementations in commercial financial institutions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Agca, S., Birge, J.-R., Wang, Z., & Wu, J. (2023). The impact of covid-19 on supply chain credit risk. Production and Operations Management, 32(12), 4088–4113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • AIG. (2023). Aig: Trade credit insurance. Accessed from https://www.aig.com/home/risk-solutions/business/specialty-risks/trade-credit, Accessed on April 15, 2023.

  • Allianz. (2023). Allianz: Solutions for Banks and Financial Institutions. Accessed from https://www.allianz-trade.com/en_global/our-solutions/credit-protection-for-banks-and-financial-institutions.html, Accessed on April 15, 2023.

  • Atradius. (2022). Us: Dso Worries Prompt Strategic Credit Management. Accessed from https://atradius.cn/zh/reports/payment-practices-barometer-us-dso-worries-prompt-strategic-credit-management.html, Accessed on April 15, 2023.

  • Auboin, M., & Engemann, M. (2014). Testing the trade credit and trade link: evidence from data on export credit insurance. Review of World Economics, 150, 715–743.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bazzana, F., De Laurentis, G., Pisani, R., & Trinca Colonel, R. (2020). Can domestic trade credit insurance contracts be effective collateral for banks? a quantitative study of the italian market. The European Journal of Finance, 26(13), 1239–1252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berneunion. (2020). Robust Response to the covid-19 Pandemic From the Export Credit Insurance Industry. Accessed from https://www.berneunion.org/Articles/Details/506/Robust-response-to-the-COVID-19-pandemic-from-the-export-credit-insurance-industry, Accessed on April 15, 2023.

  • Berneunion. (2021). How Credit Insurance Supports Trade and the Real Economy. Accessed from https://www.berneunion.org/Articles/Details/529/How-credit-insurance-Howcreditinsurancesupportstradeandtherealeconomy, Accessed on April 15, 2023.

  • Broughton, K. (2022). Companies Offer Supply-Chain Financing to Vendors as They Bulk Up on Inventory, Push Out Payment Terms. Accessed from https://www.wsj.com/articles/companies-offer-supply-chain-financing-to-vendors-as-they-bulk-up-on-inventory-push-out-payment-terms-11658316600, Accessed on April 15, 2023.

  • Buzacott, J.-A., & Zhang, R.-Q. (2004). Inventory management with asset-based financing. Management Science, 50(9), 1274–1292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cachon, G.-P. (2004). The allocation of inventory risk in a supply chain: Push, pull, and advance-purchase discount contracts. Management science, 50(2), 222–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chod, J. (2017). Inventory, risk shifting, and trade credit. Management Science, 63(10), 3207–3225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dada, M., & Hu, Q. (2008). Financing newsvendor inventory. Operations Research Letters, 36(5), 569–573.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deng, S., Gu, C., Cai, G., & Li, Y. (2018). Financing multiple heterogeneous suppliers in assembly systems: Buyer finance vs. bank finance. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management., 20(1), 53–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dong, L., & Zhu, K. (2007). Two-wholesale-price contracts: Push, pull, and advance-purchase discount contracts. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 9(3), 291–311.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • EIA. (2023). Eia Global: Credit Insurance. Accessed from http://eia-global.com/credit-insurance-insurance-for-banks-lenders-investors/, Accessed on April 15, 2023.

  • Felbermayr, G.-J., & Yalcin, E. (2013). Export credit guarantees and export performance: An empirical analysis for germany. The World Economy, 36(8), 967–999.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaffney, C., & Ben-Israel, A. (2016). A simple insurance model: Optimal coverage and deductible. Annals of Operations Research, 237(1–2), 263–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hofmann, E. (2005). Supply chain finance: some conceptual insights. In R.-L.-C.-G. Janker (Ed.), Logistik Management - Innovative Logistikkonzepte Logistik Management - Innovative Logistikkonzepte (pp. 203–214). Wiesbaden: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, B., Wu, A., & Chiang, D. (2018). Supporting small suppliers through buyer-backed purchase order financing. International Journal of Production Research, 56(18), 6066–6089.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jain, R., Reindorp, M., & Chockalingam, A. (2023). Buyer-backed purchase-order financing for SME supplier with uncertain yield. European Journal of Operational Research, 307(2), 758–772.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jing, B., Chen, X., & Cai, G. (2012). Equilibrium financing in a distribution channel with capital constraint. Production and Operations Management, 21(6), 1090–1101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kouvelis, P., & Xu, F. (2021). A supply chain theory of factoring and reverse factoring. Management Science, 67(10), 6071–6088.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kouvelis, P., & Zhao, W. (2012). Financing the newsvendor: Supplier vs. bank, and the structure of optimal trade credit contracts. Operations Research., 60(3), 566–580.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kroll, Y., & Cohen, A. (2013). Optimum pricing of mutual guarantees for credit. Small Business Economics, 41, 253–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuzak, D., & Larsen, T. (2005). Use of catastrophe models in insurance rate making. In P. Grossi & H. Kunreuther (Eds.), Catastrophe modeling: A new approach to managing risk (pp. 97–118). Boston, MA: Springer US.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lai, V.-S., & Soumaré, I. (2010). Credit insurance and investment: A contingent claims analysis approach. International Review of Financial Analysis, 19(2), 98–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lariviere, M.-A., & Porteus, E.-L. (2001). Selling to the newsvendor: An analysis of price-only contracts. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 3(4), 293–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, H., Bi, G., Song, W., & Yuan, X. (2022). Trade credit insurance: insuring strategy of the retailer and the manufacturer. International Journal of Production Research, 60(5), 1478–1499.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Y., Zhen, X., & Cai, X. (2016). Trade credit insurance, capital constraint, and the behavior of manufacturers and banks. Annals of Operations Research, 240, 395–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moser, C., Nestmann, T., & Wedow, M. (2008). Political risk and export promotion: evidence from germany. World Economy, 31(6), 781–803.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pfohl, H.-C., & Gomm, M. (2009). Supply chain finance: Optimizing financial flows in supply chains. Logistics Research, 1, 149–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • PrimeRevenue. (2022). The Financial Blueprint Annual Report 2022. Accessed from https://primerevenue.com/resources/white-papers/the-financial-blueprint-annual-report-2022/, Accessed on April 15, 2023.

  • Reindorp, M., Tanrisever, F., & Lange, A. (2018). Purchase order financing: Credit, commitment, and supply chain consequences. Operations Research, 66(5), 1287–1303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schlesinger, H. (2000). The theory of insurance demand. In G. Dionne (Ed.), Handbook of Insurance Handbook of insurance (pp. 131–151). Dordrecht: Springer Netherlands.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Schlesinger, H. (2006). Mossin’s theorem for upper-limit insurance policies. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 73(2), 297–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Serpa, J.-C., & Krishnan, H. (2017). The strategic role of business insurance. Management Science, 63(2), 384–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • SINOSURE. (2023). China export & credit insurance corporation: Insurance based financing. Accessed from https://sinosure.com.cn/en/mb/ibf/index.shtml, Accessed on April 15, 2023.

  • Tang, C.-S., Yang, S.-A., & Wu, J. (2018). Sourcing from suppliers with financial constraints and performance risk. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 20(1), 70–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van den Berg, M., Van Beveren, I., Lemmers, O., Span, T., & Walker, A.-N. (2019). Public export credit insurance in the netherlands: An input-output approach. The World Economy, 42(9), 2774–2789.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Veer, K.-J. (2015). The private export credit insurance effect on trade. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 82(3), 601–624.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, J., Zhang, Q., & Hou, P. (2022). Implications of credit default and yield uncertainty on supply chain’s equilibrium financial strategy. Annals of Operations Research, 315(1), 507–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, K., Zhao, R., & Peng, J. (2018). Trade credit contracting under asymmetric credit default risk: Screening, checking or insurance. European Journal of Operational Research, 266(2), 554–568.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, W., & Cai, G.-G. (2023). Curtailing bank loan and loan insurance under risk regulations in supply chain finance. Management Science, Forthcoming.https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2023.4827

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yan, N., Jin, X., Zhong, H., & Xu, X. (2020). Loss-averse retailers’ financial offerings to capital-constrained suppliers: Loan vs. investment. International Journal of Production Economics, 227, 107665.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, S.-A., Bakshi, N., & Chen, C.-J. (2021). Trade credit insurance: Operational value and contract choice. Management Science, 67(2), 875–891.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, S.-A., & Birge, J.-R. (2018). Trade credit, risk sharing, and inventory financing portfolios. Management Science, 64(8), 3667–3689.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, Y., Li, P., Yang, S.-A., & Huang, S. (2022). Inventory financing under Risk-Adjusted-Return-On-Capital criterion. Naval Research Logistics, 69(1), 92–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou, C., Wu, W., & Wu, C. (2010). Optimal insurance in the presence of insurer’s loss limit. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 46(2), 300–307.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhu, Y., Zhou, L., Xie, C., Wang, G.-J., & Nguyen, T.-V. (2019). Forecasting SMEs’ credit risk in supply chain finance with an enhanced hybrid ensemble machine learning approach. International Journal of Production Economics, 211, 22–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

All the authors contributed equally to this work. All the authors are co-first authors of this paper. The authors are grateful to the editors and referees for their valuable comments and suggestions to improve the quality and presentation of the paper. This work is supported by National Natural Science Foundation of China (72271252, 71872200, 71901229), General Project of Shaanxi Provincial Philosophy and Social Sciences Major Theoretical and Practical Issues Research (2022ND0185), Youth Scholar Support Project of Central University of Finance and Economics(QYP2206), and Graduate Academic Incubation Program of Central University of Finance and Economics (202302).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kin Keung Lai.

Ethics declarations

Human or animal rights

This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices: Proofs

Appendices: Proofs

1.1 Proof of Lemma 1

According to Eq. (2) and taking the first-order derivative of \(\Pi _s\) with respect to q, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\Pi _s}{dq}=w\bar{F}\left( q\right) -\frac{c}{1-r}\bar{F}\left( {\hat{x}}_3\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Subsequently, according to the supplier’s first-order condition (FOC), let \(d\Pi _s/dq=0\); we then have \(w (1-r) \bar{F}\left( q\right) =c \bar{F}\left( {\hat{x}}_3\right) .\) We can prove that \(\bar{F}\left( q\right) < \bar{F}\left( {\hat{x}}_3\right) \) because \(F\left( \cdot \right) \) is a strictly increasing function and \(q > B/w\). Thus, \(c< w (1-r) < w\).

Furthermore, by taking the second-order derivative of \(\Pi _s\) with respect to q, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d^2\Pi _s}{dq^2}={\left( \frac{c}{1-r}\right) }^2f\left( \hat{x}_3\right) -wf\left( q\right) . \end{aligned}$$

By substituting the supplier’s FOC into \({d^2\Pi _s}/{dq^2}\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{d^2\Pi _s}{dq^2}&=\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_3\right) \left[ \left( \frac{c}{1-r}\right) ^2 \frac{h\left( \hat{x}_3\right) }{w}-w h\left( q\right) {\frac{\bar{F}\left( q\right) }{\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_3\right) }}\right] \\&=\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_3\right) \frac{c}{1-r} \left[ \frac{c}{w\left( 1-r\right) } h\left( \hat{x}_3\right) -h\left( q\right) \right] . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Based on the IFR assumption of the demand function, we have \(h\left( \hat{x}_3\right) < h\left( q\right) \) because \(\hat{x}_3 < q\). We have derived that \(w (1-r) > c\), thus, we have \({d^2\Pi _s}/{dq^2}<0\)\(\Pi _s\) is a concave function in terms of q at \(d\Pi _s/dq=0\). Therefore, the supplier’s best response under the given w and r is

$$\begin{aligned} w\bar{F} \left( q^*\right) =\frac{c}{1-r}\bar{F} \left( {\hat{x}}_3\right) \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

1.2 Proof of Lemma 2

According to Eq. (3), and the end of Eq. (A.1), by taking the first-order derivative of \(\Pi _r\) with respect to w yields

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\Pi _r}{dw}=\left( 1-w\right) \frac{\partial q^*}{\partial w} \bar{F}\left( q^*\right) - \int _{0}^{q^*}\bar{F}\left( x\right) dx. \end{aligned}$$

we denote \(\Omega _1=\frac{\partial q^*}{\partial w}\). By differentiating both sides of Eq.(A.1) with respect to w, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{F}\left( q^*\right) - w \Omega _1 f\left( q^*\right) = -\frac{c}{1-r} \frac{\partial \hat{x}_3}{\partial w} f\left( \hat{x}_3\right) , \end{aligned}$$

where \(\frac{\partial \hat{x}_3}{\partial w}=\left( \frac{c}{1-r}\Omega _1-\frac{B}{w}\right) /w\), Substituting the supplier’s FOC for simplicity, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} {\Omega }_1&=\frac{\bar{F}\left( q^*\right) -\frac{cB}{(1-r)w^2} f\left( \hat{x}_3\right) }{wf\left( q^*\right) -\left( \frac{c}{1-r}\right) ^2\frac{f\left( \hat{x}_3\right) }{w}} =\frac{1-\frac{cB}{(1-r)w^2}\frac{\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_3\right) }{\bar{F}(q^*)}h\left( \hat{x}_3\right) }{w h(q^*)-\left( \frac{c}{1-r}\right) ^2\frac{h\left( \hat{x}_3\right) }{w} \frac{\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_3\right) }{\bar{F}(q^*)}}\\&=\frac{1-H\left( {\hat{x}}_3\right) }{w h\left( q^*\right) -c h\left( {\hat{x}}_3\right) /(1-r)}. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Based on the properties of the IFR distribution, we have \(1-H\left( {\hat{x}}_3\right) > 0\). As we have proven that \(w (1-r) > c\) and \(h\left( \hat{x}_3\right) < h\left( q\right) \) in the proof of Lemma 1, we obtain \(w h\left( q^*\right) -c h\left( {\hat{x}}_3\right) /(1-r)>0\). Therefore, \(\Omega _1=\frac{\partial q^*}{\partial w}>0\).

Subsequently, according to FOC and letting \(d\Pi _r/dw=0\), the retailer’s optimal procurement price satisfies

$$\begin{aligned} \left( 1-w^*\right) \frac{\partial q^*}{\partial w} \bar{F}\left( q^*\right) = \int _{0}^{q^*}\bar{F}\left( x\right) dx. \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

1.3 Proof of Lemma 3

Similar to the proof of Lemma 2, according to Eq. (4), and Eq. (A.1), taking the first-order derivative of \(\Pi _f\) with respect to r yields

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\Pi _f}{dr} = \frac{\partial B}{\partial r} \{r + \theta \left[ F\left( \hat{x}_1\right) -F\left( \hat{x}_2\right) \right] - F\left( \hat{x}_3\right) \} + B, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\frac{\partial B}{\partial r}= \frac{c}{1-r} \frac{\partial q^*}{\partial r} + \frac{B}{1-r}\).

For notational simplification, we denote \(\Omega _2=\frac{\partial B}{\partial r}\) and \(\Omega _3=\frac{\partial q^*}{\partial r}\). By differentiating both sides of Eq.(A.1) with respect to r, we have

$$\begin{aligned} -w \Omega _3 f\left( q^*\right) = \frac{c}{(1-r)^2} \bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_3\right) - \frac{c}{w(1-r)} \Omega _2 f\left( \hat{x}_3\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Substituting the supplier’s FOC for simplicity, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \Omega _3&=\frac{c \bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_3\right) - cB f\left( \hat{x}_3\right) /w}{c^2 f\left( \hat{x}_3\right) /w- w\left( 1-r\right) ^2 f(q^*)} =\frac{c-cB h\left( {\hat{x}}_3\right) /w}{c^2 h\left( {\hat{x}}_3\right) /w - w\left( 1-r\right) ^2 h(q^*) \frac{\bar{F}(q^*)}{\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_3\right) }}\\&=\frac{1-H\left( {\hat{x}}_3\right) }{{ch\left( {\hat{x}}_3\right) }/{w}-(1-r)h\left( q^*\right) }. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Subsequently, according to the supplier’s FOC condition and letting \({d\Pi _f}/{dr}=0\), the lender’s optimal interest rate satisfies

$$\begin{aligned} r^*=\{F\left( {\hat{x}}_3\right) +\theta \left[ F\left( {\hat{x}}_2\right) -F\left( {\hat{x}}_1\right) \right] \}-{{B}/{\Omega _2}} \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

1.4 Proof of Corollary 1

  1. (1)

    Based on \(\Omega _1\) and \(\Omega _3\) that we deduced in the proof of Lemma 2 and Lemma 3, we find the denominators of \(\Omega _1\) and \(\Omega _3\) have the opposite sign because \(\Omega _1=-(1-r)\Omega _3/w\). In the proof of Lemma 2, we have \(\Omega _1>0\). Thus, we can easily verify \(\Omega _3=\frac{\partial q^*}{\partial r}<0\).

  2. (2)

    Substituting the formula of \(\Omega _3\) into \(\Omega _2=\frac{\partial B}{\partial r}= \frac{c}{1-r} \frac{\partial q^*}{\partial r} + \frac{B}{1-r}\), we have

    $$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \Omega _2&=\frac{c\left[ 1-H\left( \hat{x}_3\right) \right] }{c(1-r)h\left( \hat{x}_3\right) /w-(1-r)^2h(q^*)}+\frac{B}{1-r}\\&=\frac{c-(1-r)Bh(q^*)}{(1-r)\left[ ch\left( \hat{x}_3\right) /w-(1-r)h(q^*)\right] } \\&=\frac{c\left[ 1-(q^*-k/c)h(q^*)\right] }{(1-r)\left[ ch\left( \hat{x}_3\right) /w-(1-r)h(q^*)\right] }\\&>\frac{c\left[ 1-H(q^*)\right] }{(1-r)\left[ ch\left( \hat{x}_3\right) /w-(1-r)h(q^*)\right] }. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

    Based on the properties of the IFR distribution, we have \(1-H(q^*) > 0\). Since we have proved that \(w (1-r) > c\) and \(h\left( \hat{x}_3\right) < h\left( q\right) \) in the proof of Lemma 1, we obtain \(ch\left( \hat{x}_3\right) /w-(1-r)h(q^*)<0\). Thus, we have \(\Omega _2=\frac{\partial B}{\partial r}<0\). Next, we simplify Eq.(A.3) into \(B=\Omega _2 \{F\left( \hat{x}_3\right) -\theta \left[ F\left( \hat{x}_1\right) -F\left( \hat{x}_2\right) \right] -r^*\}\). We can deduce that \(F\left( \hat{x}_3\right) -\theta \left[ F\left( \hat{x}_1\right) -F\left( \hat{x}_2\right) \right] -r^*<0\) because \(\Omega _2<0\) and \(B>0\) hold. Since \(\hat{x}_1<\hat{x}_2\) and the increasing demand CDF, we have \(F\left( \hat{x}_1\right) -F\left( \hat{x}_2\right) <0\). Thus, we obtain the restriction for the loading factor, \(\theta < \frac{r^*-F\left( \hat{x}_3\right) }{F\left( \hat{x}_2\right) -F\left( \hat{x}_1\right) }\).

  3. (3)

    Taking the partial derivative with respect to k on both sides of Eq.(A.1), we have

    $$\begin{aligned} -w^2\frac{\partial q^*}{\partial k} f(q^*)=-\left( \frac{c}{1-r}\right) ^2 \frac{\partial q^*}{\partial k} f\left( \hat{x}_3\right) + \frac{c}{(1-r)^2} f\left( \hat{x}_3\right) \end{aligned}$$

    . Additionally, substituting Eq.(A.1) into the above formula and simplifying, we have

    $$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial q^*}{\partial k}&=\frac{cf\left( \hat{x}_3\right) }{c^2 f\left( \hat{x}_3\right) - w^2 (1-r)^2 f(q^*)} =\frac{cf\left( \hat{x}_3\right) }{\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_3\right) \left[ c^2 h\left( \hat{x}_3\right) -w^2 (1-r)^2 h(q^*) \frac{\bar{F}(q^*)}{\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_3\right) }\right] }\\&=\frac{h\left( \hat{x}_3\right) }{ch\left( \hat{x}_3\right) -w(1-r)h(q^*)} \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

    Therefore, we have \( {\partial q^*}/{\partial k} <0\) for \(h\left( \hat{x}_3\right) >0\) and \(ch\left( \hat{x}_3\right) -w(1-r)h(q^*)<0\).

1.5 Proof of Proposition 1

According to Eq. (4) and the lender’s profit function in the benchmark, we calculate the lender’s profit difference between the LCI scheme and benchmark.

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta \Pi _f=\Pi _f^*- \Pi _f^{N*}=Br^*- w^*\theta \int ^{\hat{x} _2}_{\hat{x}_1} {F\left( x\right) }dxw^*\ int^{\hat{x}_3} _0{F\left( x\right) }dx - B^N {r^N}^* + {w^N} ^*\int ^{{\hat{x}}^N_3} _0 F\left( x\right) dx. \end{aligned}$$

For notational simplification, let \(Y(x)=\int ^x_0 F(x)dx\), which is a monotonically increasing function because \(dY(x)/dx=F(x)>0\). Thus, the necessary condition for the lender to benefit from LCI (i.e., \(\Delta \Pi _f \ge 0\)) is

$$\begin{aligned} Br^*-w^*\theta \left[ Y\left( \hat{x} _2\right) -Y\left( \hat{x} _1\right) \right] - w^* Y\left( \hat{x}_3\right) >B^N {r^N}^* - {w^N} ^*Y\left( \hat{x} _3^N\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)

The condition Eq. (A.4) can be rewritten as \(Y\left( \hat{x}_2\right) <\frac{1}{\theta w^*}\mathscr {A}_1+Y\left( \hat{x}_1\right) \). If \(\frac{1}{\theta w^*}\mathscr {A}_1+Y\left( \hat{x}_1\right) \ge 0\), we have \(\hat{x}_2<Y^{-1}\left[ \frac{1}{\theta w^*}\mathscr {A}_1+Y\left( \hat{x}_1\right) \right] \) since \(Y^{-1}(x)\) has the same monotonicity as Y(x). Thus, the condition can be simplified to \(d>B-w^*Y^{-1}\left[ \frac{1}{\theta w^*}\mathscr {A}_1+Y\left( \hat{x}_1\right) \right] \). If \(\frac{1}{\theta w^*}\mathscr {A}_1+Y\left( \hat{x}_1\right) <0\), this condition does not hold because \(Y\left( \hat{x}_2\right) \ge 0 > \frac{1}{\theta w^*}\mathscr {A}_1+Y\left( \hat{x}_1\right) \).

Hence, let \(\mathscr {A}_1={\left[ Br^*-w^*Y\left( {\hat{x}}_3\right) -{B^N}{r^N}^*+w^*Y\left( {\hat{x}}^N_3\right) \right] }/{w^*\theta }+Y\left( {\hat{x}}_1\right) \), if \(\mathscr {A}_1 \ge 0\). There exists a threshold

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{d}=B-w^*Y^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_1\right) , \end{aligned}$$

for which \(d\ge \hat{d}\) is the value of LCI for the lender \(\Delta \Pi _f \ge 0\). Otherwise, the value of LCI for the lender is \(\Delta \Pi _f < 0\).

From the perspective of the loading factor, Eq. (A.4) can be rewritten as \(w^*\theta \left[ Y\left( \hat{x} _2\right) -Y\left( \hat{x} _1\right) \right] \le Br^*- w^*Y\left( {\hat{x}} _3\right) -{B^N}{r^N} ^*+w{N^*} Y\left( {\hat{x}} ^N_3\right) \). Clearly, \(\left[ Y\left( \hat{x}_2\right) -Y\left( \hat{x}_1\right) \right] >0\) because \(\hat{x}_2>\hat{x}_1\). Then, the value-added condition can be simplified as \(\theta \le \frac{Br^*- w^*Y\left( {\hat{x}} _3\right) -{B^N}{r^N} ^*+w^{N*} Y\left( {\hat{x}} ^N_3\right) }{w^* \left[ Y\left( \hat{x} _2\right) -Y\left( \hat{x} _1\right) \right] }\). Therefore, there exists a threshold

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\theta }=\frac{Br^*- w^*Y\left( {\hat{x}} _3\right) -{B^N}{r^N} ^*+w^{N*} Y\left( {\hat{x}} ^N_3\right) }{w^* \left[ Y\left( \hat{x} _2\right) -Y\left( \hat{x} _1\right) \right] }, \end{aligned}$$

When \(\theta \le \hat{\theta }\), the value of LCI for the lender is \(\Delta \Pi _f \ge 0\). Otherwise, when \(\theta > \hat{\theta }\), the value of LCI for the lender is \(\Delta \Pi _f < 0\).

1.6 Proof of Proposition 2

According to Eq. (2) and the supplier’s profit function in the benchmark, and calculating the supplier’s profit difference between the LCI scheme and the benchmark, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta \Pi _s=\Pi _s^*- \Pi _s^{N*} =w^*\int ^q_{\hat{x}_3} {\bar{F}\left( x\right) }dx- {w^N}^*\int ^{{q^N}^*} _{{\hat{x}}^N_3}\bar{F} \left( x\right) dx. \end{aligned}$$

To simplify the notation, let \(S(x)=\int ^x_0 \bar{F}(x)dx\) be a monotonically increasing function because \(dS(x)/dx=\bar{F}(x)>0\). Thus, the necessary condition for the supplier to benefit from LCI (i.e., \(\Delta \Pi _s \ge 0\)) is

$$\begin{aligned} w^* S\left( \hat{x}_3\right) < {w^N}^* S\left( \hat{x}_3^N\right) +w^* S\left( q^*\right) - {w^N}^* S\left( {q^N}^*\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)

If \({w^N}^* S\left( \hat{x}_3^N\right) +w^* S\left( q^*\right) - {w^N}^* S\left( {q^N}^*\right) \ge 0\), Eq. (A.5) can be rewritten as \(B \le w^* S^{-1}\{S(q^*)-\frac{{w^N}^*}{w^*} \left[ S\left( {q^N}^*\right) -S\left( \hat{x}_3^N\right) \right] \}\) since \(S^{-1}(x)\) has the same monotonicity as S(x). Thus, \(k \ge cq^*-(1-r^*)w^* S^{-1}\{S(q^*)-\frac{{w^N}^*}{w^*} \left[ S\left( {q^N}^*\right) -S\left( \hat{x}_3^N\right) \right] \}\). If \({w^N}^* S\left( \hat{x}_3^N\right) +w^* S\left( q^*\right) - {w^N}^* S\left( {q^N}^*\right) < 0\); the condition in Eq.(A.5) does not hold, because \(S\left( \hat{x}_3\right) \ge 0 > {w^N}^* S\left( \hat{x}_3^N\right) +w^* S\left( q^*\right) - {w^N}^* S\left( {q^N}^*\right) \).

Hence, let \(\mathscr {A}_2=S(q^*)-\frac{{w^N}^*}{w^*} \left[ S\left( {q^N}^*\right) -S\left( \hat{x}_3^N\right) \right] \). If \(\mathscr {A}_2 \ge 0\), there exists a threshold

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{k}=cq^*-(1-r^*)w^*S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) , \end{aligned}$$

that satisfies \(cq^*-\hat{k}>0\). When \(k\ge \hat{k}\), the value of LCI for the supplier \(\Delta \Pi _s \ge 0\). Otherwise, the value of LCI for the supplier \(\Delta \Pi _s < 0\).

1.7 Proof of Corollary 2

  1. (1)

    From the lender’s FOC condition in Eq. (A.3), we have

    $$\begin{aligned} 1-r^*=B/\Omega _2+\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_3\right) -\theta \left[ \bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_1\right) -\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_2\right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$

    Subsequently, substituting the equation above into the expression of \(\hat{k}\), we have

    $$\begin{aligned} \hat{k}=cq^*-\{B/\Omega _2+\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_3\right) -\theta \left[ \bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_1\right) -\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_2\right) \right] \}w^*S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) . \end{aligned}$$

    Taking the derivative of \(\hat{k}\) with respect to b yields

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \hat{k}}{\partial b}=S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) \theta w^* \frac{\partial \bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_1\right) }{\partial b}=\theta f\left( \hat{x}_1\right) S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) . \end{aligned}$$

    Thus, we can verify \(\frac{\partial \hat{k}}{\partial b}>0\) because \(S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) >0\).

  2. (2)

    Taking the derivative of \(\hat{k}\) with respect to d yields

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \hat{k}}{\partial d}=-S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) \theta w^* \frac{\partial \bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_2\right) }{\partial d}=-\theta f\left( \hat{x}_2\right) S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) . \end{aligned}$$

    Thus, it is easy to verify that \(\frac{\partial \hat{k}}{\partial d}<0\).

  3. (3)

    Taking the derivative of \(\hat{k}\) with respect to \(\theta \) yields

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \hat{k}}{\partial \theta }=w^* \left[ \bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_1\right) -\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_2\right) \right] S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) . \end{aligned}$$

    Therefore, we can deduce that \(\frac{\partial \hat{k}}{\partial \theta }>0\) because we have proved \(\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_1\right) -\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_2\right) >0\).

1.8 Proof of Corollary 3

  1. (1)

    Based on our definition, we have \(\eta =\frac{d{\Pi _s}^*}{dk}=\frac{\partial {\Pi _s}^*}{\partial q^*}\frac{dq^*}{dk}+\frac{\partial {\Pi _s}^*}{\partial k}\). According to the supplier’s FOC condition, the supplier’s optimal response \(q^*\) satisfies \(\frac{\partial {\Pi _s}^*}{\partial q^*}=0\). Thus, we have \(\eta =\frac{\partial {\Pi _s}^*}{\partial k}=\frac{1}{1-r^*} \bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_3\right) \). Substituting Eq.(A.3) into the above formula, we have

    $$\begin{aligned} \eta =1-\frac{B}{\Omega _2 \left( 1-r^*\right) }+\frac{\theta }{1-r^*}\left[ F\left( \hat{x}_2\right) -F\left( \hat{x}_1\right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$

    Taking the derivative of \(\eta \) with respect to b yields

    $$\begin{aligned} \eta =\frac{\partial \eta }{\partial b}=-\frac{\theta }{1-r^*}\frac{\partial \hat{x}_1}{\partial b} f\left( \hat{x}_1\right) =\frac{\theta }{w^*(1-r^*)}f\left( \hat{x}_1\right) >0. \end{aligned}$$
  2. (2)

    Taking the derivative of \(\eta \) with respect to b yields

    $$\begin{aligned} \eta =\frac{\partial \eta }{\partial d}=\frac{\theta }{1-r^*}\frac{\partial \hat{x}_2}{\partial d} f\left( \hat{x}_2\right) =-\frac{\theta }{w^*(1-r^*)}f\left( \hat{x}_2\right) <0. \end{aligned}$$
  3. (3)

    Taking the derivative of \(\eta \) with respect to b yields

    $$\begin{aligned} \eta =\frac{\partial \eta }{\partial \theta }=\frac{\left[ F\left( \hat{x}_2\right) -F\left( \hat{x}_1\right) \right] }{1-r^*}>0. \end{aligned}$$

1.9 Proof of Proposition 3

From the perspective of the supplier’s unit production cost and based on the supplier’s positive value condition in Eq. (A.5), we have \(B \le w^* S^{-1}\{S(q^*)-\frac{{w^N}^*}{w^*} \left[ S\left( {q^N}^*\right) -S\left( \hat{x}_3^N\right) \right] \}\), which implies that \(c \le \left[ (1-r^*) w^*S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) +k\right] /q^* \). Therefore, if \(\mathscr {A}_2 \ge 0\), we obtain the threshold

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{c}=\frac{(1-r^*) w^*S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) +k}{q^*}, \end{aligned}$$

satisfying \(\hat{c}q^*-k>0\). When \(c\le \hat{c}\), the value of LCI for the supplier \(\Delta \Pi _s \ge 0\). Otherwise, the value of LCI for the supplier \(\Delta \Pi _s < 0\).

1.10 Proof of Corollary 4

  1. (1)

    Based on the proof of Corollary 2, we have \(1-r^*{=}B/\Omega _2+\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_3\right) -\theta \left[ \bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_1\right) {-}\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_2\right) \right] \). Subsequently, substituting the equation above into the expression of \(\hat{c}\), we have

    $$\begin{aligned} \hat{c}=\frac{\{B/\Omega _2+\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_3\right) -\theta \left[ \bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_1\right) -\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_2\right) \right] \}w^*S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) +k}{q^*}. \end{aligned}$$

    Taking the derivative of \(\hat{c}\) with respect to b yields

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \hat{c}}{\partial b}=-\frac{\theta w^*}{q^*} S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) \frac{\partial \bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_1\right) }{\partial b}=-\frac{\theta }{q^*}f\left( \hat{x}_1\right) S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) . \end{aligned}$$

    Thus, we can verify \(\frac{\partial \hat{c}}{\partial b}<0\) because \(S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) >0\).

  2. (2)

    Taking the derivative of \(\hat{c}\) with respect to d yields

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \hat{c}}{\partial d}=\frac{\theta w^*}{q^*} S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) \frac{\partial \bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_2\right) }{\partial d}=\frac{\theta }{q^*}f\left( \hat{x}_2\right) S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) . \end{aligned}$$

    Thus, it is easy to verify that \(\frac{\partial \hat{c}}{\partial d}>0\).

  3. (3)

    Taking the derivative of \(\hat{c}\) with respect to \(\theta \) yields

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \hat{c}}{\partial \theta }=\frac{-w^* \left[ \bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_1\right) -\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_2\right) \right] S^{-1}\left( \mathscr {A}_2\right) }{q^*}. \end{aligned}$$

    Therefore, we can deduce that \(\frac{\partial \hat{c}}{\partial \theta }<0\) because we have proved that \(\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_1\right) -\bar{F}\left( \hat{x}_2\right) >0\).

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Zhong, H., Yan, N., Lu, J. et al. Value of loan credit insurance in the capital-constrained supply chain. Ann Oper Res (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-024-05976-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-024-05976-9

Keywords

Navigation