Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Inequality and growth: the perverse relation between the productive and the non-productive assets of the economy

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The explosion generated by the global financial crisis in 2008 and its transmission to the real economies have been interpreted as calling for new kinds of regulation of the banking and the financial systems that would have allowed re-establishing a virtuous relation between the real and the financial sectors of the economy. In this paper we maintain a different view, that the financial crisis and the ensuing real crisis have roots in the strong increase in income inequality that has been taking place in the Western world in the last thirty years or so. This has created an all around aggregate demand deficiency crisis that has strongly reduced prospects and opportunities for investments in productive capacities and shifted resources toward other uses, thus feeding a perverse relation between the productive and the non-productive assets of the economy. In this context the way out of the crisis is re-establishing the right distributive conditions, which cannot be obtained by a policy aimed at relieving the weight of private or public debts but calls for a redistribution through taxes on the incomes of non-productive sectors, a fine tuning that should prevent excessive taxations transforming positive into negative effects.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This definition draws on S. Bruno (2011).

  2. This hypothesis, descending from Weber’s notion of the “spirit of capitalism”, has been stressed in the more recent literature as the reason of the fault of both the life-time-cycle and the asset price theory in explaining, respectively, the rich saving behaviors and the asset price evidences, as the equity premium puzzle. See Menchik and David 1983, Bakshi and Chen 1996, Carroll 1998, Francis 2009.

  3. The macroeconomic effects on distribution are considered in a much more similar framework; see Patriarca and Vona 2013. The stability properties of redistribution policies are also analyzed in an intertemporal optimization framework; see Garratt and Goenka 1995.

  4. See also Nardini (1993), Amendola et al. (2004), Gaffard and Saraceno (2008) and (2012), Patriarca and Vona (2013), Attar and Campioni (2007).

  5. As a result, agents behaviours are not modelled in an optimization framework.

  6. The distinction between fixed-price and flex-price markets has been introduced by Hicks who underlines the notion that only speculative markets such as markets for staple commodties and markets for securities are flexprice markets (Hicks 1974, p.78).

  7. Such time to build hypothesis is consistent with the class of models stressing the role of the time profile of production. For an extended survey of such class of model, see Hagemann and Scazzieri (2009), Landesmann and Scazzieri (2009).

  8. We assume that the processes possibly not activated are the older ones.

  9. We assume that the processes in the utilization phase not activated are not truncated but put aside to be possibly used in the future. Truncation would speed up a downward adjustment of productive capacity.

  10. We further make the hypothesis that all processes in the construction phase (xs t(j) with 1 < j < z + 1) keep being carried out until they reach the utilization phase.

  11. Since there is no heterogeneity within workers and within capitalists, we can consider the aggregate budget constraint as in a case of representative agents.

  12. According to Eqs. 1 and 2 and the hypotheses on the parameters, we have:

    \( {B}_E^s=\sum_{i= z+1}^{\infty }{x}_E^s(i){b}_i^s=\sum_{i= z+1}^{\infty }{x}_E^s(i) b{\left(1-\delta \right)}^{i- z-1}={x}_E^s\frac{b}{\delta} \)

    \( {L}_E^s=\sum_{i=1}^{\infty }{x}_E^s(i){l}_i^s=\sum_{i=1}^z{x}_E^s(i) l+\sum_{i= z+1}^{\infty }{x}_E^s(i) l{\left(1-\delta \right)}^{i- z-1}={x}_E^s\left( zl+\frac{l}{\delta}\right) \).

  13. See Bhaduri (2008).

  14. We random select a vector of the relevant parameters in each respective significant interval: α ∈ (0;1); β ∈ (0;1); σ ∈ (0;1); τ∈ (0;1); r∈ (0;0.2); δ ∈ (0;0.3); z = (1,2,3); p/w ∈ (γ; 1.3γ).

  15. The prices of the two goods are set equal at the initial equilibrium. Given the technological parameters that defines γ, p/w in a range (γ; 1.3γ) and thus corresponding to a profit margin spanning up to 30%.

  16. See Amendola and Gaffard (1998, 2003), Amendola and Vona (2012), Patriarca and Vona (2013).

  17. For a deeper assessment of credit markets in an out-of-equilibrium framework, see Attar and Campioni 2007, while for the modelling of the “love for wealth” in general equilibrium frameworks, see Kenc and Dibooglu (2007).

  18. Our objective in the paper is not to discuss how public spending is chosen. Were the public spending non productive, the public policy would be inefficient with regard to the problem dealt with.

  19. In the simulations,we consider the same initial level of prices in the two sectors.

References

  • Acemoglu D. (2011) Thoughts on inequality and the financial crisis. Presentation AEA Meeting Denver

  • Amendola M, Gaffard J-L (1998) Out of equilibrium. Clarendon Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Amendola M, Gaffard J-L (2003) Persistent unemployment and coordination issues: an evolutionary perspective. J Evol Econ 13:1–27

  • Amendola M, Gaffard J-L (2006) The market way to riches. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Amendola M, Gaffard J-L (2014) Time to build and out-of-equilibrium growth process. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 29:19–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amendola M, Vona F (2012) Coordinating the accumulation of physical and human capital in different institutional settings. Econ Innov New Technol 21(7):631–653

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amendola M, Gaffard J-L, Saraceno F (2004) Wage flexibility and unemployment: the keynesian perspective revisited. Scott J Polit Econ 51:654–674

  • Atkinson AB (1997) Bringing income distribution in from the cold. Econ J 107:297–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson AB (2008) The changing distribution of earnings in OECD countries. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson AB, Piketty T, Saez E (2011) Top incomes in the long run of history. J Econ Lit 49(1):3–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attar A, Campioni E (2007) Credit cycles in a neo-Austrian economy. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 18(2):249–269

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakshi GS, Chen Z (1996) The Spirit of capitalism and stock-market prices. Am Econ Rev 86(1):133–157

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhaduri A (2008) On the dynamics of profit-led and wage-led growth. Camb J Econ 32(1):147–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruno S (2011) Asset price inflation, money and production in a moving economy: Some Theoretical Issues. Sapienza University of Rome: mimeo

  • Carroll C (1998) Why Do the Rich Save So Much. NBER Working Paper No 6549

  • Eckstein Z, Nagypál E (2004) The evolution of US earnings inequality: 1961-2002. Fed Reserve Bank Minneapolis 28(2):10–29

    Google Scholar 

  • Francis JL (2009) Wealth and the capitalist Spirit. J Macroecon 31(3):394–408

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaffard J-L, Saraceno F (2008) Tariffs, trade and unemployment in a disequilibrium model: issues and policies. J Evol Econ 18(2):219–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaffard J-L, Saraceno F (2012) International trade and domestic distortions. J Evol Econ 22(2):275–301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garratt R, Goenka A (1995) Income redistributions without catastrophes. J Econ Dyn Control 19(1–2):441–455

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagemann H, Scazzieri R (eds) (2009) Capital, time and transitional dynamics. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks JR (1973) Capital and time. Clarendon Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks JR (1974) The crisis in Keynesian economics. Basil Backwell, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenc T, Dibooglu S (2007) The Spirit of capitalism, asset pricing and growth in a small open economy. J Int Money Financ 26(8):1378–1402

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumhof M, Ranciere R (2011) Inequality, Leverage and Crises. CEPR Discussion Papers 8179

  • Kumhof M, Lebarz C, Ranciere R, Richter A, Throckmorton N (2012) Income Inequality and Current Account Imbalances. IMF Working Papers 12/8

  • Landesmann M, Scazzieri R (eds) (2009) Production and economic dynamics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Levy F, Temin P (2007) Inequality and institutions in 20th century America. NBER Working Paper No. 13106

  • Menchik PL, David M (1983) Income distribution, lifetime savings, and bequests. Am Econ Rev 73(4):672–690

    Google Scholar 

  • Nardini F (1993) Traverse and convergence in the neo-Austrian model: the case of a distributive shock. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 4(1):105–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patriarca F, Vona F (2013) Structural change and income distribution: an inverted-U relationship. J Econ Dyn Control 37(8):1641–1658

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piketty T (2013) Capital in the Twenty-First Century. The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge Mass

    Google Scholar 

  • Piketty T, Saez E (2006) The Evolution of Top Incomes: a historical and international perspective, NBER Working Paper No 11955

  • Piketty T, Zucman G (2014) Capital is back: wealth-income ratios in rich countries 1700-2010. Q J Econ 129:1255–1310

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan RG (2010) Fault lines: how hidden fractures still threaten the world economy. Random House, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Shupp F (2002) Growth and income inequality in South Africa. J Econ Dyn Control 26:1699–1720

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE (2012) The price of inequality. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE (2014) New Theoretical Perspectives on the Distribution of Income and Wealth Among Individuals. Unpublished manuscript

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Fabrizio Patriarca.

Appendix

Appendix

In this section we check whether the benchmark and the complete models described in Eqs. 110 and 1419 are compatible with a steady state equilibrium and prove the results in Eq. 13 and 20.

By definition, at a steady state equilibrium, demand excesses are null, all variables including the indebtedness are constant (no new debt is issued), demand expectations are realized and the value of production is constant and equals the demand in each sector. Considering Eq. 67 and 1618 we have:

$$ {p}_e^1{Y}_e^1={D}_e^1+{G}_e={W}_e-{rC}_e+\tau \left({p}_e^1{Y}_e^1+{p}_e^2{Y}_e^2-{W}_e+{rC}_e\right) $$
(21)
$$ {p}_e^2{Y}_e^2={D}_e^2={F}_e-{W}_e={p}_e^1{Y}_e^1+{p}_e^2{Y}_e^2-{T}_e-{W}_e+{rC}_e $$
(22)

These two conditions are equivalent and since we have defined de = Ce/We, they are satisfied if and only if:

$$ \left(1-\tau \right){p}_e^1{Y}_e^1-\left(1-\tau \right)\left(1-{rd}_e\right){W}_e^1=\tau {p}_e^2{Y}_e^2+\left(1-\tau \right)\left(1-{rd}_e\right){W}_e^2 $$
(23)

where Ws e is the wage fund paid in sector s.

Furthermore, the steady state implies that the number of processes of each age is the same and constant (xs(i) = xs). Considering Eq. 11 the ratio Ws/Bs is:

$$ \frac{W_e^s}{B_s^e}= w\gamma $$
(24)

Using this definition in the equilibrium condition in 23 and rearranging we obtain Eq. 20 and, taking τ = 0 and de = 0, we obtain 13 as a particular case. Note that, since the firms would not produce with negative profits (psBs ≥ Ws), we must have ps/w ≥ γ and thus a sufficient condition for the ratio in the right hand side of the equilibrium condition in Eq. 20 to be positive is that rde ≤ 1, that is, it is verified whenever the interest on their debt paid by the workers are lower than their labor income.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Amendola, M., Gaffard, JL. & Patriarca, F. Inequality and growth: the perverse relation between the productive and the non-productive assets of the economy. J Evol Econ 27, 531–554 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-017-0494-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-017-0494-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation