1 Introduction

1.1 Motivation, approach, and main insight

Most models of banking—be they micro- or macro-oriented—are based on the so-called “loanable-funds approach to banking”: Banks are financed through deposits, equity, and other financial contracts, and then they lend to firms or buy assets. In our monetary architecture, however, the opposite process is at work. Banks start lending to firms and simultaneously create deposits which are nominal contracts with claims on central bank money. Firms use deposits to buy investment goods, and deposits flow to households who decide about their portfolio of bank deposits, bank equity, and other assets they want to hold. Subsequently, households buy consumption goods, and deposits are transferred back to firms who repay their loans. This approach is called the “money-creation approach to banking.”

In which circumstances do the money-creation approach and the loanable-funds approach yield the same outcomes? In our paper, we establish a simple benchmark result. In the absence of uncertainty, both processes yield the same allocation and no bank default occurs. Hence, in such cases, using the loanable-funds model as a shortcut does not imply any loss of generality.

More specifically, we develop the result in a simple two-period general equilibrium model in which a fraction of firms has to rely on banks to obtain physical goods since the firms cannot pledge to repay their bonds. The other firms are financed through the bond market. There is no production risk. We consider two different financing architectures of the economy. In both architectures, households decide on consumption and savings in the first period. The latter is split into bank deposits, bank equity, and bonds. Firms obtain loans to undertake production through banks and the bond market. In the loanable-funds approach, the households’ savings, in the form of bank deposits and bank equity, are lent to some firms. In the money-creation approach, however, bank lending creates the deposits that are necessary for households to invest in bank deposits and bank equity.

In order to establish our benchmark result, we deliberately assume favorable manifestations of some other potential frictions and distortions in the economy. In particular, we make the following assumptions:

  • Banks act as delegated monitors and can eliminate moral hazard problems of firms that do not obtain financing in the capital market.Footnote 1 Banks are therefore essential for the financing of a fraction of firms. For simplicity, we set monitoring costs to zero.Footnote 2

  • When a government bail-out is needed, the required taxation of households is lump-sum and therefore does not lead to additional distortions.

We show that under these circumstances, both the money-creation approach and the loanable-funds approach yield the same allocation and no bank default occurs in equilibrium. Bank defaults may occur out-of equilibrium. Hence, in the absence of production risk and together with the manifestation of frictions outlined above, using the loanable-funds model as a shortcut does not imply any loss of generality. In the extension, we indicate that when there is aggregate risk with complete contracts and complete markets, a restricted equivalence result holds in the following sense: There is an equilibrium in the money-creation model that replicates the investment and consumption allocation in the equilibrium of the loanable-funds model, but the set of equilibria in both models differ.

1.2 Relation to the literature

Our work relates to two rather recent analytical papers.Footnote 3 Jakab and Kumhof (2015) use a DSGE model to compare the money-creation approach with the loanable-funds approach to establish differences and similarities. In particular, they predict that in the money-creation approach, shocks to the creditworthiness of bank borrowers have a more pronounced and more immediate impact on the amount of outstanding bank loans and on output than in the loanable-funds version of the same model. Faure and Gersbach (2021) investigate the welfare properties of a general equilibrium model with bank money creation and an aggregate productivity shock. They demonstrate that the level of money creation is first-best in symmetric equilibria when prices are flexible, but that it is not necessarily first-best in asymmetric equilibria. Moreover, they show that when prices are rigid, there may be circumstances for which money creation by banks is not bounded. In such cases, the monetary system breaks down. Faure and Gersbach (2021) prove that capital requirements may restore the existence of equilibria with finite money creation, and in some cases, may even implement the first-best allocation.

In the present paper, we develop a model to study constellations when the loanable-funds approach and the money-creation approach to banking might deliver similar results.Footnote 4 For this purpose, we use a two-sector macroeconomic model, but we abstract from any type of uncertainty. More specifically, the model is much more general than in Faure and Gersbach (2021), as it incorporates consumption/investment choices and it replaces the linear production function in one of the sectors with a concave production function. However, the present model is more restricted than in Faure and Gersbach (2021), as it assumes away any type of uncertainty, which will ensure that default does not occur in equilibrium.Footnote 5 Our main result is that all the newly detected phenomena linked to money creation are connected to the presence of risks and bank default. In the absence of idiosyncratic and aggregate risks, the loanable-funds approach and the money-creation approaches are equivalent, since the allocations are identical.

In this paper, we rely on an important line of reasoning which shows that fiat money can have positive value in a finite-horizon model when, first, there are sufficiently large penalties when debts to governments—such as tax liabilities—are not paid, and, second, there are sufficiently large gains from using and trading money.Footnote 6 To this literature we add the two-tier structure with privately and publicly created monies. Commercial banks create bank deposits (privately created money) when they grant loans to firms enabling them to buy investment goods. Bank deposits will be used later by households to buy consumption goods.Footnote 7 The central bank creates reserves (publicly created money) when it grants loans to commercial banks, enabling them to settle claims on privately created money among banks. The publicly created money is often called “central bank money”. The essential assumption for a positive value of fiat money in our paper is that banks (the shareholders) face large penalties if they default against the central bank, and thus banks will never choose to default. An explicit deposit-in-advance constraint is not needed.

1.3 Structure of the paper

The paper is organized as follows: Sect. 2 gives an overview of the two models. Their common features are detailed in Sect. 3. Section 4 describes and analyzes the loanable-funds model, and Sect. 5 describes and analyzes the money-creation model. Section 7 concludes.

2 Overview

We first describe the common set-up of the two models in Sect. 2.1 and then set out their particularities in Sect. 2.2 for the so-called “loanable-funds model” and in Sect. 2.3 for the so-called “money-creation model.”

2.1 Common set-up

We build a general equilibrium model with two periods (\(t=0,1\)), one physical good, and two production sectors. Households are initially endowed with the good and own the firms in the two production sectors. In period \(t=0\), households consume a part of the good, and the rest is invested in the production in both sectors. At the start of period \(t=1\), production takes place in both sectors. At the end of period \(t=1\), households consume the amount of produced goods.

After the initial consumption of a share of the physical good at the beginning of the first period (t = 0), households found and fund banks by exchanging equity contracts against some amount of physical good in the loanable-funds model and by exchanging equity contracts against money in the money-creation model. In one sector, firms are plagued by moral hazard, but banks, acting as delegated monitors, can alleviate moral hazard problems. These firms thus can only be financed by bank loans. The other sector can be directly financed by households, who provide the firms with the remaining amount of the physical good in exchange for bonds. These bonds represent the agreement that firms will deliver some amount of the physical good after production in the second period (t = 1) against the provision of some amount of the physical good in the first period. In the second period, firms and banks pay dividends from profits to households, who are their shareholders.

Although there is no risk in the production technologies and default will not occur in equilibrium, it is nevertheless necessary to account carefully for default risk of banks out-of-equilibrium, in particular in the money creation model.Footnote 8 Government authorities fully insure the households’ deposits.Footnote 9 Banks defaulting against households are bailed out, and government authorities finance the bail-out with lump-sum taxation.

2.2 Loanable-funds model

In period \(t=0\), households consume a part of their endowment of the physical good. They also found and fund banks by providing them with some amount of the physical good in exchange for deposits and equity contracts. Banks then lend this amount of the physical good to firms in one sector which are plagued by moral hazard. The other sector is directly financed by households, who provide firms in this sector with the remaining amount of the physical good. In period \(t=1\), firms in the bank-financed sector repay the loans in terms of the physical good, which enables banks to repay depositors and shareholders. All contracts and all variables are denominated in terms of the physical good, and no money is involved.

2.3 Money-creation model

In period \(t=0\), households consume part of their endowment of the physical good. The firms in one sector are financed by bank loans. Money in the form of bank deposits is created at the same time as loans are granted to these firms. The bank deposits serve as a store of value and as a means of payment. Households sell part of the physical good that was not consumed in period \(t=0\) to the latter firms in exchange for deposits, which enable households to invest in bank equity and bank deposits. The other sector is directly financed by households, who provide firms in this sector with the remaining amount of the physical good in exchange for bonds.

The banks that experience an inflow of deposits from other banks that is lower than outflow have a net liability against other banks. Banks that have net liabilities against other banks can repay their liability by borrowing from the central bank electronic central bank money at the policy rate and by paying with it. Electronic central bank money—or simply reserves—will thus be transferred to the banks that have claims against other banks, and the central bank will pay some interest according to the policy rate. We note that the presence of the central bank and the use of reserves to settle interbank liabilities are essential for the working of the monetary architecture. Otherwise, deposits could not serve as a medium of exchange.

In period \(t=1\), anticipating the repayment of the firms financed by banks, non-defaulting banks pay dividends to their shareholders in the form of deposits. Households use these deposits to buy the amount of the physical good produced by the firms. Bank loans are repaid by these firms with their deposits. When borrowers pay loans back, the deposits originally created during period \(t=0\) are destroyed. At the end of period \(t=1\), by the repayment of loans, both types of money—central bank money and private deposits—are destroyed.

3 Common features of the two models

Sections 3.1 to 3.4 present the features common to both models. In Sect. 3, we do not use bold characters to distinguish between variables denominated in real terms and variables denominated in nominal terms. The difference will be spelled out in each of Sects. 3.1 to 3.4, if necessary.

3.1 Entrepreneurs

Firms employ two different technologies that use an amount of a physical good in period \(t=0\) to produce some amount of the physical good in the next period. Entrepreneurs operate these firms and maximize shareholder value.

There is a moral hazard technology called “MT.” Entrepreneurs running the firms using MTFootnote 10 are subject to moral hazard. That is, their pledgeable revenues, i.e. the revenues an entrepreneur can credibly promise to pay to external financiers, are low. In particular, they are lower than the repayment obligations they would face in the bond market (see Holmström and Tirole (1997) for the foundations of limited pledgeability). Banks act as delegated monitors and alleviate the moral hazard problem. For simplicity, we assume that banks can completely eliminate the moral hazard problem, i.e. that they can ensure the repayment of loans or the liquidation value if the latter is smaller.Footnote 11 We also assume that monitoring costs are zero.Footnote 12

We use \(K_M \in [0,W]\) to denote the aggregate amount of the physical good invested in MT in period \(t=0\), where \(W > 0\) denotes the total amount of the physical good in the economy in period \(t=0\). We use \(f_M(K_M)\) to denote the amount of the physical good produced by MT in period \(t=1\). In the loanable-funds model, \(R_L > 0\) denotes the real gross rate of return, which is the amount of the physical good to be repaid by firms in period \(t=1\) for the use of one unit of physical good in period \(t=0\). In the money-creation model, it denotes the nominal gross rate of return, which is the amount of money to be repaid by firms in period \(t=1\) for the use of one unit of nominal investment in period \(t=0\).

There is a frictionless technology referred to as “FT”. Entrepreneurs running the firms using FTFootnote 13 are not subject to any moral hazard problem.Footnote 14 We use \(K_F \in [0,W]\) to denote the aggregate amount of the physical good invested in FT in period \(t=0\), which is also equal to the amount of bonds \(S_F = K_F\) issued by firms using FT to finance the investment \(K_F\). We also use \(f_F(K_F)\) to denote the amount of the physical good produced by FT in period \(t=1\) and \(R_F\) to denote the amount of the physical good to be repaid by firms using FT in period \(t=1\) for the use of one unit of physical good in period \(t=0\).

We assume two technologies in the model to study the mix of bank and bond financing and to examine whether the loanable funds and the money creation approach yield different financing mixes. We assume twice continuously differentiable production functions and:Footnote 15

Assumption 1

$$f_F', f_M' > 0 {\text{ and }} f_F'', f_M'' < 0, f'_F(0) = f'_M(0) = \infty. $$

This assumption ensures that total production cannot be maximized by allocating the entire amount of the physical good to one sector of production only. We assume price-taking firms in each sector, run by entrepreneurs and assume a representative firm in each sector. Firms using MT and FT are owned by households, and as long as the firms’ profits, denoted by \(\Pi _M\) and \(\Pi _F\) respectively, are positive, they are paid to owners as dividends. The shareholder values are given by \(\max (\Pi _M, 0)\) and \(\max (\Pi _F, 0)\), respectively.Footnote 16

3.2 Banks

In Sect. 3.2, all variables except the one that denotes a bank are denominated in real terms in the loanable-funds model and in nominal terms in the money-creation model.

There is a set of banks of measure 1, which we label \(b \in [0,1]\). Banks are perfectly competitive, i.e., they take interest rates as given. Bankers that operate these banks maximize shareholder value. Banks offer equity and deposit contracts and grant loans to the firms using MT. Individual amounts are denoted by \(e_B\), dH and lm, respectively, and may be further indexed by a specific bank b, if necessary. Aggregate quantities are denoted by capital letters \(E_B\), \(D_H\) and \(L_m\), respectively. We denote the lending gross rate of such loans by \(R_L\). As discussed above, we assume that banks can perfectly alleviate the moral hazard problem when investing in MT by monitoring borrowers and enforcing contractual obligations. Moreover, monitoring costs are assumed to be zero.

An identical amount of equity financing \(e_B\) is invested in each bank. As the set of banks is of measure 1, the individual amount \(e_B\) is identical to the aggregate amount \(E_B\). We assume \(E_B > 0\) and thus we have circumstances in which banks are founded and fundedFootnote 17 and can engage in lending activities. Limited liability protects bank owners, and Bank b pays dividends as long as profits denoted by \(\Pi _B^b\) are positive. The gross rate of return on equity and the bank shareholders’ value are given by \(R_E^b = \frac{\max (\Pi _B^b,0)}{e_B}\) and \(\max (\Pi _B^b,0)\), respectively.

We assume that households keep their deposits \(D_H\) evenly distributed across all banks at all times: \(d_H = D_H\). For example, they never transfer deposits from their account at one bank to another bank. The deposit gross rate is denoted by \(R_D\).

3.3 Households

There is a continuum of identical households of measure 1 and thus we can focus on a representative household initially endowed with W units of a physical good and ownership of all firms in the economy. In period \(t=0\), households consume a part of the physical good and invest or sell the rest of it. The amount of the physical good consumed by the representative household in period \(t=0\) is denoted by \(C_0\), and the remaining amount of the physical good invested by the representative household in period \(t=0\) is denoted by \(I = W - C_0\). Households’ portfolio decision-making involves investment in bank deposits, bank equity, and bonds issued by firms using FT.Footnote 18 Households are also paid some dividends from firm ownership. Households consume the entire physical good produced in period \(t=1\), and we denote the representative household’s consumption by \(C_1\) in period \(t=1\).

We use \(u(\cdot )\) to denote the representative household’s utility function for consumption in a given period and \(\delta \) (0 < δ ≤ 1) to denote the households’ time discount factor. The household’s total intertemporal utility, which we denote by \(U(C_0, C_1)\), is then given by

$$\begin{aligned} U(C_0, C_1) := u(C_0) + \delta u(C_1). \end{aligned}$$

We assume that the utility function is twice continuously differentiable, with \(u' > 0\), \(u'' < 0\), as well as the following Inada condition:

$$\begin{aligned} u'(0) = \infty . \end{aligned}$$

In words, the above assumption ensures that a household’s consumption cannot be maximized either by the consumption or by the investment of the entire amount of the physical good in period \(t=0\).

3.4 Government authorities

Banks that default on households’ deposits are bailed out by government authorities, which finance this bail-out by levying lump-sum taxes on all households. As a result, deposits are a safe investment. In practice, the use of deposits as a means of payment requires them to be safe.

4 Loanable-funds model

We outline the sequence of events in Sect. 4.1. In Sect. 4.2, we define and characterize equilibria with banks, and we investigate their welfare properties and implications.

4.1 Timeline of events

4.1.1 Period \(t=0\)

Households start with endowment W (equal to their equity) and first consume some amount of their physical good and then found and fund banks by providing them with an amount of physical good \(K_M\) in exchange for deposits \(D_H\) and equity contracts \(E_B\).Footnote 19 Banks lend the physical good \(K_M = L_M\) to firms using MT. They will repay the loans in the next period in terms of the physical good. Firms in the other sector are directly financed by households providing the firms with the remaining amount \(K_F\) of the physical good in exchange for bonds \(S_F\). These bonds represent the agreement that firms will deliver some amount of the physical good after production in the second period against the provision of one unit of the physical good in the first period.

The households’ and the banks’ balance sheets at the end of period \(t=0\) are shown in Table 1.

Table 1 Balance sheets at the end of period \(t=0\) in the loanable-funds model

\(E_H\) denotes the households’ equity. At the end of period \(t=0\), household equity is simply equal to the amount of the physical good invested in bonds, bank deposits, and bank equity. Hence, \(E_H = W - C_0\). In period \(t=1\), the households’ equity evolves depending on the returns on these investments and the profits of firms in both sectors of production.Footnote 20 We thus obtain the bank’s profits as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _B&= l_M R_L - d_H R_D \nonumber \\&= l_M (R_L - R_D) + e_B R_D. \end{aligned}$$
(1)

The interactions between agents during the first period are illustrated in Fig. 1.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Flows between agents in period \(t=0\)

4.1.2 Period \({t=1}\)

Entrepreneurs in MT produce \(f_M(K_M)\) units of the physical good and use this output to repay the loans \(L_M R_L\) to banks. Then banks that do not default against households repay them with \(D_H R_D\) and pay dividends \(E_B R_E\). Banks that default against households receive from them some taxes T. The lump-sum taxes the households have to pay are assumed to be considered an exogenous variable by households, who believe that they cannot influence the size of the lump-sum taxes by their actions. The bail-out makes it possible to pay the depositors \(D_H R_D\) in all circumstances. Entrepreneurs in FT produce \(f_F(K_F)\) units of the physical good and repay households \(K_F R_F\) for the use of \(K_F\) units of the physical good in period \(t=0\). Finally, the entrepreneurs in both sectors pay dividends to their shareholders.

Figure 2 summarizes the agents’ interactions in period \(t=1\).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Flows between agents in period \(t=1\)

4.2 Equilibria with banks

4.2.1 Definition

We define an equilibrium with banks as follows:

Definition 1

An equilibrium with banks in the sequential market process described in Sect. 4.1 with no bank default is defined as a tuple

$$\begin{aligned}&(R_E,R_D,R_L,R_F, \\&E_B,D_H,L_M,S_F, \\&K_M,K_F), \end{aligned}$$

such that

  • households hold some private deposits \(D_H > 0\) in period t = 0,

  • banks are founded and funded and receive a positive amount of equity \(E_B > 0\),

  • households maximize their utility

    $$\begin{aligned}&\max _{D_H,E_B,S_F, I \in [0,W]} \Bigl \{u(C_0) + \delta u(C_1) \Bigr \} \\ \text{ s.t. } \quad&\left\{ \begin{array}{lcl} C_0 &{} = &{} W - I, \\ C_1 &{} = &{} E_B R_E + D_H R_D + f_F(S_F) + f_M(E_B + D_H) - (E_B + D_H) R_L, \end{array} \right. \\ \text{ and } \quad&E_B + D_H + S_F = I, \end{aligned}$$

    taking gross rates of return \(R_E\), \(R_D\), and \(R_L\) as given, and

  • entrepreneurs in MT and FT maximize their shareholder value, given respectively by

    $$\begin{aligned}&\max _{K_M \in [0,I]} \{ \max (f_M(K_M) - K_M R_L, 0 ) \}, \\&\max _{K_F \in [0,I]} \{ \max (f_F(K_F) - K_F R_F, 0 ) \}, \end{aligned}$$

    taking gross rates of return \(R_L\) and \(R_F\) as well as investment I as given.

Henceforth, the superscript \(^*\) will be used to denote variables in equilibrium. We first characterize the optimum investment allocation. The social planner’s problem in the frictionless economy is given by

$$\begin{aligned}&\max _{\{K_M, K_F, I\}} u(W - I) + \delta u \bigl ( f_M(K_M) + f_F(K_F) \bigr ), \\ \text{ s.t. } \quad&\left\{ \begin{array}{l} 0 \le I \le W, \\ 0 \le K_F \le I, \\ 0 \le K_M \le I, \end{array} \right. \quad \text{ and } \quad I = K_M + K_F. \end{aligned}$$

We obtain

Proposition 1

There exists a unique optimal allocation \((I, K_M, K_F)\) with \(I \in (0,W)\) and \(K_F, K_M \in (0,I)\) which is defined by the following system of equations:

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{rcl} u'(W-I) &{} = &{} \delta u'\bigl (f_M(I-K_F) + f_F(K_F) \bigr ) f'_M(I-K_F), \\ f'_F(K_F) &{} = &{} f'_M(I-K_F), \\ I &{} = &{} K_F + K_M. \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

The proof of Proposition 1 is given in Appendix 4. We denote the first-best levels of \(K_F\), \(K_M\), and I by \(K_F^{FB}\), \(K_M^{FB}\), and \(I^{FB}\), respectively.

4.2.2 Individually optimal choices

We next examine equilibria with banks. Banks passively lend the amount of the physical good with which the households have provided them to firms using MT.Footnote 21 Regarding the households’ investment behavior, we can characterize the representative household’s optimal portfolio choice as follows:

Lemma 1

Suppose that there is no bank default. Then, the representative household’s portfolio choice \((E_B,D_H,S_F,I)\) involves 0 < I < W, and with EB > 0, DH > 0 it is optimal if

$$\begin{aligned} \delta f'_F(S_F^*(I)) u'\bigl (&(I - S_F^*(I) - D_H)(R_E - R_L) \\&+ D_H (R_D - R_L) + f_F(S_F^*(I)) + f_M(I - S_F^*(I)) \bigr ) = u'(W - I), \end{aligned}$$

where \(S_F^*(I)\) is the unique solution to

$$\begin{aligned} R_E - R_L + f'_M(I - S_F) = f'_F(S_F) \end{aligned}$$

and \(D_H\) has to fulfill

$$\begin{aligned} \bigl (R_E - R_L + f'_M(D_H) \bigr ) \delta u'\bigl (D_H (R_D - R_L) + f_F(S_F^*(I)) + f_M(D_H) \bigr ) \\ > u'(W - S_F^*(I) - D_H), \end{aligned}$$

and \(R_E = R_D.\) Reciprocally, such tuples constitute the representative household’s optimal portfolio choices.

The proof of Lemma 1 is given in Appendix 4. We now turn to the firms’ behavior.

Lemma 2

Demands for the physical good by firms using MT and FT are represented by two real-valued functions denoted by \({\hat{K}}_M: {\mathbb {R}}_{+}\times [0,W] \rightarrow [0,I]\) and \({\hat{K}}_F: {\mathbb {R}}_{+}\times [0,W] \rightarrow [0,I]\), respectively and given by

$$\begin{aligned}{\hat{K}}_M(R_L,I) = \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} I{} \le{ if } R_L \le f_M'(I), \\ f_M'^{-1}(R_L) {} \le{ otherwise. } \end{array} \right. \\ \le{ and } \quad{\hat{K}}_F(R_F,I) = \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} I{} \le{ if } R_F \le f_F'(I), \\ f_F'^{-1}(R_F) {} \le{ otherwise. } \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

The proof of Lemma 2 is given in Appendix 4.

4.2.3 Characterization

The preceding lemmata enable us to characterize all equilibria with banks. For this, we use the notation \(\varphi = \frac{E_B}{L_M}\) to denote the aggregate equity ratio of the banking system. We obtain

Theorem 1

All equilibria with banks take the following form:

$$\begin{aligned}&R_E^* = R_D^* = R_L^* = R_F^* = f'_F(K_F^{FB}), \end{aligned}$$
(2)
$$\begin{aligned}&E_B^* = \varphi ^* \bigl (I^{FB}- K_F^{FB}\bigr ), \quad D_H^* = (1-\varphi ^*) \bigl (I^{FB}- K_F^{FB}\bigr ), \end{aligned}$$
(3)
$$\begin{aligned}&L_M^* = \bigl (I^{FB}- K_F^{FB}\bigr ), \quad S_F^* = K_F^{FB}, \end{aligned}$$
(4)
$$\begin{aligned}&K_M^* = I^{FB}- K_F^{FB}, \quad K_F^* = K_F^{FB}, \end{aligned}$$
(5)

where the aggregate equity ratio \(\varphi ^* \in (0,1)\) is arbitrary. Equilibrium profits of firms and banks are given by

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _M^*&= f_M \bigl ( I^{FB}- K_F^{FB}\bigr ) - (I^{FB}- K_F^{FB}) f'_F(K_F^{FB}), \end{aligned}$$
(6)
$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _F^*&= f_F \bigl ( K_F^{FB}\bigr ) - K_F^{FB}f'_F(K_F^{FB}), \end{aligned}$$
(7)
$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _B^*&= \varphi ^* \bigl (I^{FB}- K_F^{FB}\bigr ) f'_F(K_F^{FB}). \end{aligned}$$
(8)

The proof of Theorem 1 is given in Appendix 4.

4.2.4 Welfare properties and implications

Theorem 1 directly implies

Corollary 1

The first-best allocation is implemented in any equilibrium with banks.

The capital structure of banks is indeterminate within the set of equilibria with banks, which are given in Theorem 1. This is a macroeconomic illustration of the Modigliani-Miller Theorem. As the gross rates of return on deposits and equity are equal and no equilibrium with banks involves any banks’ default, households do not have any preference between various possible capital structures. We obtain

Corollary 2

Given some aggregate equity ratio \(\varphi ^* \in (0,1)\), all equilibrium values with banks are uniquely determined.

5 Money-creation model

We first describe the institutional set-up in Sect. 5.1. Then we outline the detailed sequence of events in Sect. 5.2. Finally, in Sect. 5.3 we define and characterize equilibria with banks and investigate their welfare properties and implications. To help the reader to differentiate between nominal and real variables, subsequently we will use bold characters to denote the latter.

5.1 Institutional set-up

We impose favorable conditions on the functioning of the monetary architecture and the public authorities.

5.1.1 Interbank market and monies

In our current monetary architecture, there are two forms of money (public and private monies) and three types of money creation.Footnote 22 The central bank, which we also call “CB,” creates the first form of money when it grants loans to banks. This money is a claim of banks against the central bank and it is publicly created. We call it “CB deposits.” Commercial banks create the second form of money when they grant loans to firms or other banks. This money is a claim of households, firms, or banks against other banks. It is privately created by banks and destroyed when bank equity is bought and loans are repaid. We call it “private deposits.”

We now discuss the principles that connect the two forms of money. When private deposits are used in monetary transactions, these deposits are transferred from the buyer’s bank, say \(b_j\), to the seller’s bank, say \(b_i\). The settlement of this transaction requires Bank \(b_j\) to become liable to \(b_i\). There are now two options for these banks. Either Bank \(b_j\) applies for a loan from the CB and pays Bank \(b_i\) with CB deposits, or it directly obtains a loan from Bank \(b_i\). The institutional rule is that one unit of CB money settles one unit of liabilities of privately created money and that both types of money have the same unit. This sets the “exchange rate” between CB money and privately created money at 1.Footnote 23 Finally, we do not consider transaction costs for using CB or private deposits in monetary transactions.

We use \(p_I\) and \(p_C\) to denote the price of the physical good in period \(t=0\) and \(t=1\) in units of both publicly created and privately created monies, respectively. To differentiate nominal from real variables—i.e. variables denominated in terms of the physical good—, we express the latter in bold characters.

We integrate an interbank market. The same gross rate is applied to loans and deposits for borrowing and depositing among banks. Deposits owned by other banks and deposits owned by households cannot be discriminated. As a result, the gross rate on the interbank market is equal to the deposit gross rate paid to households, and we denote this gross rate by \(R_D\). The interbank market works as follows: At any time, banks can reimburse their debt against the CB by paying with their deposits at other banks, they can reimburse their interbank liabilities by paying with CB deposits, and they can require their debtor banks to reimburse their interbank liabilities in terms of CB deposits.Footnote 24 Accordingly, as long as banks can refinance themselves at the CB, interbank borrowing is not associated with default risk. Finally, we assume the following tie-breaking rule to simplify the analysis: If banks are indifferent between participating in the interbank market and transacting with the CB, they will choose the latter.

5.1.2 Role of public authorities

Two public authorities—a CB and a government—ensure the functioning of the monetary architecture. These authorities fulfill three roles. First, banks can obtain loans from the CB and can thus acquire CB deposits at the same policy gross rate \(R_{CB}\) at any stage of economic activities where \(R_{CB} - 1\) is the CB interest rate. This assumption implies that the exact flow of funds at any particular stage is irrelevant for banks’ decisions, as interest payments to or from the CB depend only on their net position at the end of the first period.Footnote 25 Second, government authorities levy very large penalties on the bankers who let their bank default on liabilities to any public authority.Footnote 26 As a result, banks will avoid defaulting on their obligations to the CB at all costs. Third, we assume that the CB buys interbank loans that cannot be repaid by the counterparty bank. By this mechanism, no bank defaults on interbank loans, as the very large penalties for defaulting against the CB translate into very large penalties for defaulting against other banks.

We explore equilibrium outcomes for different CB policy gross rates and we determine the associated level of welfare expressed in terms of household consumption. We assume that the CB aims at maximizing the welfare of households.

5.2 Timeline of events

In the following, we describe the sequence of events in more detail. To that end, we split each period into stages. Figure 3 illustrates the timeline of events.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Timeline of events

5.2.1 Period \({t=0}\)

Stage A: Banks are founded.

There are two cases. When no bank is founded because bank equity is not a profitable investment for households, there is a unique possible allocation of the physical good, which can be found in Sect. 5.2.2. In the other case, households promise to turn a predefined share \(\varphi \in (0,1]\) of their deposits into bank equity \(E_B = \varphi D_M\) before production in stage C. In the latter case, shareholder value per unit of equity is the gross rate of return on equity, and we denote it by \(R_E^{b} = \frac{\max (\Pi _B^{b},0)}{e_B}\). In the rest of Sect. 5.2, we concentrate on the case where households found and fund banks, unless we specify otherwise.

Stage B: Loans are granted to firms and money is created by banks.

Bank b grants loans \(l_M^b\) to firms using MT at the lending gross rate \(R_L\). \(d_M^b\) deposits at Bank b and the corresponding aggregate deposits \(D_M = L_M\) are simultaneously created in this process. The ratio of lending by a single Bank b to the average lending by all banks can be expressed as \(\alpha _M^b := \frac{l_M^b}{L_M}\).Footnote 27 MT firms’ deposits are spread across banks according to \(d_M^b\) (or \(\alpha _M^b\)).

Stage C: Firms in MT purchase the physical good and households invest in bank equity and firms in FT.

Households sell a part of their endowment of the physical good to firms using MT against bank deposits. They also buy \(S_F\) bonds at the real gross rate of return \(\mathbf{R}_{\mathbf{F}}\). These bonds are denominated in real terms, which means that one bond exchanges the delivery of \(\mathbf{R}_{\mathbf{F}}\) units of the physical good in the second period against one unit of the physical good in the first period.Footnote 28 Households consume the rest of their endowment. At the end of the first period, households use part of their deposits to buy the equity \(E_B\) that they promised in stage A. The purchase of bank equity destroys this part of deposits in the economy. We denote the individual amount of deposits after the purchase of bank equity by \(d_H\), and we denote the resulting aggregate amount of deposits by \(D_H = L_M - E_B\). At the end of the first period and depending on the amount of loans they have granted, some banks labeled \(b_j\) have liabilities \(l_{CB}^{b_j}\), and the other banks bi have claims \(d_{CB}^{b_i}\) against the CB. These processes are detailed in Appendix 1. The balance sheets are shown in Table 2, with EH denoting total households ownership.

Table 2 End of stage C: Banks’ and households’ balance sheets

The interactions between agents during the first period are illustrated in Fig. 4.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Flows between agents in period \(t=0\)

5.2.2 Period \(\mathbf {t=1}\)

In the second period, Bank b’s profitsFootnote 29 can be derived from the bank balance sheets given in Table 2 and using Equation (18) in Appendix 1 and Appendix 2:

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _B^{b}&= (1 - \alpha _M^b) L_M R_{CB} + \alpha _M^b L_M R_L - d_H R_D \nonumber \\&= (1 - \alpha _M^b) L_M R_{CB} + \alpha _M^b L_M R_L - (L_M - E_B) R_D \nonumber \\&= \alpha _M^b L_M (R_L - R_{CB}) + L_M (R_{CB} - R_D) + E_B R_D. \end{aligned}$$
(9)

Equation (9) holds for any bank, independently of whether it has deposits or liabilities at the central bank. As banks maximize their profits when choosing the level of lending determined by \(\alpha _M^b\), they will never default in any possible set of variables. We thus do not consider the case where banks default. The following description can be divided into two cases: Either no bank is founded, or some banks are founded and funded.

Case I: Banks are not founded.

In this case, \(E_B = 0\). This case represents an equilibrium. Such an equilibrium is called an “equilibrium without banks.” In such a situation, no money is created, and investment in MT is not possible. The physical good is thus entirely invested into Sector FT:Footnote 30

$$\begin{aligned} \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}^*= \mathbf{0}\quad \text{ and } \quad \quad \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^*= \mathbf{W}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(^*\) denotes equilibrium variables. This is an inefficient allocation, as Assumption 1 implies that it is socially desirable to invest a positive amount in MT.

Case II: Banks are founded.

Then the following stages occur:

Stage D: Firms produce and the government taxes households.

Firms produce in both sectors and repayments fall due. Profits from firms are given by

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _M&= \mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{M}}(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}) p_C - \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}R_L p_I, \\ {{\varvec{\Pi }}_{\mathbf{F}}}&= \mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{F}}(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}) - \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}\mathbf{R}_{\mathbf{F}}. \end{aligned}$$

The balance sheets are given in Table 3, where \(R_H\) denotes the resulting gross rate of return on household ownership of the physical goods and of both production technologies.

Table 3 End of stage D, no bank defaults: Banks’ and households’ balance sheets

Stage E: Dividends are paid and all debt is reimbursed and households consume.

Dividends from bank equity are distributed to shareholders. Households purchase the physical good for consumption. Debts are reimbursed. Appendix 2 details these processes. The banks’ balance sheets have empty balances, and households end up with all the consumption goods produced, \(\mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{M}}(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}) + \mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{F}}(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}})\).

The interactions between agents during the second period are illustrated in Fig. 5.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Flows between agents in period \(t=1\)

5.3 Equilibria with banks

5.3.1 Definition

The details of the sequential market process are given in Sect. 5.2. We only consider symmetric equilibria with banks in this setting, i.e. equilibria with banks in which all of them choose the same amount of lending and money creation. These banks thus have identical balance sheets in equilibrium. Moreover, the policy gross rate \(R_{CB}\) is set by the CB, so that equilibria with banks are dependent on this choice.

Definition 2

We assume that the central bank sets the policy gross rate \(R_{CB}\). The setting is given by the sequential market process in Sect. 5.2. We define a symmetric equilibrium with banks in this setting as a tuple

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathcal {E}} := \,&\Bigl (\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}},\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}, \\&E_B,D_H,L_M,S_F, \\&R_E,R_D,R_L,\mathbf{R}_{\mathbf{F}},p_I,p_C \Bigr ) \end{aligned}$$

consisting of physical investment allocations, savings, and finite and positive gross rates of return and prices, such that

  • some private deposits \(D_H > 0\) are held by households at the end of stage C,

  • households maximize their utility

    $$\begin{aligned}&\max _{\{D_H,E_B,S_F, \mathbf{I}\in [\mathbf{0},\mathbf{W}]\}} \Bigl \{u(\mathbf{C}_{\mathbf{0}}) + \delta u(\mathbf{C}_{\mathbf{1}}) \Bigr \} \\ \text{ s.t. } \quad&\left\{ \begin{array}{lcl} \mathbf{C}_{\mathbf{0}}&{} = &{} \mathbf{W}- \mathbf{I}, \\ \mathbf{C}_{\mathbf{1}}&{} = &{} \dfrac{E_B R_E + D_H R_D - (E_B + D_H) R_L}{p_C} \\ &{} &{} + \mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{F}}(S_F) + \mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{M}}\left( \dfrac{E_B + D_H}{p_I}\right) , \end{array} \right. \\ \text{ and } \quad&E_B + D_H + p_I S_F = p_I \mathbf{I}, \end{aligned}$$

    taking prices \(p_I\) and \(p_C\) as well as gross rates of return \(R_E\), \(R_D\), and \(R_L\) as given,

  • each bank \(b \in [0,1]\) and all firms maximize their shareholder value,Footnote 31 given respectively by

    $$\begin{aligned}&\max _{\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}\in [\mathbf{0},\mathbf{W}]} \{ \max (\mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{M}}(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}) p_C - \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}R_L p_I, 0 ) \}, \\&\max _{\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}\in [\mathbf{0},\mathbf{W}]} \{ \max (\mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{F}}(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}) - \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}\mathbf{R}_{\mathbf{F}}, 0 ) \}, \\ \text{ and } \quad&\max _{\alpha _M^b \ge 0} \{ \max (\alpha _M^b L_M (R_L - R_{CB}) + L_M (R_{CB} - R_D) + E_B R_D,0)\}, \end{aligned}$$

    taking prices \(p_I\) and \(p_C\) as well as gross rates of return \(R_D\), \(R_L\), and \(\mathbf{R}_{\mathbf{F}}\) as given,

  • the same level of money creation is chosen by all banks, and

  • markets for the physical good clear in both periods.

In the remainder of the paper, we only consider symmetric equilibria with banks. However, we may omit the word “symmetric” for ease of presentation. We can write the social planner’s problem as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&\max _{\{\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}, \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}, \mathbf{I}\}} u(\mathbf{W}- \mathbf{I}) + \delta u \bigl ( \mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{M}}(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}) + \mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{F}}(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}) \bigr ) \\ \text{ s.t. } \quad&\left\{ \begin{array}{l} 0 \le \mathbf{I}\le \mathbf{W}, \\ 0 \le \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}\le \mathbf{I}, \\ 0 \le \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}\le \mathbf{I}, \end{array} \right. \quad \text{ and } \quad \mathbf{I}= \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}+ \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}. \end{aligned}$$

We obtain

Proposition 2

There exists a unique optimal allocation of the social planner’s problem \((\mathbf{I}, \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}, \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}})\) with \(\mathbf{I}\in (\mathbf{0},\mathbf{W})\) and \(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}, \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}\in (\mathbf{0},\mathbf{I})\), which is defined by the following system of equations:

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{rcl} u'(\mathbf{W}-\mathbf{I}) &{} = &{} \delta u'\bigl (\mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{M}}(\mathbf{I}-\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}) + \mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{F}}(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}) \bigr ) \mathbf{f'}_{\mathbf{M}}(\mathbf{I}-\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}), \\ \mathbf{f'}_{\mathbf{F}}(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}) &{} = &{} \mathbf{f'}_{\mathbf{M}}(\mathbf{I}-\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}), \\ \mathbf{I}&{} = &{} \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}+ \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}. \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

The proof of Proposition 2 is identical to that of Proposition 1, which is given in Appendix 4. We denote the first-best levels of \(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}\), \(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}\), and \(\mathbf{I}\) by \(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}}\), \(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}^{\mathbf{FB}}\), and \(\mathbf{I}^{\mathbf{FB}}\), respectively.

5.3.2 Individually optimal choices

In this section, we determine the optimal strategies of banks, households, and firms. We first establish the way in which the deposit gross rate is related to the policy gross rate. The absence of arbitrage opportunities on the interbank market in any equilibrium with banks implies

Lemma 3

The nominal gross rate on the interbank market is equal to

$$\begin{aligned} R_D^* = R_{CB} \end{aligned}$$

in any equilibrium with banks.

The proof of Lemma 3 is given in Appendix 4. It uses the absence of arbitrage opportunities on the interbank market in any equilibrium with banks. Banks could exploit any differential in the gross rates by lending or borrowing on the interbank market to increase their shareholder value.

We next examine the amount of money created by an individual bank. Whenever there is no finite optimum amount of money creation, we denote the banks’ strategy by “\(\infty \).” We thus obtain

Proposition 3

We assume that \(R_D = R_{CB}\). Then, we denote byFootnote 32\({\hat{\alpha }}_M: {\mathbb {R}}_{++}^2 \rightarrow {\mathcal {P}}({\mathbb {R}} \cup \{+\infty \})\) the sets of individually optimum amounts of lending and money creation by a single bank. This correspondence is given by

$$\begin{aligned} {\hat{\alpha }}_M \bigl ( R_L, R_{CB}\bigr ) = \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \{ + \infty \} &{} \text{ if } R_L > R_{CB}, \\ \left[ 0, +\infty \right) &{} \text{ if } R_L = R_{CB}, \\ \{ 0 \} &{} \text{ if } R_L < R_{CB}. \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

The proof of Proposition 3 is given in Appendix 4. The banks’ behavior only depends on \(R_L - R_{CB}\), which is the intermediation margin. If the intermediation margin is zero, it is obvious that banks are indifferent between all lending levels. For positive intermediation margins, banks would like to grant as many loans as possible. When the intermediation margin is negative, banks will choose not to grant any loan. In the following, we describe the representative household’s portfolio choice:

Lemma 4

The representative household’s portfolio choice \((E_B,D_H,S_F,\mathbf{I})\) is optimal for all \(\mathbf{I}> \mathbf{0}\) such that

$$\begin{aligned} \delta \mathbf{f'}_{\mathbf{F}}\bigl (S_F^*(\mathbf{I})\bigr ) u'\Biggl (&\bigl (p_I \mathbf{I}- p_I S_F^*(\mathbf{I}) - D_H \bigr ) \frac{R_E - R_L}{p_C} \\&+ D_H \frac{R_D - R_L}{p_C} + \mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{F}}\bigl (S_F^*(\mathbf{I})\bigr ) + \mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{M}}\bigl (\mathbf{I}- S_F^*(\mathbf{I})\bigr ) \Biggr ) = u'(\mathbf{W}- \mathbf{I}), \end{aligned}$$

where \(S_F^*(\mathbf{I})\) is the unique solution to

$$\begin{aligned} p_I \frac{R_E - R_L}{p_C} + \mathbf{f'}_{\mathbf{M}}(\mathbf{I}- S_F) = \mathbf{f'}_{\mathbf{F}}(S_F) \end{aligned}$$
(10)

and \(D_H\) is small enough such that

$$\begin{aligned} \left( p_I \frac{R_E - R_L}{p_C} + \mathbf{f'}_{\mathbf{M}}\left( \frac{D_H}{p_I}\right) \right) \delta u'\Biggl (D_H \frac{R_D - R_L}{p_C} + \mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{F}}(S_F^*(\mathbf{I})) + \mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{M}}\left( \frac{D_H}{p_I}\right) \Biggr ) \\ > u'\left( \mathbf{W}- S_F^*(\mathbf{I}) - \frac{D_H}{p_I}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

In addition, \(R_E = R_D\) has to hold. Reciprocally, such tuples constitute the representative household’s optimum portfolio choices.

The proof of Lemma 4 is similar to that of Lemma 1, which is given in Appendix 4. We now turn to firms’ behavior.

Lemma 5

Demands for the physical good by firms using MT and FT are represented by two real functions denoted by \({{\hat{\mathbf{K}}}_{\mathbf{M}}}: {\mathbb {R}}_{+}\times [\mathbf{0},\mathbf{W}] \rightarrow [\mathbf{0},\mathbf{I}]\) and \({{\hat{\mathbf{K}}}_{\mathbf{F}}}: {\mathbb {R}}_{+}\times [\mathbf{0},\mathbf{W}] \rightarrow [\mathbf{0},\mathbf{I}]\), respectively and given by

$$\begin{aligned}&{{\hat{\mathbf{K}}}_{\mathbf{M}}}(R_L,\mathbf{I}) = \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \mathbf{I}&{} if \dfrac{R_L}{p_C} p_I \le \mathbf{f'}_{\mathbf{M}}(\mathbf{I}), \\ {f'}_{M}^{-1}\left( \frac{R_L}{p_C} p_I\right) &{} otherwise. \end{array} \right. \\ and \quad&{{\hat{\mathbf{K}}}_{\mathbf{F}}}(\mathbf{R}_{\mathbf{F}},\mathbf{I}) = \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \mathbf{I}&{} if \mathbf{R}_{\mathbf{F}}\le \mathbf{f'}_{\mathbf{F}}(\mathbf{I}), \\ \mathbf{f'}_{\mathbf{F}}^{-1}(\mathbf{R}_{\mathbf{F}}) &{} otherwise. \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

The proof of Lemma 5 is similar to that of Lemma 2, which is given in Appendix 4.

5.3.3 Characterization

The preceding lemmata enable us to characterize all equilibria with banks.

Theorem 2

Given some CB policy gross rate \(R_{CB}\), all equilibria with banks take the following form:

$$\begin{aligned}R_E^* = R_D^* = R_L^* = R_{CB} = p_C^* \frac{\mathbf{R}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{*}}}{p_I^*} = p_C^* \frac{\rm{f'}_{\rm F}(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}})}{p_I^*}, \end{aligned}$$
(11)
$$\begin{aligned}&E_B^* = \varphi ^* \bigl (\mathbf{I}^{\mathbf{FB}}- \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}}\bigr ), \quad D_H^* = (1-\varphi ^*) \bigl (\mathbf{I}^{\mathbf{FB}}- \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}}\bigr ), \end{aligned}$$
(12)
$$\begin{aligned}&L_M^* = \bigl (\mathbf{I}^{\mathbf{FB}}- \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}}\bigr ), \quad S_F^* = \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}}, \end{aligned}$$
(13)
$$\begin{aligned}&\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{M}}^*= \mathbf{I}^{\mathbf{FB}}- \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}}, \quad \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^*= \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}}, \end{aligned}$$
(14)

where the aggregate equity ratio \(\varphi ^* \in (0,1)\) and \(p_I^* > 0\) are arbitrary. Equilibrium profits of firms and banks are given by

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _M^*&= p_C^* \Bigl (\mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{M}}\bigl ( \mathbf{I}^{\mathbf{FB}}- \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}}\bigr ) - (\mathbf{I}^{\mathbf{FB}}- \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}}) \mathbf{f'}_{\mathbf{F}}(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}}) \Bigr ), \end{aligned}$$
(15)
$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _F^*&= \mathbf{f}_{\mathbf{F}}\bigl ( \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}}\bigr ) - \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}}\mathbf{f'}_{\mathbf{F}}(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}}), \end{aligned}$$
(16)
$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _B^*&= \varphi ^* p_C^* \bigl (\mathbf{I}^{\mathbf{FB}}- \mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}}\bigr ) \mathbf{f'}_{\mathbf{F}}(\mathbf{K}_{\mathbf{F}}^{\mathbf{FB}}). \end{aligned}$$
(17)

The proof of Theorem 2 is similar to that of Theorem 1, which is given in Appendix 4. We now make the following observations.

First, we examine the equilibrium conditions in detail. All nominal gross rates are equal to the policy gross rate set by the CB, as expressed in (11). There is a unique equilibrium with banks in real terms, i.e. with respect to the physical allocation to both sectors, which is shown in (14), and thus with regard to the real values of saving and lending in (13), where \(L_M^*\) is divided by \(p_I^*\). Equations (15), (16), and (17) represent the profits of firms and banks. Firms’ dividends from Sector FT are distributed in the form of the physical good, while banks and firms in Sector MT distribute dividends in the form of deposits.

Second, the system is indeterminate with regard to the price of the physical good in period \(t=0\) and the capital structure. This has two implications. The economic system is nominally anchored by the price of the physical good in \(t=0\) and the CB interest rate, which determine prices and interest rates, and the banks’ capital ratio determines the asset structure and the payment processes.

Third, the theorem implies that there are no incentives for banks to create more private money. The creation of money by a bank above the average level of money created would require the bank to borrow from the central bank at the gross rate \(R_{CB}\), as the deposits created in excess of the average level of money would flow to other banks. Since all nominal gross rates are equal to the policy gross rates, this additional money creation is not profitable.

Fourth, the physical investment allocation does not depend on the capital structure, so bank equity capital does not need to be regulated. Fifth, the physical investment allocation is independent of the CB policy gross rate. Monetary policy is neutral. Sixth, in an equilibrium with banks, all banks create the same amount of money and, after the payment processes in stage C in period \(t = 0\) (see Figure 3), end up with the same amount of household deposits. Hence, in equilibrium, no interbank liabilities emerge and banks do not need to borrow central bank money from the CB to settle interbank liabilities. Hence, positive nominal interest rates are sustained in equilibrium since the banking system as a whole does not incur repayment obligations in \(t = 0\) against the central bank and thus does not need to pay these obligations back later, plus interest.

The conclusion also holds out of equilibrium. If an individual bank creates more private money than another bank through higher loan financing, it ends up with higher deposit outflows than the other banks, and thus has to borrow reserves from the central bank to settle interbank liabilities. However, the other banks obtain the additional amount of reserves and the banking system as a whole has again no liabilities against the central bank.

Hence, also in such cases out of equilibrium, the banking system does not need any further means at the end of the lifetime. Banks that have initially received reserves will obtain interests on their deposits at the CB, but need these reserves to settle the higher outflow of deposits and end up with zero central bank reserves. Banks who have initially borrowed reserves are charged with interest rates on these liabilities, but will receive exactly the same amount of reserves when higher loan repayments lead to less outflow of deposits.

Finally, we note that the money market clears as follows. Whenever banks have decided to create a certain amount of money and the central bank has set its nominal interest rate \(R_{CB}\), prices for investment goods and all other interest rates adjust, such that the money market and commodity markets clear.

In the next subsection, we investigate the welfare properties of the equilibria with banks found in Theorem 2, and we compare them with the ones found for the loanable-funds model in Theorem 1.

5.3.4 Welfare properties and implications

The equilibria with banks described in Theorem 2 are indeterminate in two respects, (a) with regard to the price of the physical good in period \(t=0\) and (b) with regard to the capital structure of banks. In the former case, we simply have a price normalization problem, and we can set \(p_I = 1\) without loss of generality. The indifference between various potential capital structures is a macroeconomic illustration of the Modigliani-Miller Theorem. As the gross rates of return on deposits and equity are equal and no equilibrium with banks involves any banks’ default, households do not have any preference between various possible capital structures. Moreover, the specific capital structure of banks has no impact on money creation and lending by banks. We thus immediately obtain

Corollary 3

Given \(p_I = 1\) and some \(\varphi ^* \in (0,1)\), all equilibrium values are uniquely determined when the CB sets the policy gross rate \(R_{CB}\).

Finally, we can compare the equilibria with banks in the loanable-funds model given in Theorem 1 and the equilibria in the money-creation model given in Theorem 2. We obtain

Theorem 3

The investment and consumption allocation in any equilibrium with banks in the loanable-funds model is the same as the one in any equilibrium with banks in the money-creation model. This allocation is first-best.

6 Extensions and discussions

So far, we have focused on the equivalence between the loanable-funds and the money-creation model. We next explore extensions and several critical issues of our model and the results.

6.1 Extensions

Of course, there are various possibilities for extending the benchmark, such as infinite horizon set-ups and growth processes. As long as there is no uncertainty and thus no bank default, the logic set out in this paper regarding the equivalence of the loanable-funds and money-creation approaches can be expected to hold in these macroeconomic environments.

More subtle extensions concern the following scenario. There is aggregate productivity risk, e.g. production functions are of the types \({\tilde{\eta }} f_F (K_F)\) and \({\tilde{\eta }} f_M (K_M)\), where \({\tilde{\eta }}\) is a random variable with possible realizations \(\eta _{i} \in {\mathbb {R}}_+, i \in \{1,\ldots , n\}\), with \(0< \eta _{1}< \cdots < \eta _{n}\). The value \({\tilde{\eta }} = \eta _{i}\) occurs with probability \(p_{\eta _j}\), with \(\Sigma ^\eta _{i = 1} p_{\eta _j} = 1\).

The proof for the equivalence of the loanable-funds approach and the money-creation approach can be repeated under the following conditions: complete markets, all contracts (loan contracts and deposit contracts) and central bank policy gross rates are made contingent on the state of the world, consumption good markets clear in every state of the world, and all the institutional characteristics—including sufficiently large penalties for defaults against central banks—continue to exist. Then, in such an environment with complete markets and contingent contracts, the equivalence continues to hold, as the proof for the equivalence can be repeated step by step for this environment. However, with aggregate productivity risk, new type of equilibria may emerge. As already shown in Faure and Gersbach (2016) in a much simpler setting, asymmetric equilibria occur in which money creation is different among groups of banks, some banks default and total investments by banks are inefficiently highFootnote 33. Hence, the equivalence between loanable-funds and the money-creation model only holds in a restricted sense, i.e., there is an equilibrium in the money-creation model that replicates the investment and consumption allocation in the equilibrium of the loanable-funds model, but the set of equilibria in both models differ.

6.2 Determination of the price level

We observe that the equilibrium relationship between nominal and real interest rates and commodity prices today and tomorrow in the money-creation model are governed by the Fisher equation. Indeed, from the equilibrium condition (11), we obtain \(1 + r = (1 + \pi ) (1 + \mathbf{r} )\), where r (\(= R^*_D - 1\)) is the nominal interest rate, \(\pi = \frac{p^*_c}{p^*_I} - 1\) is the inflation rate and \(\mathbf{r} = \mathbf {R^*_F} - 1\) is the real interest rate. As long as \(\mathbf{r} \) and \(\pi \) are small, we obtain \(r \approx \mathbf{r} + \pi \).

In the money-creation model, however, the initial price level is indeterminate and thus the model does not anchor prices. This problem can be resolved by adopting ideas from Dubey and Geanakoplos (1992) and two changes of the model. First, we assume that households start with an endowment of outside money, say M, measured in the unit of account. The outside money would typically be banknotes issued by the central bank. Second, banks would be required to hold a fraction of their issued deposits as banknotes at the central bank. If households exchange their outside money at the beginning into bank deposits to earn interests, banks obtain M and can create bank deposits subject to the reserve requirement. This essentially constrains bank deposit creation and anchors the price of the investment good.

In order to make sure that markets clear in period \(t=1\), all inside money is destroyed and banknotes stay at the central bank, the easiest way is to require that the reserves in the form of outside money stay at the central bank forever (or banks are taxed by this amount). In addition, there has to be a uniquely determined equilibrium spread between loan and deposit rates such that the repayment obligation of firms is identical to the amount of deposits households have in period \(t=1\) to buy consumption goods.Footnote 34

6.3 Money neutrality

The equivalence between the loanable funds and the money creation approach implies that money is neutral, i.e. if the banking system creates a higher amount of bank deposits, this has no impact on the investment and consumption allocation. The neutrality of money in our context arises because a higher amount of private deposits created by banks leads to a proportional increase of the price of investment goods and a subsequent proportional increase of consumption goods. The real purchasing power of firms and households remains unaffected. This parallels other money neutrality results. For instance, in economies with a cash-in-advance economy, no uncertainty, no default, and a representative agent, money is neutral, i.e. changing the endowment of money has no impact on commodity allocations (see e.g. Walsh 2017).

In our context, the essential constraint to obtain equilibria in which money has value is that a fraction of firms has to rely on banks. Specifically, banks competitively create money in the form of deposits that allow these firms to buy investment goods. Since bank deposits are interest-bearing, no deposit-in-advance constraint needs to be imposed to obtain the equilibria in which bank deposits are held.

7 Conclusion

The purpose of this paper was to establish the equivalence between the loanable-funds approach and the money-creation approach for particular macroeconomic environments. In such environments, it is much easier to use the shortcut loanable-funds approach, and this paper serves as a justification for using this shortcut. A final remark is in order. To model the properties, challenges (see e.g. Gersbach 2021), and implications of changes in our monetary system, the money creation approach is the suitable framework to be used.