Skip to main content
Log in

A ”conservative Marxist” at Harvard: the influence of Joseph A. Schumpeter on Paolo Sylos Labini

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper addresses the scholarly influence of Joseph A. Schumpeter on Paolo Sylos Labini and briefly discusses their personal relationship. Although they met at Harvard only one year before Schumpeter died, they had the opportunity to interact frequently and Sylos attended both the graduate courses taught by the Austrian economist during the 1948-49 academic year. They had very different personalities and political attitudes. Nevertheless, Schumpeter’s intellectual influence on Sylos was very significant. Its analysis is structured here along Schumpeter’s three most important contributions to social sciences: an evaluation of past economic theories, a theory of economic development, and a few contributions to a theory of social and institutional change. Even if Sylos had a different conception of economics as a discipline, he caught fire from Schumpeter’s teachings, whose imprint is self-evident in most of his important contributions

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. To avoid confusions, Sylos’ critics to Marx are mostly concerned with his moral conduct and political activism. Therefore, they are not related to the intellectual influence that the German thinker had on Schumpeter.

  2. To stress his interest for Schumpeter’s works (and to emphasize the length of Business Cycles!), Sylos was used to remark ironically that he was one of the only six persons worldwide who red the whole book.

  3. See also the opinion expressed by Vianello (2007) (p.3), who was Sylos’ student.

  4. Schumpeter, in the last year of his life, even recognized that mathematical models in the business cycle research had been relatively sterile and argued that the historical method had been by far more important (Schumpeter 1949b).

  5. The following quotation is particularly revealing: ”In truth we can learn not so much from his [Adam Smith] prescriptions as from the nature of his approach, which is at once theoretical and historical and points to the necessity of studying economies in their global movements”. (Sylos Labini 1984)

  6. In this respect, it is worth mentioning an episode related to the the note handed by Sylos to Schumpeter when he was at Harvard. He questioned whether a reduction of the interest rate had an impact on the capital intensity of the production processes, as neoclassical theory implies. When Sylos had the chance to discuss his controversial opinion with Schumpeter, he objected that, if Sylos was right, an essential part of traditional theory had to be rejected.

  7. On this point, see for example Scherer (1992). Note that innovation and technical progress are used as synonymous.

  8. An article remained unknown until 1993 suggests that Schumpeter himself was conscious that in his works the explanation of novelty (that in the realm of economic life is innovation) remains to a good extent unsolved (Schumpeter 2005).

  9. To be sure, in another part of BS innovation is also defined more broadly as ”doing things differently in the realm of economic life” (Schumpeter 1939, 84).

  10. See Sweezy (1943) for a discussion on this point.

  11. For a critical assessment see Langlois (2003) and the literature cited therein.

  12. See Sylos’ opinion expressed in Roncaglia (1988).

  13. ”I studied at Harvard with Schumpeter [...] and I was strongly influenced — I hope for the good reasons — by him; hence my vision of innovation is not only economic, but also social”. My translation from (Sylos Labini 1985, 18).

  14. Sylos’ disagreement on the usefulness of Schumpeter’s distinction between growth and development is also addressed in the note he handed to Schumpeter while he was at Harvard and that Schumpeter addressed publicly in two classes (Roncaglia 1988).

  15. According to Sylos, diminishing returns in agriculture and mining make growth without innovation impossible. In his chapter for Sylos Festschrift, (Baumol 1993) shows with a formal model that the above conjecture is valid under the assumptions of sufficiently strong decreasing returns to scale and capital depreciation rates.

  16. Among others, two quotes are particularly revealing of Sylos thought. ”Many economists — andSchumpeter is among them — consider innovation as exogenous or autonomous, i.e. they include them among the shocks that influence economic activity from the outside.” My translation from Sylos Labini (1989), p.55. ”Schumpeter[...] concentrated on the inventions originated, exogenously, by individual inventors [...] and by the scientists and research workers operating in firms’ laboratories” (Sylos Labini 1998, 347).

  17. The English translation reported here is from Sylos Labini (1984), p.55.

  18. Sylos Labini (1983a) provides an empirical investigation on the importance of the above sources in Italy and the US.

  19. ”[...] Schumpeter recognized that his own views on the role of the large firms in the economy had a large ideological content [...]” (Mason 1951, 142).

  20. Arguably, Sylos’ position is bolder than Shumpeter’s. He was used to say that textbook perfect competition never existed.

References

  • Baumol WJ (1993) Investment, population growth and stationarity of the Ricardian type. In: Biasco S, Roncaglia A, Salvati M (eds) Market Institutions in Economic Development: Essays in Honor of Paolo Sylos Labini. St. Martin’s Press, New York, pp 1–9

    Google Scholar 

  • Langlois RN (2003) Schumpeter and the obsolescence of the entrepreneur. Adv Austrian Econ 6:287–302

    Google Scholar 

  • Leontief W (1950) Joseph A. Schumpeter (1883-1950). Econometrica 18(2):103–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mason ES (1951) Schumpeter on monopoly and the large firms. Rev Econ Stat 33(2):139–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F (1958) New developments on the oligopoly front. J Polit Econ 66(3):215–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richardson GB (1955) Schumpeter’s History of economic analysis. Oxf Econ Pap 7(2):136–150

    Google Scholar 

  • Roncaglia A (1988) Schumpeter. E’ possibile una teoria dello sviluppo economico? Arezzo, Banca popolare dell’Etruria / Studi e Ricerche

  • Roncaglia A, Sylos Labini P (1995) Il pensiero economico. Temi e protagonisti. Roma-Bari, Laterza

  • Ruttan VW (1959) Usher and Schumpeter on invention, innovation, and technological change. Q J Econ 73(4):596–606

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson PA (1951) Schumpeter as a teacher and economic theorist. The Review of Economics and Statistics 33(2):98–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scherer FM (1992) Schumpeter and plausible capitalism. J Econ Lit:1416–1433

  • Schumpeter JA (1912) The theory of economic development: An Inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycle: 1934

  • Schumpeter JA (1928) The instability of capitalism. Econ J 28:361–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1939) Business cycles: a theoretical, historical and statistical analysis of the capitalist process. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1942) Capitalism, socialism and democracy. Elarper & Brothers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1949a) Science and ideology. Am Econ Rev 39(2):346–359

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1949b) The historical approach to the analysis of business cycles. National Bureau Conference on Business Cycle Research

  • Schumpeter JA (1950) The march into socialism. Am Econ Rev 40(2):446–456

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1954) History of Economic Analysis. E. Boody (ed). New York, Oxford University Press

  • Schumpeter JA (2005) Development. J Econ Lit XLIII:108–120

  • Solo CS (1951) Innovation in the capitalist process: a critique of the Schumpeterian theory. Q J Econ 65(3):417–428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sweezy PM (1943) Professor Schumpeter’s theory of innovation. Rev Econ Stat 25(1):93–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sylos Labini P (1954) Il problema dello sviluppo economico in Marx e Schumpeter. In: Papi G U (ed) Teoria dello sviluppo economico. Milano, Giuffré, pp 17–73

  • Sylos Labini P (1956) Oligopolio e progresso tecnico. Giuffré, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Sylos Labini P (1981) Technological change under contemporary conditions: an economist’s view. Econ Pap 66:1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sylos Labini P (1983a) The problem of economic growth in Marx and Schumpeter. In: Groenewegen P, Halevi J (eds) Altro polo: Italian economics past and present. The F May Foundation for Italian Studies, Sydney, pp 129–166

    Google Scholar 

  • Sylos Labini P (1983b) Factors affecting changes in productivity. J Post Keynesian Econ 6(2):161–79

    Google Scholar 

  • Sylos Labini P (1984) The forces of economic growth and decline. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Sylos Labini P (1985) Le dinamiche del mutamento. Processi innovativi e trasformazione culturale 5:15–29

  • Sylos Labini P (1989) Nuove tecnologie e disoccupazione. Roma-Bari, Laterza

    Google Scholar 

  • Sylos Labini P (1990) ’Capitalismo, socialismo e democrazia’ e le grandi imprese. Moneta e Credito 43(172):447–58

    Google Scholar 

  • Sylos Labini P (1994) Carlo Marx: tempo di un bilancio. Roma-Bari, Laterza

    Google Scholar 

  • Sylos Labini P (1998) Schumpeter and the classical economists. In: Kurz H D, Salvadori N (eds) The Elgar Companion to Classical Economics, vol 2. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp 345–49

  • Sylos Labini P (2002) Working Paper Series 52

  • Vianello F (2007) Paolo Sylos Labini economista classico. Economia & Lavoro:65–77

Download references

Acknowledgments

I wish to thank Alessandro Roncaglia, Stefano Sylos Labini, and Fernando Vianello for very helpful comments and discussions. The usual disclaimers apply

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mauro Sylos Labini.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Labini, M. A ”conservative Marxist” at Harvard: the influence of Joseph A. Schumpeter on Paolo Sylos Labini. J Evol Econ 25, 311–321 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-014-0369-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-014-0369-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation