Skip to main content
Log in

Business-cycle pattern of asset returns: a general equilibrium explanation

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Annals of Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

I develop an analytical general-equilibrium model to explain economic sources of business-cycle pattern of aggregate stock market returns. With concave production functions and capital accumulation, a technology shock has a pro-cyclical direct effect and a counter-cyclical indirect effect on expected returns. The indirect effect, reflecting the “feedback” effect of consumers’ behavior on asset returns, dominates the direct effect and causes counter-cyclical variations of expected returns. I show that the conditional mean, volatility, and Sharpe ratios of asset returns all vary counter-cyclically and they are persistent and predictable, and that stock market behavior has forecasting power for real economic activity.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, Fama and French (1989) use the term spread, default spread, and dividend yield; Schwert (1989) enlists short-term interest rates, yields on corporate bonds, and growth rates of industrial production; Whitelaw (1997) employs dividend yield, default spread, commercial paper-Treasury spread, and one-year Treasury yield; Lettau and Ludvigson (2010) utilize consumption-wealth ratio and some of these conditioning variables. In contrast, Brandt and Kang (2004) and Binsbergen et al. (2013) adopt a VAR approach without relying on predictors. Overall, the empirical studies of the business-cycle behavior of asset returns are often related to a large literature documenting that excess returns are time-varying and predictable. See, e.g., Cochrane (1999) and Koijen and Nieuwerburgh (2011) for two surveys of the return predictability literature.

  2. Lettau (2003) uses a similar decomposition of asset price responses to technology shocks to study why the premium of equity is small over the risk-free rate and over a real long-term bond.

  3. Analytical results would be difficult to obtain in an infinitely-lived-agent setting. There is also a caveat. The two-period OLG model suits the low-frequency phenomenon well and the business cycle is a relatively high-frequency phenomenon, but the economic intuition illustrated in this article carries over to a representative-agent model or a more realistic OLG model with many periods of life for agents.

  4. Cuoco and Cvitanic (1998) examine an optimal consumption and investment problem for a ‘large’ investor whose portfolio choices affect the instantaneous expected returns on the traded assets. Basak (1997) studies in an exchange economy a consumption-portfolio problem of an agent who acts as a price-leader in all markets and the implications of his behavior on equilibrium security prices.

  5. The reason is as follows. Typically, when firms do not face adjustment costs, the social planner can perfectly smooth the impact of shocks on consumption and risk premia should be zero. When firms pay infinite adjustment costs, then this production economy is reduced to an exchange economy.

  6. The literature has shown that standard RBC models have counter-factual quantitative asset pricing implications (see., e.g., Jermann 1998; Boldrin et al. 2001). Generally, two additional features are needed to solve the quantitative failure: frictions at the household level like habit formation preferences and borrowing constraints that prevent inter-temporal consumption smoothing, and frictions at the firm level like capital adjustment costs, investment irreversibility, and multi-production sectors with limited inter-sectoral factor mobility.

  7. As well understood, a production model typically requires incredibly high risk aversion to fit the data unless the model features frictions. Like a generic OLG structure, my model does inherently impose the inter-generational risk sharing restriction, which in theory should help lower the value of risk aversion coefficient to match the data. However, due to the oversimplified model setup for the sake of analytical tractability, I still need quite high risk aversion values to achieve a match in magnitude of model predictions with the real-world data. In other words, more frictions are needed in my model in order to improve its quantitative performance with more economically reasonable risk aversion values.

  8. The firm faces a dynamic problem. If the state of the economy follows a Markovian process then, denoting by \(V\left( k_{t},s_{t}\right) \) the firm value at time t,  the Bellman equation for the firm’s problem is:

    $$\begin{aligned} V\left( k_{t},s_{t}\right) =\max _{\left\{ h_{t},i_{t}\right\} }p_{t}\left( z_{t}k_{t}^{\alpha }h_{t}^{1-\alpha }-w_{t}h_{t}-i_{t}\right) +E_{t}\left[ V\left( k_{t+1},s_{t+1}\right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$
  9. A caveat is in order. A typical general-equilibrium model endogeneizes the risk-free rate. In my model, because there are no inter-generational transfers and each agent lives for two periods and only cares about period 2 consumption, the risk-free rate is constant. Given the availability of a risk-free storage technology delivering a constant rate of return \(r^{f}\), the no-arbitrage condition requires the risk-free rate to equal the return on the storage technology that is exogenously given. As a tradeoff, this result greatly simplifies the analytical exercise of this paper. Moreover, as empirical studies show that the fluctuation in the risk-free rate is unlikely to be a main source of the business-cycle pattern of asset returns, the exogenously given risk-free rate in my model is an innocuous modeling feature.

  10. Let X be a random variable with a stochastic volatility distribution so that X|V is distributed \(N(\mu ,\sigma ^{2}V)\) and V has density p(V). The size-biased volatility-adjusted distribution Q is given by \( q(V)=V_{p}(V)/E(V)\).

  11. Note that \(\frac{\partial \phi _{t}}{\partial y_{t}}=\frac{1}{144} A^{-3}y_{t}^{-4}\gamma \sigma _{z,t}^{2}Q_{t}/\sqrt{\gamma ^{2}\sigma _{z,t}^{4}+48Ay_{t}^{2}\mu _{z,t}}>0.\)

  12. In principle, \(\frac{\partial \phi _{t}}{\partial z_{t}}\) can be obtained by applying the implicit function theorem to Eq. (24), but it is not trivial to get its sign. When \(\alpha =\frac{1}{2}\), \(\frac{\partial \phi _{t}}{\partial z_{t}}=\frac{2\phi _{t}}{z_{t} \left( 2Ay_{t}+\gamma \sigma _{z,t}^{2}\right) }\left[ 2\rho Ay_{t}+\gamma \sigma _{z,t}^{2}\right] >0\).

  13. When \(\alpha =\frac{1}{2}\), \(\frac{d\mu _{r,t}}{dz_{t}}=\frac{\gamma \sigma _{z,t}^{2}}{2z_{t}y_{t}}\left( \rho -1\right) \leqslant 0\) with equality if \(\rho =1\).

References

  • Backus, D., Routledge, B., Zin, S.: The cyclical component of US asset returns. Working paper, New York University (2010)

  • Barberis, N.: Investing for the long run when returns are predictable. J Finance 55, 225–264 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R.J.: The stock market and investment. Rev Financ Stud 3, 115–131 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basak, S.: Consumption choice and asset pricing with a non-price-taking agent. Econ Theory 10, 437–462 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bansal, R., Yaron, A.: Risks for the long run: a potential resolution of asset pricing puzzles. J Finance 59, 1481–1509 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binsbergen, J., Hueskes, W., Koijen, R., Vrugt, E.: Equity yields. J Financ Econ 110, 503–519 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boldrin, M., Christiano, L.J., Fisher, J.D.: Habit persistence, asset returns, and the business cycle. Am Econ Rev 91, 149–166 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandt, M.W., Kang, Q.: On the relationship between the conditional mean and volatility of stock returns: a latent VAR approach. J Financ Econ 72, 217–257 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J.Y.: Asset pricing at the millennium. J Finance 55, 1515–1569 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J.Y., Cochrane, J.H.: By force of habit: a consumption-based explanation of aggregate stock market behavior. J Polit Econ 107, 205–251 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, J.H.: Production-based asset pricing and the link between stock returns and economic fluctuations. J Finance 46, 209–237 (1991)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, J.H.: New facts in finance. Fed Reserve Bank Chicago Econ Perspect 23, 36–58 (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, J.H.: Asset Pricing. Princeton: Princeton University Press (2001)

  • Constantinides, G.M., Donaldson, J.B., Mehra, R.: Junior can’t borrow: a new perspective on the equity premium puzzle. Q J Econ 117, 269–296 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cuoco, D., Cvitanic, J.: Optimal consumption choices for a ‘large’ investor. J Econ Dyn Control 22, 401–436 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Long, B.J., Shleifer, A., Summers, L.H., Waldmann, R.J.: Noise trader risk in financial markets. J Polit Econ 98, 703–738 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, L.G., Zin, S.: Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: a theoretical framework. Econometrica 57, 937–969 (1989)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, L.G., Zin, E.: The independence axiom and asset returns. J Empir Finance 8, 537–572 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E.F.: Stock returns, expected returns and real activity. J Finance 45, 1089–1108 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E.F., French, K.R.: Business conditions and expected returns on stocks and bonds. J Financ Econ 25, 23–49 (1989)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feng, Z., Hoelle, M.: Indeterminacy in stochastic overlapping generations models: real effects in the long run. Econ Theory 63, 559–585 (2017)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garleanu, N., Kogan, L., Panageas, S.: Displacement risk and asset returns. J Financ Econ 105, 491–510 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gron, A., Jorgensen, B.N., Polson, N.G.: Optimal portfolio choice and stochastic volatility. Appl Stoch Models Bus Ind 28, 1–15 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harvey, C.R.: Time-varying conditional covariances in tests of asset pricing models. J Financ Econ 24, 289–317 (1989)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayashi, F.: Tobin’s marginal q and average q: a neoclassical interpretation. Econometrica 50, 213–224 (1982)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jermann, U.J.: Asset pricing in production economies. J Monet Econ 41, 257–275 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kandel, S., Stambaugh, R.F.: On the predictability of stock returns: an asset allocation perspective. J Finance 51, 385–424 (1996)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koijen, R., Nieuwerburgh, S.: Predictability of returns and cash flows. Annu Rev Financ Econ 3, 4677–4691 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lettau, M.: Inspecting the mechanism: the determination of asset prices in the RBC model. Econ J 113, 550–575 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lettau, M., Ludvigson, S.C.: Measuring and modeling variations in the risk-return tradeoff. In: Ait-Shalia, Y., Hansen, L.P. (eds.) Handbook of Financial Econometrics, vol. 1, pp. 617–690. North Holland: Elsevier (2010)

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Prescott, E.C.: Theory ahead of business-cycle measurement. Carnigie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy 24, 11–44 (1986) Reprinted in Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 10, 9–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ríos-Rull, J.: On the quantitative importance of market completeness. J Monet Econ 34, 463–496 (1994)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ríos-Rull, J.: Life-cycle economies and aggregate fluctuations. Rev Econ Stud 63, 465–489 (1996)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rouwenhorst, G.K.: Asset pricing implications of equilibrium business cycle models. In: Cooley, T.F. (ed.) Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, pp. 294–330. Princeton: Princeton University Press (1995)

  • Schwert, G.W.: Why does stock market volatility change over time? J Finance 44, 1115–1153 (1989)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spiegel, M.: Stock price volatility in a multiple security overlapping generations model. Rev Financ Stud 11, 419–447 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J., Watson, M.: New indexes of coincident and leading economic indicators. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, vol. 4, pp. 351–394. Cambridge: MIT Press (1989)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Storesletten, K., Telmer, C.I., Yaron, A.: Asset pricing with idiosyncratic risk and overlapping generations. Rev Econ Dyn 10(4), 519–548 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whitelaw, R.F.: Time-varying Sharpe ratios and market timing. Working paper, New York University (1997)

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Qiang Kang.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

This paper is revised from the second chapter of my Ph.D. dissertation. I am indebted to Andrew B. Abel, Michael W. Brandt, A. Craig MacKinlay, and Roberto Mariano for their guidance and encouragement. I thank an anomynous referee, Bill Dupor, Lixin Huang, Urban Jermann, José-Víctor Ríos-Rull, Amir Yaron, and seminar participants at Wharton School, Economics Department at University of Pennsylvania, the Inter-university Conference at New York University, and the Financial Management Association Annual Meeting for helpful comments and suggestions. Any errors are mine.

Appendix: Proofs

Appendix: Proofs

Proof of Corollary 1

Using Proposition 1, the net asset return \(r_{t+1}\equiv \frac{ P_{t+1}+d_{t+1}}{P_{t}}-1=\)\(\frac{k_{t+2}+d_{t+1}}{k_{t+1}}-1 = \alpha z_{t+1}k_{t+1}^{\alpha -1}h_{t+1}^{1-\alpha }-\delta \equiv r_{t+1}^{I}\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 2

  1. (1)

    If \(\rho <1,\) then Eq. (2) implies that \(\ln z_{t+1}|\ln z_{t}\sim N\left( \rho \ln z_{t},\sigma _{\varepsilon }^{2}\right) \). Then use the formula on the first two moments of a lognormal distribution to obtain the first two equations. The remaining two equations are obtained using the first two equations and Eq. (2).

  2. (2)

    \(\frac{\partial \mu _{z,t}}{\partial \rho }=\mu _{z,t}\ln z_{t} >0 \ \left( <0\right) \) and \(\frac{\partial \sigma _{z,t}}{\partial \rho }=\sigma _{z,t}\ln z_{t}>0\)\(\left( <0\right) \) if \(z_{t}>1\ \left( <1\right) .\)

  3. (3)

    \(\frac{\partial \mu _{z,t}}{\partial z_{t}}=\mu _{z,t} \frac{\rho }{z_{t}}\geqslant 0\) and \(\frac{\partial \sigma _{z,t}}{\partial z_{t}} =\sigma _{z,t}\frac{\rho }{z_{t}}\geqslant 0\).

\(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 3

The proof is trivial since \(b=\alpha \phi ^{\alpha -1}\) is a decreasing function of \(\phi \) as \(\alpha <1\) (the law of diminishing returns to capital). If \(\alpha =1,\)\(b=1\) is a constant. \(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 1

The first part is trivial given Eqs. (32) and (31).

For the second part, realize that \(\frac{\partial v_{t}}{\partial y_{t}}=-\frac{2\mu _{z,t}^{2}\left( 2Ay_{t}-\gamma \sigma _{z,t}^{2}\right) }{\left( 2Ay_{t}+\gamma \sigma _{z,t}^{2}\right) ^{3}}<0\)\(\left( >0\right) \) if \(2Ay_{t}-\gamma \sigma _{z,t}^{2}>0\)\(\left( <0\right) \!.\)

For the last part, note that \(\phi _{t}=\frac{1}{2}v_{t}y_{t},\) so \(\frac{\partial \phi _{t}}{\partial y_{t}}=\frac{1}{2} \left( \frac{\partial v_{t}}{\partial y_{t}}y_{t}+v_{t}\right) \! =\!\frac{2\gamma y_{t}\mu _{z,t}^{2}\sigma _{z,t}^{2}}{\left( 2Ay_{t}+\gamma \sigma _{z,t}^{2}\right) ^{3}}>0\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 6

Note that

\(\frac{\partial b_{t}}{\partial \gamma }=24\cdot 2^{\frac{2}{3} }A^{2}y_{t}^{2}\sigma _{z,t}^{2} Q_{t}^{-\frac{2}{3}}/\sqrt{\gamma ^{2} \sigma _{z,t}^{4}+48Ay_{t}^{2}\mu _{z,t}}>0\), and

\(\frac{\partial b_{t}}{\partial y_{t}}=-24\cdot 2^{\frac{2}{3} }A^{2}y_{t}\gamma \sigma _{z,t}^{2}Q_{t}^{-\frac{2}{3}}/\sqrt{\gamma ^{2} \sigma _{z,t}^{4}+48Ay_{t}^{2}\mu _{z,t}}<0\).

Because \(\mu _{r,t}^{e}=b_{t}\mu _{z,t}-A\), \(\sigma _{r,t} =b_{t}\sigma _{z,t}\), and \(SR_{r,t}=\frac{b_{t}\mu _{z,t}-A}{b_{t}\sigma _{z,t}}\), I have \(\frac{\partial \mu _{r,t}^{e}}{\partial X}=\frac{\partial b_{t}}{\partial X} \mu _{z,t}\), \(\frac{\partial \sigma _{r,t}}{\partial X} =\frac{\partial b_{t} }{\partial X}\sigma _{z,t}\), and

\(\frac{\partial SR_{r,t}}{\partial X}=\frac{\partial b_{t}}{\partial X}\frac{ A}{b_{t}^{2}\sigma _{z,t}}\), for \(X=\gamma \) and \(y_{t}\), respectively. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kang, Q. Business-cycle pattern of asset returns: a general equilibrium explanation. Ann Finance 15, 539–561 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-019-00347-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-019-00347-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation