Skip to main content
Log in

Equilibria in second-price auctions with private participation costs

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Economic Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study equilibria in second-price auctions where bidders are independently and privately informed about both their values and participation costs, and where the joint distributions of these values and costs across bidders are not necessarily identical. We show that there always exists an equilibrium in this general setting with two-dimensional types of ex ante heterogeneous bidders. When bidders are ex ante homogeneous, there is a unique symmetric equilibrium, but asymmetric equilibria may also exist. We provide conditions under which the equilibrium is unique (not only among symmetric ones). We find that the marginal density of participation costs and the concentration of values matter for the uniqueness. The presence of private information on participation costs tends to reduce multiplicity of participation equilibria, although multiplicity still persists.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Several related terms have been used in the literature, including participation cost, entry fee, entry cost, or opportunity cost. Since we only study equilibrium behavior, we do not need to distinguish between (bidder) participation costs and entry fees (charged by the seller.)

  2. Our analysis in this paper applies to standard English auctions or ascending-price auctions. In this scenario, bidders who participate will stay in the auction until the price reaches their valuations and the participation conditions are identical to those in second-price auctions, which we analyze in this paper.

  3. In another recent paper, Xu et al. (2013) study how resale affects both the entry decision and bidding behavior in a second-price auction model with two-dimensional types of bidders and binomially distributed entry costs, focusing on the symmetric equilibrium.

  4. The literature starts with Samuelson (1985), Stegeman (1996), and Campbell (1998) are among the early contributors. See Kaplan and Sela (2006), Tan and Yilankaya (2006), Celik and Yilankaya (2009), Lu (2009), Cao and Tian (2010, 2013) for some of the more recent contributions.

  5. There is another strand of literature where bidders learn their values after incurring their (commonly known) participation costs, see, for example, McAfee and McMillan (1987), Tan (1992), and Levin and Smith (1994).

  6. The support for valuations is set to be [0, 1] by normalization. Bidders with participation costs higher than 1 will not participate in the auction and such a type of bidder is of no practical interest. If the upper bounds of the supports for the participation costs are higher than 1, the above distributions on the participation costs should be interpreted as the truncated distributions of the original distributions on [0, 1]. All the derivations in the paper hold with this interpretation.

  7. We will study the special case where \(v_i\) and \(c_i\) are independently distributed in Sects. 4 and  5.

  8. When there are atoms in the distribution, \(k_i(v_i,c_i)\) can incorporate Dirac delta functions to handle the infinite density.

  9. Lu and Sun (2007) show that, for any auction mechanism with participation costs, the participating and non-participating types of bidders are divided by a non-decreasing and equicontinuous shutdown curve.

  10. It is well known that there are other (dominated) equilibria of second-price auctions when there is no cost of participation (see Blume and Heidhues (2004) for the characterization of all equilibria). In this paper, we restrict to cutoff equilibria, where all participating bidders bid their valuations.

  11. In equilibrium, \(c_i^*(v_i)\) depends on the distributions of all bidders’ valuations and participation costs.

  12. The description of the equilibria can be slightly different under different informational structures on \(K_i(v_i,c_i)\). For example, when \(v_i\) is private information and \(c_i\) is exogenously fixed for all bidders, \(K_i(v_i, c_i) = F_i(v_i)\) (see Campbell 1998; Stegeman 1996; Tan and Yilankaya 2006; Cao and Tian 2013) and the equilibrium is described by a valuation cutoff \(v_i^*\) for each bidder i such that bidder i submits a bid whenever \(v_i\ge v_i^*\).

  13. Uniqueness of the symmetric equilibrium has been addressed in the literature for the special cases where either costs (see Campbell 1998; Tan and Yilankaya 2006) or valuations (see Kaplan and Sela 2006) are commonly known. Laffont and Green (1984) investigated the existence and uniqueness of the symmetric equilibrium in a symmetric model where valuations and participation costs are uniformly distributed.

  14. Following their proof of Lemma 3, when \(n=2\),

    $$\begin{aligned} |F(\lambda ^{t+1}(\theta ))-F(\lambda ^{t}(\theta ))|= & {} |\int _0^{\theta }\int _m^1[\lambda ^{t}(\tau )-\lambda ^{t+1}(\tau )]{\mathrm{d}}\tau {\mathrm{d}}m|\\\le & {} \int _0^{\theta }\int _m^1|\lambda ^{t}(\tau )-\lambda ^{t+1}(\tau )|{\mathrm{d}}\tau {\mathrm{d}}m<\Vert \lambda ^{t}(\cdot )-\lambda ^{t+1}(\cdot )\Vert \int _0^{\theta }{\mathrm{d}}m. \end{aligned}$$

    Thus,

    $$\begin{aligned} \Vert F(\lambda ^{t+1}(\cdot ))-F(\lambda ^t(\cdot ))\Vert <\Vert \lambda ^{t}(\cdot )-\lambda ^{t+1}(\cdot )\Vert . \end{aligned}$$

    The Contraction Mapping Theorem can be applied to show the uniqueness of the equilibrium without using the claim that Laffont and Green (1984) made at the beginning of their proof. The above statement can be treated as a special case for our proof to Proposition 1.

  15. See Stegeman (1996), Campbell (1998), Tan and Yilankaya (2006), Cao and Tian (2013), and Kaplan and Sela (2006) for multiplicity when the costs or valuations are commonly known.

  16. We can extend the supports of the distributions to be \([0,1]\times [0,1]\) by assigning zero density over the extended areas \([0,1]\times [0,1]\setminus [v_l,v_h]\times [c_l, c_h]\) with \(c_h\le v_h\). Then, by Theorem 1, an equilibrium exists.

  17. Note that since \(v_l=0<c_l\), the condition in Corollary 1 is violated. Moreover, there cannot be an equilibrium in which one bidder always participates. If \(F(\cdot )\) is concave on a support with a positive lower bound, this potentially induces convexity on some interval in [0, 1], which may induce asymmetric equilibria. See Tan and Yilankaya (2006) for more on this issue.

  18. Also see Stegeman (1996) for an example of an asymmetric ex ante efficient auction.

References

  • Blume, A., Heidhues, P.: All equilibria of the vickrey auction. J. Econ. Theory 114, 170–177 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burton, T.A.: Stability and Periodic Solutions of Ordinary and Functional Differential Equations. Dover Publications Inc, Mineola, New York (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, C.M.: Coordination in auctions with entry. J. Econ. Theory 82, 425–450 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cao, X., Tian, G.: Equilibria in first price auctions with participation costs. Games Econ. Behav. 69, 258–273 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cao, X., Tian, G.: Second price auctions with different participation costs. J. Econ. Manag. Strategy 22(1), 184–205 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Celik, G., Yilankaya, O.: Optimal auctions with simultaneous and costly participation. BE J. Theor. Econ. 9(1), 1–33 (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gal, S., Landsberger, M., Nemirovski, A.: Participation in auctions. Games Econ. Behav. 60, 75–103 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, J., Laffont, J.J.: Participation constraints in the vickrey auction. Econ. Lett. 16, 31–36 (1984)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan, T.R., Sela, A.: Second price auctions with private entry costs. Working paper (2006)

  • Levin, D., Smith, J.L.: Equilibrium in auctions with entry. Am. Econ. Rev. 84, 585–599 (1994)

    Google Scholar 

  • Lu, J.: Auction design with opportunity cost. Econ. Theory 38, 73–103 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lu, J., Sun, Y.: Efficient auctions with private participation costs. Working Paper (2007)

  • McAfee, R.P., McMillan, J.: Auctions with entry. Econ. Lett. 23, 343–347 (1987)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, W.F.: Competitive bidding with entry costs. Econ. Lett. 17, 53–57 (1985)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stegeman, M.: Participation costs and efficient auctions. J. Econ. Theory 71, 228–259 (1996)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tan, G.: Entry and R&D costs in procurement contracting. J. Econ. Theory 58, 41–60 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tan, G., Yilankaya, O.: Equilibria in second price auction with participation costs. J. Econ. Theory 130, 205–219 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vickrey, W.: Counterspeculation, auctions, and competitive sealed tenders. J. Finance 16, 8–37 (1961)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xu, X., Levin, D., Ye, L.: Auctions with entry and resale. Games Econ. Behav. 79, 92–105 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Guofu Tan.

Additional information

We thank three anonymous referees and a co-editor for helpful comments and suggestions that substantially improved the paper. Xiaoyong Cao thanks the financial supports from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (NSFC-71201030) and “the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities” in UIBE (14YQ02). Guoqiang Tian thanks the financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (NSFC-71371117). Okan Yilankaya thanks the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada and a Marie Curie International Reintegration Grant for financial support.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Lemma 1

If \(m_i=0\), none of the other bidders will participate, the probability of which is

$$\begin{aligned} \prod _{j\ne i}F_{c_j^{*}}(0)=\prod _{j\ne i}\int _{0}^{1}\int _{c_j^*(\tau )}^{1}k_j(\tau ,c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j{\mathrm{d}}\tau . \end{aligned}$$

Otherwise, at least one other bidder submits a bid. Then,

$$\begin{aligned} \prod _{j\ne i}F_{c_j^{*}}(m_i)=\prod _{j\ne i}\left[ 1-\int _{m_i}^1\int _0^{c_j^*(\tau )}k_j(\tau , c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j{\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] . \end{aligned}$$

Thus, the cutoff for individual i, \(i\in {1,2,\ldots n}\), which is \(c_i^{*}(v)=\int _{0}^{v}(v_i-m_i){\mathrm{d}}\prod _{j\ne i} F_{c_j^{*}}(m_i)\), can be expressed as

$$\begin{aligned} c_i^{*}(v)= & {} \int _{0}^{v}(v_i-m_i){\mathrm{d}}\prod _{j\ne i}\left[ 1-\int _{m_i} ^1\int _0^{(c_j^*(\tau ))}k_j(\tau , c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] \\&+\,v\prod _{j\ne i} \left[ \int _{0}^{1}\int _{(c_j^*(\tau ))}^{1}k_j(\tau ,c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j{\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] . \end{aligned}$$

Integrating by parts, we have

$$\begin{aligned} c_i^{*}(v)= & {} \int _{0}^{v}(v-m_i){\mathrm{d}}\prod _{j\ne i}\left[ 1-\int _{m_i}^1\int _0^{(c_j^*(\tau ))}k_j(\tau ,c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] \\&+\,v\prod _{j\ne i}\left[ \int _{0}^{1}\int _{(c_j^*(\tau ))}^{1}k_j (\tau ,c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] \\= & {} (v-m_i)\prod _{j\ne i}\left[ 1-\int _{m_i}^1\int _0^{(c_j^*(\tau ))}k_j(\tau , c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] \big |_{0}^{v_i}\\&+\,v\prod _{j\ne i}\left[ \int _{0}^{1}\int _{(c_j^*(\tau ))}^{1}k_j(\tau ,c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] \\&+\int _{0}^{v}\prod _{j\ne i}\left[ 1-\int _{m_i}^1\int _0^{(c_j^*(\tau ))}k_j(\tau , c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] {\mathrm{d}}m_i\\= & {} -v\prod _{j\ne i}\left[ 1-\int _{0}^1\int _0^{(c_j^*(\tau ))}k_j(\tau , c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] \\&+\,v\prod _{j\ne i}\left[ \int _{0}^{1}\int _{(c_j^*(\tau ))}^{1}k_j(\tau ,c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] \\&+\int _{0}^{v}\prod _{j\ne i}\left[ 1-\int _{m_i}^1\int _0^{(c_j^*(\tau ))}k_j(\tau , c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] {\mathrm{d}}m_i. \end{aligned}$$

Since

$$\begin{aligned} \int _{0}^1\int _0^{(c_j^*(\tau ))}k_j(\tau , c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau {+}\int _{0}^{1}\int _{(c_j^*(\tau ))}^{1}k_j(\tau ,c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau = \int _0^1\int _0^{1}k_j(\tau , c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau {=}1, \end{aligned}$$

thus we have

$$\begin{aligned} c_i^{*}(v)=\int _{0}^{v}\prod _{j\ne i}\left[ 1-\int _{m_i}^1\int _0^{c_j^*(\tau )}k_j(\tau , c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] {\mathrm{d}}m_i. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 2

  1. (i)

    Let \(v=0\) in the expression of \(c_i^{*}(v)\), we have the result.

  2. (ii)

    Since

    $$\begin{aligned} c_i^{*}(v)=\int _{0}^{v}\prod _{j\ne i}\left[ 1-\int _{m_i}^1\int _0^{c_j^*(\tau )}k_j(\tau , c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] {\mathrm{d}}m_i \leqslant \int _0^{v}{\mathrm{d}}m_i=v \end{aligned}$$

    by \(0\le \int _{m_i}^1\int _0^{c_j^*(\tau )}k_j(\tau , c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j{\mathrm{d}}\tau \le \int _{0}^{1}\int _{0}^{1}k_j(\tau , c_j) {\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau = 1\), thus \(0\le c_i^{*}(v)\le v\).

  3. (iii)

    Letting \(v=1\) in (3), we have the result.

  4. (iv)
    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm{d}}c^*_i(v)}{{\mathrm{d}} v}=\prod _{j\ne i}\left[ 1-\int _{v}^1\int _0^{c_j^*(\tau )}k_j(\tau , c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] \ge 0 \end{aligned}$$

    by noting that \(\int _{v}^1\int _0^{c_j^*(\tau )}k_j(\tau , c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau \le 1\). Then,

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm{d}}^2 c^*_i(v)}{{\mathrm{d}} v^2}{=}\sum _{k\ne i}\prod _{j\ne i, j\ne k}\left[ 1{-}\int _{v}^1\int _0^{c_j^*(\tau )}k_j(\tau , c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] \int _0^{c_k^*(v)}k_j(\tau , c_j){\mathrm{d}}c_j {\mathrm{d}}\tau {\ge } 0. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Proof of Theorem 1

In the following, we apply the Schauder–Tychonoff fixed-point theorem (see Burton 2005, p. 185) ), which states that any continuous mapping from a compact convex non-empty subset of a locally convex topological space to itself has a fixed point, to show the existence of the equilibria.

Let \(h_i(m_i, \mathbf c ^*)=\prod _{j\ne i}[1-\int _{m_i}^1\int _0^{c_j^*(\tau )}k_j(\tau , c){\mathrm{d}}c{\mathrm{d}}\tau ]\) with \(\mathbf c ^*=(c_1^*,\ldots ,c_n^*)\). Since \(k_j(\tau , c)\) is integrable over c as it is a density function, there exists a continuous function \(\gamma _j(\tau , c)\) with \(\frac{\partial \gamma _j(\tau , c)}{\partial c}=k_j(\tau , c)\) such that \(\int _0^{c_j^*(\tau )}k_j(\tau , c){\mathrm{d}}c=\gamma _j(\tau , c_j^*(\tau ))-\gamma _j(\tau ,0)\). Thus, \(h_i(m_i, \mathbf c ^*)=\prod _{j\ne i}[1-\int _{m_i}^1[\gamma _j(\tau , c_j^*(\tau ))-\gamma _j(\tau ,0)]{\mathrm{d}}\tau ]\), which is a continuous mapping from \([0, 1]\times [0,1]^n\rightarrow [0,1]\).

Let \(H(m, \mathbf c ^*))=(h_1(m_1, \mathbf c ^*)), h_2(m_2, \mathbf c ^*)),\ldots , h_n(m_n, \mathbf c ^*)))'\), which is a continuous mapping from \([0,1]^n\times [0,1]^n\rightarrow [0,1]^n\). By Lemma 2, H is bounded above by one. Define

$$\begin{aligned} M=\{ {\mathbf{c}}\in \varphi \mid : \Vert {\mathbf{c}}\Vert \le 1\}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\varphi \) is the space of continuous functions \(\phi \) defined on \([0,1]^n\rightarrow [0,1]^n\) with \(\Vert c\Vert =\sup _{0\le v\le 1}c(v)\). Then, by Ascoli Theorem, M is compact. M is clearly convex.

Define an operator \(P: M\rightarrow M\) by

$$\begin{aligned} (P\mathbf c )(v)=\int _0^vH(s, \mathbf c (\cdot )){\mathrm{d}}s. \end{aligned}$$

To see that P is continuous, let \(\phi \in M\) and let \(\epsilon >0\) be given. We show that there exists an \(\eta >0\) such that \(\varphi \in M\) and \(\Vert \phi -\varphi \Vert <\eta \) implies \(\Vert (P\phi )(v)-(P\varphi )(v)\Vert \le \epsilon \). Now

$$\begin{aligned} \big |(P\phi )(v)-(P\varphi )(v)\big |=\big |\int _0^v[H(s, \phi (\cdot ))-H(s, \varphi (\cdot ))]{\mathrm{d}}s\big | \end{aligned}$$

and \(h_i\) is continuous, so for \(\epsilon >0\), there is an \(\eta \) such that \(\big | \phi (\tau )-\varphi (\tau )\big |<\eta \) implies \(\big |h_i(m_i, \phi (\tau ))-h_i(m_i, \varphi (\tau ))\big |<\epsilon \). Thus, for \(\Vert \phi -\varphi \Vert <\eta \), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \big |(P\phi )(v)-(P\varphi )(v)\big |= & {} \big |\int _0^v[H(s, \phi (\cdot ))-H(s, \varphi (\cdot ))]{\mathrm{d}}s\big |\\= & {} \int _0^1\big |H(s, \phi (\cdot ))-H(s, \varphi (\cdot ))\big |ds\le \epsilon . \end{aligned}$$

Then, by Lemma 2, P is a continuous function from M to itself. Thus, by Schauder–Tychonoff fixed-point theorem, there exists a fixed point, i.e., a solution for the functional differential equation system exists. \(\square \)

Proof of Theorem 2

The existence of the symmetric equilibrium can be established by the Schauder–Tychonoff fixed-point theorem. Here, we only need to prove the uniqueness of the symmetric equilibrium. Suppose, by way of contradiction, that we have two different symmetric equilibria x(v) and y(v). Then, we have

$$\begin{aligned} x'(v)= & {} \left[ 1-\int _{v}^1\int _0^{x(\tau )}k(\tau , c){\mathrm{d}}c{\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] ^{n-1}\\ y'(v)= & {} \left[ 1-\int _{v}^1\int _0^{y(\tau )}k(\tau , c){\mathrm{d}}c{\mathrm{d}}\tau \right] ^{n-1}. \end{aligned}$$

Suppose \(x(1)>y(1)\), then by the continuity of x(v) and y(v), we can find a \(v^*\) such that \(x(v^*)=y(v^*)=c(v^*)\) and \(x(v)>y(v)\) for all \(v\in (v^*, 1]\) by noting that \(x(0)=y(0)\).

Case 1: If \(k(v,c)>0\) with positive probability measure on \((v^*,1)\times (c(v^*),1)\), then \(x(\tau )>y(\tau )\) for all \(\tau \in (v^*, 1]\) implies that

$$\begin{aligned} \int _0^{x(\tau )}k(\tau , c){\mathrm{d}}c>\int _0^{y(\tau )}k(\tau , c){\mathrm{d}}c \end{aligned}$$

for \(\tau \in (v^*,1)\). Then, we have \(x'(v^*)<y'(v^*)\) which is a contradiction to \(x(v)>y(v)\) for \(v>v^*\). So we have \(x(1)=y(1)\).

Now suppose there exists an interval \([\alpha ,\beta ]\subset [0,1]\) such that \(x(\alpha )=y(\alpha )\) and \(x(\beta )=y(\beta )\) while for all \(v\in (\alpha ,\beta )\), \(x(v)>y(v)\) and for all \(v\in [\beta ,1]\), \(x(v)=y(v)\), by the same logic above, we have \(x(\beta )=y(\beta )\) and \(x'(v)<y'(v)\) for \(v\in (\alpha ,\beta )\), which is inconsistent with \(x(v)>y(v)\) for all \(v\in (\alpha ,\beta )\). Thus, we can prove that \(x(v)=y(v)\) for all \(v\in [0,1]\) and so the symmetric equilibrium is unique.

Case 2: If \(k(v,c)>0\) with zero probability measure on \((v^*,1)\times (c(v^*),1)\), then we have \(x'(v)=y'(v)\) for all \(v\in (v^*,1]\). By \(x(v^*)=y(v^*)\), we have \(x(v)=y(v)\) for all \(v>v^*\), which is a contradiction to \(x(v)>y(v)\). Thus, there is a unique symmetric equilibrium.

Then, in both cases, we prove that there is a unique symmetric equilibrium. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 1

Based on (P2), define a mapping

$$\begin{aligned} (Pc)(v)=\int _0^v{\mathrm{d}}s-\int _0^v\int _s^1\left( \begin{array}{cc} 0 &{}\quad f_2(\tau )\\ f_1(\tau ) &{}\quad 0 \end{array}\right) \left( \begin{array}{c } G_1(c_1(\tau ))\\ G_2(c_2(\tau )) \end{array}\right) {\mathrm{d}}\tau {\mathrm{d}}s, \end{aligned}$$

where \(c=(c_1, c_2)'\).

Take any \(x(v)=(x_1(v), x_2(v))'\) and \(y(v)=(y_1(v), y_2(v))'\) with x(v), \(y(v)\in \varphi \) where \(\varphi \) is the space of monotonic increasing continuous functions defined on \([0,1]\rightarrow [0,1]\). First note that by mean value theorem, \(\forall i=1, 2\),

$$\begin{aligned} G_i(x_i(\tau ))-G_i(y_i(\tau ))=g_i(\widehat{x}_i(\tau )) (x_i(\tau )-y_i(\tau )), \end{aligned}$$

where \(\widehat{x}_i(\tau )\) is some number between \(x_i(\tau )\) and \(y_i(\tau )\). In the following, for presentation convenience, denote

$$\begin{aligned} h(\widehat{x}_1(\tau ),\widehat{x}_2(\tau ),\tau )=\left( \begin{array}{cc} 0 &{}\quad g_2(\widehat{x}_2(\tau ))f_2(\tau )\\ g_1(\widehat{x}_1(\tau ))f_1(\tau ) &{}\quad 0 \end{array}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Then, we have

$$\begin{aligned} |(Px)(v)- & {} (Py)(v)| = |\int _0^v\int _s^1h(\widehat{x}_1(\tau ),\widehat{x}_2(\tau ),\tau )\left( \begin{array}{c } x_1(\tau )-y_1(\tau )\\ x_2(\tau )-y_2(\tau ) \end{array}\right) {\mathrm{d}}\tau {\mathrm{d}}s|\\\le & {} \int _0^v\int _s^1h(\widehat{x}_1(\tau ),\widehat{x}_2(\tau ),\tau ){\mathrm{d}}\tau {\mathrm{d}}s \sup _{0<v\le 1}|x(v)-y(v)|\\\le & {} \int _0^1\int _s^1h(\widehat{x}_1(\tau ),\widehat{x}_2(\tau ),\tau ){\mathrm{d}}\tau {\mathrm{d}}s \sup _{0<v\le 1}|x(v)-y(v)|\\\le & {} \int _0^1\left( \begin{array}{cc} 0 &{} \sup _{[0,1]} g_2(c)(1-F_2(s))\\ \sup _{[0,1]} g_1(c)(1-F_1(s))&{} 0 \end{array}\right) {\mathrm{d}}s \\&\quad \sup _{0<v\le 1}|x(v)-y(v)|. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, when \(\sup _{[0,1]} g_i(c)\int _0^1(1-F_i(s)){\mathrm{d}}s=\sup _{[0,1]} g_i(c)E(v_i)<1\), or \(\sup _{[0,1]} g_i(c)<\frac{1}{E(v_i)}\) by noting that \(E(v_i)=\int _0^1sf_i(s){\mathrm{d}}s=\int _0^1(1-F_i(s)){\mathrm{d}}s\), the above mapping is a contraction, so there exists a unique equilibrium.

We further show Proposition 1 also holds when the support of \(c_i\) is a subset of [0, 1] and the proof is slightly modified. Suppose that the support of \(G_i(c_i)\) is \([c_l,c_h]\subset [0,1]\) and \(G_i(c_i)\) is differentiable on \((c_l,c_h)\). Then, for any \(c_1(\tau )\) and \(c_2(\tau )\), if \(c_l\le c_i(\tau )\le c_h\) for \(i=1,2\), we can follow the proof above to apply the Mean Value Theorem. Otherwise, if one of them is not in \([c_l,c_h]\), an extra treatment is needed. For instance, if \(c_l\le c_1(\tau )\le c_h\) and \(c_2(\tau )<c_l\), then \(|G_i(c_1(\tau ))-G_i(c_2(\tau ))|=|G_i(c_1(\tau ))-G_i(c_l)|\le \sup _{[c_l,c_h]}g_i(c_i)|(c_1(\tau )-c_l)|<\sup _{[c_l,c_h]}g_i(c_i)|(c_1(\tau )-c_2(\tau ))|\). Similar inequalities hold for other possible cases. Thus, if \(\sup _{[c_l,c_h]} g_i(c_i)<\frac{1}{E(v_i)}\) for \(i=1, 2\), the equilibrium is unique. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 2

We first prove necessity. Suppose, in an asymmetric equilibrium, bidder 2 never participates, then bidder 1 participates if and only if \(v_1\ge c_1\) and thus we have \(c_1^*(v_1)=v_1\). Simplifying R, the expected revenue of bidder 2 with \(v_2=v_h\) when he participates in the auction while bidder 1 participates whenever \(v_1\ge c_1\), we get (6) and thus necessity holds.

Next we prove sufficiency. Suppose (6) holds. Consider the strategies that bidder 2 never participates and bidder 1 participates whenever \(v_1\ge c_1\). Given the strategy of bidder 2, bidder 1’s best response is to participate whenever \(v_1\ge c_1\). Given the strategy of bidder 1, since (6) holds, the expected revenue of bidder 2 with \(v_2=v_h\) is less than \(c_l\); thus, the best response for bidder 2 is never participating for any type. Thus, there exists an asymmetric equilibrium in which one bidder never participates and sufficiency satisfies. \(\square \)

Proof of Corollary 1

Suppose we have an equilibrium in which bidder 1 always participates and bidder 2 never participates. Then, bidder 1 always participates is a best response to bidder 2’s strategy since \(v_l>c_h\). For bidder 2’s strategy to be a best response, we just check that (6) holds with \(c_l<c_h<v_l<v_h\). To see this, note that \(F(c_h)=0\), \(\int _{c_h}^{v_h}(v_h-x)dF(x)=\int _{v_l}^{v_h}(v_h-x){\mathrm{d}}F(x)=v_h-E(v)\) and \(\int _{c_l}^{c_h}xG(x){\mathrm{d}}F(x)=0\), thus

$$\begin{aligned} v_hF(c_h)-\int _{c_l}^{c_h}xG(x){\mathrm{d}}F(x)+\int _{c_h}^{v_h}(v_h-x){\mathrm{d}}F(x)-c_l=v_h-E(v)-c_l<0 \end{aligned}$$

by noting that \(v_h-E(v)<c_l\). \(\square \)

Proof of Corollary 2

Let \(\lambda (c)=v_hF(c)+\int _{c}^{v_h}(v_h-x){\mathrm{d}}F(x)-c\) with \(c\in [0,v_h]\) and notice that (6) can be written as \(\lambda (c_h)-\int _{c_l}^{c_h}xG(x){\mathrm{d}}F(x)+c_h-c_l<0\). Note that when v is distributed on [0, 1], \(v_h=1\), and we have \(\lambda (c)=F(c)+\int _c^1(1-x){\mathrm{d}}F(x)-c\). First we prove for any strictly convex \(F(\cdot )\) with support [0, 1], there exists a unique \(\overline{c}\in (0,1)\) such that \(\lambda (c)<0\) if and only if \(c\in (\overline{c},1)\). To see this, note that from \(\lambda (c)\), we have \(\lambda (0)=\int _0^1(1-x){\mathrm{d}}F(x)>0\), \(\lambda (1)=0\) and \(\lambda '(c)=-1+cf(c)\). When \(F(\cdot )\) is strictly convex on [0, 1], \(\lambda (c)\) is a strictly convex function of c with \(\lambda (1)=0\) since \(\lambda ''(c)=f(c)+cf'(c)>0\). Also note that \(\lambda '(1)=f(1)-1>0\), by the strict convexity of \(\lambda (c)\) with \(\lambda (1)=0\), there exists a unique \(\overline{c}\) such that \(\lambda (c)<0\) if and only if \(c\in (\overline{c},1)\). Thus, we have \(\lambda (c_h)>0\) for \(c_h\in (\overline{c},1)\). Note that \(c_h-c_l-\int _{c_l}^{c_h}xG(x){\mathrm{d}}F(x)=0\) when \(c_h=c_l\). By continuity, when \(c_h-c_l\) is sufficiently small,

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda (c_h)-\int _{c_l}^{c_h}xG(x){\mathrm{d}}F(x)+c_h-c_l\le 0 \end{aligned}$$

for all \(c_h\in (\overline{c},1)\). Thus, (6) holds with \(v_h=1\) and an asymmetric equilibrium in which one bidder never participates exists. The other bidder participates whenever \(v\ge c\). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cao, X., Tan, G., Tian, G. et al. Equilibria in second-price auctions with private participation costs. Econ Theory 65, 231–249 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-016-1028-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-016-1028-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation