Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Complementarity of willingness to pay and cost heterogeneity under vertical product differentiation: A welfare analysis

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Due to the fact that a consumer’s willingness to pay differs between segments, many unregulated industries are price constrained, although the specific costs of market segments also differ. If the product quality is endogenously chosen, we find that third-degree price discrimination increases welfare if a sufficiently pronounced complementarity between the willingness to pay and variable cost heterogeneity is given. This is due to the fact that the monopolist’s incentive for employing a pronounced price dispersion strategy is directly influenced by the consumers’ willingness to pay for the quality of a product. With endogenous product quality, the paper shows that the standard welfare result of third-degree price discrimination compared to uniform monopoly pricing (e.g. that total welfare and consumer surplus both fall if total output does not rise) can be only reversed given the complementarity is sufficiently pronounced.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Court of Justice of the European Union in its ruling on 1st March 2011 in the case C-236/09.

  2. The set-up by Mussa and Rosen (1978) has been employed to discuss a large variety of economic issues. For instance, Jin (1995) focused on the timing of innovation announcements in a vertically differentiated industry. Chandler and Muthukrishnan (2015) used the model to discuss green consumerism and pollution control with an emphasis towards collective action of consumers.

  3. It is worth pointing out that qualitatively similar results can be obtained when we restrict v 1 ∈ (0, 1) and normalize v 2 = 1. It can be shown that, for this case, the welfare gain changing from uniform pricing towards price discrimination is more pronounced than for the case where v 2 < v 1. Under the constellation α < 1and v 1 < v 2, the price reducing effect in segment one is larger in magnitude compared to the price reducing effect for segment two when v 2 < v 1, which induces that the consumer welfare gain under price discrimination is much larger for the case v 1 < v 2 than the consumer welfare gain for second segment consumer under v 2 < v 1. In other words, for the case v 1 < v 2, welfare increases under third-degree-price discrimination if consumer heterogeneity and cost heterogeneity move in opposite directions, but the move does not to be as pronounced as for the case where v 2 < v 1. In the following, we only consider the ”conservative” scenario in our welfare analysis when we assume that v 2 < v 1. As welfare implications are qualitatively identical for the case v 1 < v 2, we depart from replicating similar arguments.

  4. Of course, one can also solve for a critical α.

  5. Consider the case where α ∈ [0.67; 0.70) and v 2 is sufficiently small.

  6. Consider the case where α ∈ [0.67; 0.70) and v 2 is sufficiently large.

  7. For an extreme example, see #7 of Table 1.

  8. The welfare change is defined as the move from uniform pricing to price discrimination. Hence, a negative value of \(\Delta \mathcal {W}\) indicates that welfare is higher under uniform pricing.

  9. With our definition, social goals have a pure legal sphere. For instance, social goals could comprise equal rights of men and women. Translated to our example, a fair premium scheme in the health insurance market, which discriminates among men and women implies welfare gains compared to a uniform premium scheme, which obviously does not price risks in a fair manner.

References

  • Chandler P, Muthukrishnan S (2015) Green consumerism and pollution control. J Econ Behav Organ 114:27–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Y, Schwartz M (2015) Differential Pricing When Costs Differ: A Welfare Analysis. RAND J Econ 46:442–460

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coyne CJ, Isaacs JP, Schwartz JT (2010) Entrepreneurship and the taste for discrimination. J Evol Econ 20:609–627

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galera F, Zaratiegui JM (2006) Welfare and output in third-degree price discrimination: A note. Int J Ind Organ 24:605–611

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ikeda T, Toshimitsu T (2010) Third-degree price discrimination, quality choice, and welfare. Econ Lett 106:54–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jin JY (1995) Innovation announcement with vertical differentiation. J Econ Behav Organ 28:399–408

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Layson SK (1998) Third-Degree Price Discrimination with interdependent demands. J Ind Econ XLVI:511–524

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mussa M, Rosen R (1978) Monopoly and product quality. J Eco Theory 18:301–317

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nguyen X (2014) Monopolistic third-degree price discrimination under vertical product differentiation. Econ Lett 125:153–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pigou A. C. (1920) The Economics of Welfare. London: Macmillan

  • Schmalensee R (1981) Output and welfare implications of monopolistic third-degree price discrimination. Am Econ Rev 37:242–247

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz M (1990) Third-degree price discrimination and output: generalizing a welfare result. Am Econ Rev 80:1259–1262

    Google Scholar 

  • Valletti TM (2006) Differential pricing, parallel trade, and the incentive to invest. J Int Econ 70:314–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varian H (1985) Price discrimination and social welfare. Am Econ Rev 75:870–875

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author would like to thank two anonymous referees, the Advisory Editor Nathalie Lazaric and the Editor-in-Chief Uwe Cantner for comments and suggestions that helped to improve the paper considerably. All remaining errors are, of course, my own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Torben Klarl.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interests

The author declares that he has no conflict of interest.

Additional information

This project was carried out during the author’s stay as a temporary professor at Ulm University.

Appendices

Appendix 1

Table 2 presents the fixed quality game’s results.

Table 2 Fixed quality game’s results summary

Appendix 2

Proof Proof of Proposition 1

Based on Table 2, we are able to verify the following results:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {y_{1}^{D}}>{y_{1}^{U}}&\Leftrightarrow&\bar{q}<\frac{2 (\alpha -1)}{v_{2}-v_{1}}\:\text{given}\:\ v_{1}>v_{2} \end{array} $$
(12)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {y_{1}^{D}}>{y_{1}^{U}}&\Leftrightarrow& v_{2}\geq v_{1} \end{array} $$
(13)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {y_{2}^{D}}<{y_{2}^{U}}&\Leftrightarrow&\bar{q}<\frac{2 (\alpha -1)}{v_{2}-v_{1}}\:\text{given}\:\ v_{1}>v_{2} \end{array} $$
(14)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {y_{2}^{D}}<{y_{2}^{U}}&\Leftrightarrow& v_{2}\geq v_{1} \end{array} $$
(15)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} y^{D}=y^{U}&& \end{array} $$
(16)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} p_{}^{U}>{p_{1}^{D}}&\Leftrightarrow&\bar{q}<\frac{2 (\alpha -1)}{v_{2}-v_{1}}\:\text{given}\:\ v_{1}>v_{2} \end{array} $$
(17)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} p_{}^{U}>{p_{1}^{D}}&\Leftrightarrow& v_{2}\geq v_{1} \end{array} $$
(18)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {p_{2}^{D}}>p_{}^{U}&\Leftrightarrow&\bar{q}<\frac{2 (\alpha -1)}{v_{2}-v_{1}}\:\text{given}\:\ v_{1}>v_{2} \end{array} $$
(19)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {p_{2}^{D}}>p_{}^{U}&\Leftrightarrow& v_{2}\geq v_{1} \end{array} $$
(20)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \pi^{D}>\pi^{U} \end{array} $$
(21)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} C{S_{1}^{D}}\leq(>)C{S_{1}^{U}}&\Leftrightarrow& \bar{q}\in\left[\frac{2 (\alpha -1)}{v_{2}-v_{1}},\frac{2 \alpha (3 \alpha +1)}{(\alpha +2) v_{1}+\alpha v_{2}}\right]\:\text{given}\:\ v_{1}> v_{2} \end{array} $$
(22)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} C{S_{1}^{D}}\geq(<)C{S_{1}^{U}}&\Leftrightarrow& \bar{q}\leq(>) \frac{2 \alpha (3 \alpha +1)}{(\alpha +2) v_{1}+\alpha v_{2}}\:\text{given}\:\ v_{2}\geq v_{1} \end{array} $$
(23)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} C{S_{2}^{D}}\geq (<)C{S_{2}^{U}}&\Leftrightarrow& \bar{q}\in\left[\frac{2 (\alpha -1)}{v_{2}-v_{1}},\frac{2 (\alpha +3)}{(2 \alpha +1) v_{2}+v_{1}}\right]\:\text{given}\:\ v_{1}> v_{2} \end{array} $$
(24)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} C{S_{2}^{D}}\geq (<)C{S_{2}^{U}}&\Leftrightarrow& \bar{q}\geq(<) \frac{2 (\alpha +3)}{(2 \alpha +1) v_{2}+v_{1}}\:\text{given}\:\ v_{2}\geq v_{1} \end{array} $$
(25)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} CS_{}^{D}\geq CS_{}^{U}&\Leftrightarrow& \bar{q}\in\left[\frac{2 (\alpha -1)}{v_{2}-v_{1}},\infty^{+}\right]\:\text{given}\:\ v_{1}> v_{2} \end{array} $$
(26)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} CS_{}^{D}\geq CS_{}^{U}&\Leftrightarrow& \bar{q}\in\left[\frac{6 (\alpha -1)}{v_{1}-v_{2}},\infty^{+}\right]\:\text{given}\:\ v_{2}> v_{1} \end{array} $$
(27)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} CS_{}^{D}<CS_{}^{U}&& \forall\: \bar{q}\:\text{given}\:\ v_{1}= v_{2} \end{array} $$
(28)

If we now use the set of expressions (12)-(28) together with Eqs. 23and 4, we can derivein a straightforward way the relationships depicted with the expressions (5) and (7). □

Appendix 3

The equilibrium values for the endogenous quality game are recorded in Tables 3 and 4.

Table 3 Endogenous product quality game’s results summary. Note that \(\Delta \equiv \sqrt {\alpha ^{2} \left (\left (4 \alpha ^{2}-3\right ) {v_{1}^{2}}+\left (4-3 \alpha ^{2}\right ) {v_{2}^{2}}+2 \alpha v_{2} v_{1}\right )}\)
Table 4 Endogenous product quality game’s results summary. Note that \({\Gamma }\equiv \sqrt {\alpha \left ((\alpha -3) {v_{1}^{2}}+8 \alpha v_{2} v_{1}+(1-3 \alpha ) \alpha {v_{2}^{2}}\right )}\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Klarl, T. Complementarity of willingness to pay and cost heterogeneity under vertical product differentiation: A welfare analysis. J Evol Econ 28, 591–607 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-017-0496-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-017-0496-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation