Skip to main content
Log in

The value of public information in common-value Tullock contests

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Economic Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Consider a symmetric common-value Tullock contest with incomplete information in which the players’ cost of effort is the product of a random variable and a deterministic real function of effort, d. We show that the Arrow–Pratt curvature of d\(R_{d},\) determines the effect on equilibrium efforts and payoffs of the increased flexibility/reduced commitment that more information introduces into the contest: If \(R_{d}\) is increasing, then effort decreases (increases) with the level of information when the cost of effort (value) is independent of the state of nature. Moreover, if \(R_{d}\) is increasing (decreasing), then the value of public information is nonnegative (nonpositive).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Baye, M., Hoppe, H.: The strategic equivalence of rent-seeking, innovation, and patent-race games. Games Econ. Behav. 44, 217–226 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, D., Riis, C.: Contest success functions: an extension. Econ. Theory 11, 201–204 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denter, P., Morgan, J., Sisak, D.: Where ignorance is bliss, ’tis folly to be wise: transparency in contests. University of St. Gallen, School of Economics and Political Science Discussion Paper No. 1128 (2011)

  • Einy, E., Moreno, D., Shitovitz, B.: The value of public information in a Cournot duopoly. Games Econ. Behav. 44, 272–285 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Einy, E., Haimanko, O., Moreno, D., Sela, A., Shitovitz, B.: Equilibrium existence in Tullock contests with incomplete information. J. Math. Econ. 61, 241–245 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, M.: Bayesian implementation. Econometrica 59, 461–477 (1993)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konrad, K.: Strategy and Dynamics in Contests. Oxford University Press, Oxford (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kovenock, D., Morath, F., Münster, J.: Information sharing in contests. J. Econ. Manage. Strat. 24, 570–596 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morath, F., Münster, J.: Information acquisition in conflicts. Econ. Theory 54, 99–129 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R.B., Warneryd, K.: Population uncertainty in contests. Econ. Theory 27, 469–474 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skaperdas, S., Gan, L.: Risk aversion in contests. Econ. J. 105, 951–962 (1995)

    Google Scholar 

  • Szidarovszky, F., Okuguchi, K.: On the existence and uniqueness of pure Nash equilibrium in rent-seeking games. Games Econ. Behav. 18, 135–140 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G.: Efficient rent-seeking. In: Buchanan, J.M., Tollison, R.D., Tullock, G. (eds.) Toward a Theory of Rent-Seeking Society. Texas AM University Press, College Station (1980)

    Google Scholar 

  • Vohra, R.: Incomplete information, incentive compatibility and the core. J. Econ. Theory 54, 429–447 (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  • Warneryd, K.: Information in conflicts. J. Econ. Theory 110, 121–136 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wasser, C.: Incomplete information in rent-seeking contests. Econ. Theory 53, 239–268 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to Dan Kovenock and referees for helpful comments and suggestions. Einy acknowledges financial support of the Israel Science Foundation, Grant 648/13. Moreno acknowledges financial support from the Ministerio Economía y Competitividad (Spain), Grants ECO2014-55953-P and MDM2014-0431, and from the Comunidad de Madrid, Grant S2015/HUM-3444.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Diego Moreno.

Appendix

Appendix

Lemma 6.1

A symmetric common-value Tullock contest with complete information in which the players’ cost of effort is a twice differentiable strictly increasing and convex function \(c:{\mathbb {R}} _{+}\rightarrow {\mathbb {R}}_{+}\) such that \(c(0)=0\) has a unique pure strategy Nash equilibrium. Moreover, this equilibrium is symmetric and interior.

Proof

In the game associated with a symmetric common-value Tullock contest with complete information the set of pure strategies of every player is \({\mathbb {R}}_{+}\), and the payoff function of each player \(i\in N\) is \(h_{i}:{\mathbb {R}}_{+}^{n}\rightarrow {\mathbb {R}}_{+}\) given for \(x\in {\mathbb {R}}_{+}^{n}\backslash \{0\}\) by

$$\begin{aligned} h_{i}(x)=\frac{x_{i}}{\bar{x}}v-c(x_{i}), \end{aligned}$$

where \(v>0\) is the players’ common value and \(\bar{x}=\sum _{j=1}^{n}x_{j}\), and

$$\begin{aligned} h_{i}(0)=\rho _{i}v-c(0)=\rho _{i}v, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\rho \in \Delta ^{n}\) is predetermined. Thus, \(h_{i}\left( \cdot ,x_{-i}\right) \) is twice differentiable and concave on \({\mathbb {R}}_{++}\), and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial h_{i}(x)}{\partial x_{i}}=\frac{\bar{x}-x_{i}}{\bar{x}^{2}} v-c^{\prime }(x_{i}). \end{aligned}$$

Let \(x^{*}\in {\mathbb {R}}_{+}^{n}\) be a pure strategy Nash equilibrium. Then, for all \(i\in N\), player i’s effort \(x_{i}^{*}\) solves the problem

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{x_{i}\in {\mathbb {R}}_{+}}h_{i}\left( x_{i},x_{-i}^{*}\right) , \end{aligned}$$

i.e., \(\left( \partial h_{i}(x^{*})/\partial x_{i}\right) x_{i}^{*}=0.\) Clearly, \(x^{*}\ne 0;\) since \(n\ge 2,\) then \(\rho _{i}<1\) for some \(i\in N,\) and therefore

$$\begin{aligned} h_{i}(0,0)=\rho _{i}v<v-c(\varepsilon )=h_{i}(\varepsilon ,0) \end{aligned}$$

for \(\varepsilon >0\) sufficiently small. Let \(k\in N\) be such that \(x_{k}^{*}>0.\) Then,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial h_{i}(0,x_{-i}^{*})}{\partial x_{i}}=\frac{v}{\bar{x} ^{*}}-c^{\prime }(0)>\frac{\bar{x}^{*}-x_{k}^{*}}{\left( \bar{x} ^{*}\right) ^{2}}v-c^{\prime }(x_{k}^{*})=0 \end{aligned}$$

for all \(i\in N\backslash \{k\}.\) Thus, \(x_{i}^{*}>0\), and therefore \( \partial h_{i}(x^{*})/\partial x_{i}=0,\) i.e.,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\bar{x}^{*}-x_{i}^{*}}{\left( \bar{x}^{*}\right) ^{2}} v=c^{\prime }(x_{i}^{*}) \end{aligned}$$

for all \(i\in N.\) Hence, \(x_{i}^{*}=t^{*}>0\) for all \(i\in N,\) where \( t^{*}\) is the unique solution (recall that \(c^{\prime \prime }\ge 0)\) to the equation

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\left( n-1\right) }{n^{2}t}v=c^{\prime }(t). \end{aligned}$$
(9)

Obviously, the profile \((t^{*},\ldots ,t^{*}),\) where \(t^{*}\) is the solution to Eq. (9), is a pure strategy equilibrium. Hence, the contest has a unique pure strategy Nash equilibrium, which is symmetric and interior. \(\square \)

Lemma 6.2

Let \(f:{\mathbb {R}}^{2}\rightarrow {\mathbb {R}}\) be twice differentiable and homogeneous of degree one. Then, f is convex (concave) on \({\mathbb {R}}^{2}\) if and only if \(f_{xx}(x,y)\ge 0\) (\(f_{xx}\mathrm{(}x,y\mathrm{)}\le 0\)) for all \((x,y)\in {\mathbb {R}}^{2}.\)

Proof

By Euler’s Theorem,

$$\begin{aligned} f(x,y)=xf_{x}(x,y)+yf_{y}(x,y). \end{aligned}$$

Differentiating with respect to x on both sides on this equation and simplifying yields

$$\begin{aligned} xf_{xx}(x,y)+yf_{yx}(x,y)=0. \end{aligned}$$
(10)

Likewise,

$$\begin{aligned} xf_{xy}(x,y)+yf_{yy}(x,y)=0. \end{aligned}$$
(11)

Hence,

$$\begin{aligned} x^{2}f_{xx}(x,y)=y^{2}f_{yy}(x,y), \end{aligned}$$

and therefore

$$\begin{aligned} f_{xx}(x,y)\lesseqqgtr 0\Leftrightarrow f_{yy}(x,y)\lesseqqgtr 0. \end{aligned}$$

Further, (10) and (11) imply

$$\begin{aligned} f_{xx}(x,y)f_{yy}(x,y)-f_{xy}(x,y)f_{yx}(x,y)=0. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, the eigenvalues of the Hessian matrix of f are nonnegative (nonpositive) when \(f_{xx}\) is a nonnegative (nonpositive) function on \( {\mathbb {R}}^{2}\). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Einy, E., Moreno, D. & Shitovitz, B. The value of public information in common-value Tullock contests. Econ Theory 63, 925–942 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-016-0974-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-016-0974-3

Keywords

JEL Classfication

Navigation