Skip to main content
Log in

India in the globalized economy : Growth spillovers & business cycle synchronization

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Economics and Economic Policy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In recent decades, in the wake of accelerated globalization, the issue of output coupling/decoupling has assumed considerable importance in academic as well as in policy debates. Special attention has been focussed on the following four issues (i) whether economies are getting increasingly synchronized in their cyclical behaviour and in particular whether EMEs are getting synchronized with the advanced group of countries (or otherwise) and/or among themselves ? (ii) whether similar synchronization is also evident in the growth profiles of EMEs and advanced economies ? (iii) what are the main factors driving this two types of synchronization ? and (iv) are the factors driving growth synchronization different from those driving business cycle co-movements? This is a single-country study which examines the decoupling issue from the perspective of the Indian economy over a fairly long time span viz. 1961–2008, dividing the same into three sub-periods characterized by relative insularity (1961–1978), restricted globalization (1979–1993) and full-scale globalization (1994–2008). Among the important potential determinants of co-movements suggested by the available literature are inter-industry and intra-industry trade intensities, co-ordination of fiscal and monetary policy, financial integration etc. Our key finding is that the economic determinants for India’s cyclical synchronization differ across short (16–32 months) and medium cycles (32–64 months) and vis-a-vis growth spillovers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The term BRICS is now a common acronym for the following group of countries—Brazil, Russia, India, China and S. Africa

  2. See Willett et al. (2011) for a discussion on different ways the term decoupling has been used in the literature.

  3. “Growth spillovers” are likely to be explained by trade intensity and specialization, FDI (foreign direct investment) inflows, technology transfer etc. whereas “business cycle synchronization” is influenced by factors such as financial contagion, portfolio capital inflows, fiscal and monetary policy coordination etc.

  4. See e.g. Kalemli-Ozcan et al (2009), Mendoza and Quadrini (2010) etc. Morgan et al. (2004) indicate a similar ambiguity about the impact of banking integration on output co-movement, depending on whether financial shocks or total factor productivity shocks predominate.

  5. See Fidrmuc et al. (2008) on China and Jayaram et al. (2009) on India. Hsiao et al. (2003) study the impact of the U.S. economy on the Asia-Pacific Rim.

  6. Korea became a full member of the OECD group in December 1996. Its classification as an EME is somewhat contentious, as its current per capita gross national income is about two and a half times the norm of $ 11, 500 (US PPP) conventionally used in classifying EMEs. However, several features of the Korean economy still keep it akin to an EME (see e.g. the reasons cited by the MSCI (Morgan Stanley Capital International) in its decision to retain the emerging market status for Korea in http://news.xinhuanet.com/english2010/business/2011-06/22/c_13943427.htm) . Further much of the current comparative development literature still persists with this classification mainly with a view to maintaining historical continuity (see e.g. . Chui et al. (2002), He et al. (2007) etc.).

  7. It may appear that the shares of some countries like the Netherlands, Swedn or Spain may be insignificant, but taken as a group these countries’ share exceeded that of Japan, Korea and several other Asian EMEs (taken individually)

  8. An excellent advanced text on wavelets is Percival and Walden (2000). Easily readable accounts are available in Gencay et al. (2002), Crowley (2007), Nachane and Dubey (2013) etc.

  9. The actual derivation of the wavelet details and smooths may be done via the so-called discrete wavelet transform (DWT), which can be computed in several alternative ways. The intuitively most appealing procedure is the pyramid algorithm, suggested in Mallat (1989) (and fully explained in Percival and Walden (2000)).

  10. Wavelet coefficients are obtained by a projection of the wavelet filter onto the vector of observations (see Gencay et al. (2002), p. 120 fn. 12.

  11. We are grateful to an anonymous referee for this suggestion.

  12. Using this confidential data set the authors find that (for a group of 20 developed economies) increased financial integration seems to get reflected in less synchronized output movements.

  13. Our sample size is 216 for Period I, 180 for Periods II and III, and hence the maximum number of scales that we choose is five (see e.g. Crowley (2007)).

  14. Of course it need hardly be stressed that that the choice of the wavelet is guided by the characteristics of the signal one is analyzing. Given that our series of interest are relatively smooth over the period of analysis, a Symmlet was thought appropriate. For a discontinuous signal, the Haar wavelet, for example, could be a better choice.

  15. An adjustment has however to be done for the standard errors of the POLS estimator.

  16. Pre-determinedness requires that E(x j,τ u jτ ) = 0, where j is the country index, τ is the time index and x j,τ is the vector of regressors.

  17. An additional consideration in our decision, being that the monetary policy measures across countries are defined differently. Besides, the targets of monetary policy for any given country have often shifted over the three periods of our analysis (e.g. India shifted from money supply (M3) targeting to repo rate targeting in the middle of Period III).

  18. Note that in computing the weight we use the aggregate GDP, data on which is obtained from the Penn World Tables (version 7.0).

  19. Considering ρ j,τ (k = s4) (which accounts for long-tem effects in conjunction with medium term cyclical effects (i.e. those with cycles between 32 to 64 months) produced results not materially different from those with ρ j,τ (k = s5), thus leading us to suppose that even shorter cycles (of less than 32 months) can affect long-term growth.

References

  • Aghion P, Angletos GM, Banerjee A, Manova K (2005) Volatility and growth : credit constraints and productivity enhancing investment, NBER Working Paper No. 11349

  • Aghion P, Hemous D, Kharroubi E (2011) Cyclical fiscal policy, credit constraints, and industry growth, BIS Working Papers No. 340

  • Aguiar M, Gopinath G (2007) Emerging market business cycles : the cycle is the trend. J Polit Econ 115:69–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akin C, Kose MA (2008) Changing nature of North-South linkages : stylized facts and explanations. J Asian Econ 19(1):1–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M (1993) On the testing of correlated effects with panel data. J Econometr 59:87–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Artis MJ, Okubo T (2011) Does International trade really lead to business cycle synchronization?—a panel data approach. Manchester School, Univ Manchester 79(2):318–332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Backus DK, Kehoe PJ, Kydland FE (1995) International business cycles : theory and evidence. In: Plosser C (ed) Frontiers of business cycle research. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 331–357

    Google Scholar 

  • Balassa B, Bauwens L (1988) The determinants of intra-European trade in manufactured goods. Europ Econ Rev 32:1421–1437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi BH (1999) Specification tests in panel data models using artificial regressions. Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, No. 55/56, p. 277–297

  • Brahmbhatt M, Da Silva LP (2009) The global financial crisis : comparisons with the great depression and scenarios for recovery, PREM note 141. World Bank, Washington, D.C

  • Breusch TS, Pagan AR (1980) The Lagrange multiplier test and its applications to model specification in econometrics. Rev Econ Stud 47:239–253

  • Bruce A, Gao HY (1996) Applied wavelet analysis with S-Plus. Springer, U.S

  • Camacho M, Perez-Quiros G, Saiz L (2008) Do European Business Cycles look like one? J Econ Dyn Control 32:2165–2190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chui M, Levine P, Murshed SM, Pearlman J (2002) North-South models of growth and trade. J Econ Surv 16:123–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ciccarelli M, Mojon B (2010) Global Inflation. Rev Econ Stat 92(3):524–535

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark T, van Wincoop E (2001) Borders and business cycles. J Int Econ 55:59–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crowley PM (2007) A guide to wavelets for economists. J Econ Surv 21(2):207–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crucini MJ, Kose MA, Otrok C (2008) What are the driving forces of international business cycles?. Working Paper No. 14380 National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Culem CG, Lundberg L (1997) The product pattern of intra-industry trade : stability among countries and over time. Weltwirtschaftliches Arch 122:113–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen B (1992) Should the maastricht treaty be saved?, Princeton Studies in International Finance, No. 74, International Finance Section, Princeton University

  • Fidrmuc J, Korhonen I, Btorov I (2008) China in the world economy : dynamic correlation analysis of business cycles, BOFIT Discussion Paper No. 7/2008, Bank of Finland

  • Findlay R (1980) The terms of trade and equilibrium growth in the world economy. Am Econ Rev 70:291–299

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank AG (1967) Capitalism and underdevelopment in Latin America. Monthly Review Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel JA, Rose AK (1998) The endogeneity of the optimum currency area criteria. Econ J 108(449):1009–1025

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel JA, Rose AK (2002) An estimate of the effect of currency unions on trade and income. Q J Econ 117:437–466

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallegati M (2007) Wavelet variance analysis of output in G-7 countries. Stud Nonlinear Dynam Economet 11(3), Article 6: 1–23

  • García-Herrero A, Ruiz JM (2008) Do trade and financial linkages foster business cycle synchronization in a small economy?. Documentos de Trabajo No. 0810 Banco De Espana

  • Gencay R, Selcuk F, Whitcher B (2002) An Introduction to wavelets and other filtering methods in finance and economics. Academic, San Diego

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (1997) Econometric analysis. Prentice Hall, New Jersey

    Google Scholar 

  • Grubel H, Lloyd PJ (1975) Intra-industry trade : the theory and measurement of international trade in differentiated products. Macmillan Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Harding D, Pagan A (2006) Synchronisation of cycles. J Econ 132(1):59–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman JA (1978) Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica 46:1251–1271

  • Hausman JA, Taylor WE (1981) Panel data and unobservable individual effects. Econometrica 49:1377–1398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • He D, Cheung L, Chang J (2007) Sense and nonsense on Asia’s export dependency and the decoupling Thesis, Hong Kong Monetary Authority Research Memorandum No : 06/2007

  • Heathcote J, Perri F (2013) The international diversification puzzle is not as bad as you think. J Polit Econ 121(6):1108–1159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henriksen E, Kydland FE, Sustek R (2009) the high cross-country correlations of prices and interest rates. Working Paper No. 15123 National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Hogan JA, Lakey JD (2003) Time-frequency and time-scale methods. Birkhauser, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom B, Tirole J (1998) Private and public supply of liquidity. J Polit Econ 106(1):1–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsiao FST, Hsiao MW, Yamashita A (2003) The impact of the US economy on the Asia-Pacific Region : does it matter ?. Working Paper No. 03-05, Center for Economic Analysis, University of Colorado at Boulder

  • Imbs JM (1999) Technology, growth and the business cycle. J Monet Econ 44(1):65–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imbs J (2007) Growth and volatility. J Monet Econ 54(7):1848–1862

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2007) World economic outlook : spillovers and cycles in the global economy. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Jayaram S, Patnaik I, Shah A (2009) Examining the decoupling hypothesis for India. Working Paper No. 2009-61, National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi

  • Kalemli-Ozcan S, Papaioannou E, Peydró JL (2009) Financial Integration and Business Cycle Synchronization, CEPR Discussion Papers No.7292

  • Kaminsky GM, Reinhart CM, Vegh CA (2004) When it rains, it pours : pro-cyclical capital flows and macroeconomic policies. NBER Macroecon Annu 19:11–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiyotaki N, Moore J (2012) Liquidity, business cycles, and monetary policy. NBER Working Paper No. 17934 (March)

  • Kose MA, Yi LM (2002) The trade comovement problem in international macroeconomics. Staff Reports No. 155, Federal Reserve Bank of New York

  • Kose MA, Prasad ES, Terrones ME (2003) How does globalization affect the synchronization of business cycles? Am Econ Rev 93(2):57–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kose MA, Otrok C, Prasad ES (2008) Global business cycles: convergence or decoupling?. IMF Working Paper No. WP/08/143

  • Mallat S (1989) A theory for multiresolution signal decomposition : the wavelet representation. IEEE Trans Pattern Anal Mach Intell 11(7):674–693

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendoza EG, Quadrini V (2010) Financial globalization, financial crises and contagion. J Monet Econ 57(1):24–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morgan DP, Rime B, Strahan PE (2004) Bank integration and state business cycles. Q J Econ 119(4):1555–1584

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mumtaz H, Simonelli S, Surico P (2011) International comovements, business cycle and inflation: a historical perspective. Rev Econ Dyn 14(1):176–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nachane D, Dubey AK (2013) Trend and cyclical decoupling: new estimates based on spectral causality tests and wavelet correlations. Appl Econ 45(31):4419–4428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oaxaca RL, Geisler I (2003) Fixed effects models with time invariant variables: a theoretical note. Econ Lett 80(3):373–377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Percival D, Walden A (2000) Wavelet methods for time series analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Priestley MB (1996) Wavelets and time-dependent spectral analysis. J Time Ser Anal 17(1):85–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan R, Zingales L (1998) Financial dependence and growth. Am Econ Rev 88:559–586

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramey C, Ramey V (1995) Cross-country evidence on the link between volatility and growth. Am Econ Rev 85(5):1138–1151

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose AK, Spiegel M (2009) International financial remoteness and macroeconomic volatility. J Dev Econ 89(2):250–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rossi V (2009) Decoupling debate will return : emergers dominate in long Run. Chatham House, Briefing Note, IEP BN 08/01

  • Sato K, Zhang Z (2006) Real output co-movements in East Asia: any evidence for a monetary union? World Econ 29:1671–1689

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shin K, Sohn C-H (2006) Trade and financial integration in East Asia: effects on comovements. World Econ 29:1649–1669

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shin K, Wang Y (2003) Trade integration and business cycle synchronization in East Asia. Asian Econ Papers 2(3):1–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Watson MW (2008) Heteroscedasticity-robust standard errors for fixed effects panel data regression. Econometrica 76(1):155–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strang G (1993) Wavelet transforms versus Fourier transforms. Bull Am Math Soc 28:288–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strang G, Nguyen T (1996) Wavelets and filter banks. Wellesley-Cambridge, Wellesley

    Google Scholar 

  • Talvi E, Veigh CA (2005) Tax base variability and pro-cyclical fiscal policy. J Dev Econ 78:156–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor L (1983) Structuralist macroeconomics. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Thornton J (2008) Explaining pro-cyclical fiscal policy in African countries. J Afr Econ 17(3):451–464

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White H (1980) A heteroscedasticity consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroscedasticity. Econometrica 48:817–838

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Willett TD, Liang P, Zhang N (2011) Global contagion and the decoupling debate. in Cheung YW, Kakkar V, Ma G (ed). Frontiers of economics and globalization, vol. 9, Emerald Group Publishing Ltd., p. 215–234

  • Yeyati LE, Williams T (2012) Emerging economies in the 2000s: real decoupling and financial recoupling. J Int Money Financ 31(8):2102–2126

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are very grateful to an anonymous referee for his valuable suggestions. Errors and shortcomings are the authors’ sole responsibility. Amlendu Dubey acknowledges the financial support he received from IIT Delhi for the work on this paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Amlendu Dubey.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Nachane, D., Dubey, A. India in the globalized economy : Growth spillovers & business cycle synchronization. Int Econ Econ Policy 15, 89–115 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-016-0367-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-016-0367-x

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation