Skip to main content
Log in

Asymmetric information in external versus internal promotions

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Employers have an incentive to fill managerial positions with the most able candidates, and they face a central choice of promoting from inside or outside the firm. With respect to the observability of the candidates’ quality, individual and job-specific characteristics might exert differential influences on these two channels of promotion. We conduct a close comparison of co-workers within occupation–workplace cells in multinomial logit regressions and thereby assess the drivers of external and internal promotions. The results demonstrate that overtime hours, which are observed only by the current employer, are more important for internal promotions, whereas formal educational degrees are more relevant for promotions across establishments. Moreover, the promotion gap for women and foreigners is large and particularly pronounced for promotions across workplaces. However, the disadvantage of women decreases when they work overtime hours.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There are numerous ways for a manager to obtain information about potential candidates for a promotion to a managerial position. For internal promotions, managers usually have more sources of information. For instance, they learn about actual hours worked from direct observation and/or by means of time recording, if available. For promotions from the outside, managers have to rely on other resources, e.g., CVs, interviews, or information deliberately made public by a person via a professional networking platform.

  2. In our analysis, only the part of actual working hours that represents a discretionary choice of the worker is relevant. In this way, by controlling for establishment heterogeneity, we try to purge our estimation results from the impact of employer-induced changes in actual working hours.

  3. Only covariates capturing heterogeneities of the destination job are measured in period t + 1.

  4. Wooldridge (2010) suggests the use of so-called Mundlak terms, i.e., group-specific averages, to capture correlated unobserved heterogeneity in nonlinear model. This procedure approximates the same identification strategy as fixed-effect estimation or regressing on group-specific dummy variables, which is infeasible in large-scale nonlinear models such as the presented multinomial logit.

  5. We choose being non-promoted at the same workplace as the base outcome because in this case, no change is observed for the individual.

  6. We observe the population of employed individuals liable to social security contributions; thus, we exclude individuals in the black market, the self-employed, and civil servants. However, promotions might be rather limited on the black market, and they are irrelevant for self-employment.

  7. Moreover, since top manager are often employed under a contract for work which does not constitute employment subject to social security, presumably only a non-random subsample of top-managers is included in our administrative data.

  8. Due to our data sampling approach, we observe the entirety of promotions but only a random sample of non-promotions. Consequently, the shares of promotions among all observations are artificially high and do not refer to the true proportions in the population.

  9. Suppose that for a specific characteristic z = 1, we are interested in the relative risk of being promoted (y=j) in comparison with staying in the base category (y= base), where category y = j is overrepresented by the factor \( F_{j} \left( {z,x} \right) \),

    i.e., \( {\text{rrr}}^{z = 1} (y_{i} = j | x_{i} ) = \frac{{\frac{{Pr\left( {y = j |z_{i} = 1,x_{i} } \right)*F_{j} \left( {z,x} \right)}}{{Pr\left( {y = {\text{base}} |z_{i} = 1,x_{i} } \right)}}}}{{\frac{{Pr\left( {y = j |z_{i} = 0,x_{i} } \right)*F_{j} \left( {z,x} \right)}}{{\Pr \left( {y = {\text{base}} |z_{i} = 0,x_{i} } \right)}}}} \). As long as the overrepresentation is not structurally correlated with the covariates, i.e., Fj(z,x) = Fj, the baseline probability of each outcome category is canceled out of the relative risk ratio and does not influence the promotion probabilities of interest.

  10. While most of the theoretical considerations build on a firm-level argumentation, we use an establishment-level distinction in the data. If the hypothesized information is available across establishments but not across firms, the establishment-level distinction might be rather imprecise, leading to an underestimation of the difference between internal and external promotions.

  11. A more comprehensive but after these revisions slightly outdated overview on the administrative employment register and its collection process is provided in Oberschachtsiek et al. (2009).

  12. All our baseline results can be replicated using a reduced 2% random sample of non-promoted workers from within the same workplaces, ensuring that the sampling does not affect the presented results.

  13. For a robustness check, we utilize a 2% random sample of all non-promoted employees of the entire work force, i.e., employees working at any establishment during that time. While this subsample does not allow us to control for establishment heterogeneity, the results remain unchanged from those in panel A of Table 2.

  14. Since we use a cross section, the detailed controls for age also capture cohort effects, which are relevant for promotions (Kwon et al. 2010).

  15. The churning rate is defined as the employment neutral turnover rate at the establishment level.

  16. The number of promoted individuals is calculated by taking the shares of promoted individuals 0.074 (internally promoted) + 0.184 (externally promoted) times the total number of individuals 386,048.

  17. Both of the presented specifications control for observable establishment characteristics, such as establishment size, industry, and churning rate, as well as the number of managers and promotions, at both the initial and destination establishments. Hence, the observables control for differences in hierarchical levels and job turnover in managerial positions.

  18. The likelihood ratio test provides a possibility to compare both models. The test statistic is 7786, which is evaluated at a Chi-squared distribution with 384 degrees of freedom since the full model estimates 384 additional coefficients. Hence, the equivalence of both models is clearly rejected.

  19. See also Appendix A for the difference in actual working hours across and within workplaces.

  20. In Table B1 of Appendix B, we can show that the differential effect on external versus internal promotions is fully robust to the use of secondary schooling degrees instead of tertiary vocational certificates.

  21. An alternative theoretical explanation suggesting the same outcome is provided by a large stream of theoretical contributions addressing promotions as a signal (e.g., DeVaro and Waldman 2012; Cassidy et al. 2016; Bernhardt 1995), where employers have an incentive to promote educated workers before their uneducated but equally or even more capable counterparts.

References

  • Agrawal A, Knoeber CR, Tsoulouhas T (2006) Are outsiders handicapped in CEO successions? J Corp Finance 12(3):619–644

    Google Scholar 

  • Albrecht J, Björklund A, Vroman S (2003) Is there a glass ceiling in Sweden? J Labor Econ 21(1):145–177

    Google Scholar 

  • Altonji JG, Pierret CR (2001) Employer learning and statistical discrimination. Q J Econ 116(1):313–350

    Google Scholar 

  • Anger S (2005). Working time as an investment? The effects of unpaid overtime on wages, promotions, and layoffs. DIW discussion paper No. 535, Berlin

  • Anger S (2008) Overtime work as a signaling device. Scott J Polit Econ 55(2):167–189

    Google Scholar 

  • Arulampalam W, Booth AL, Bryan ML (2007) Is there a glass ceiling over Europe? Exploring the gender pay gap across the wage distribution. Ind Labor Relat Rev 60(2):163–186

    Google Scholar 

  • Bayo-Moriones A, Ortín-Ángel P (2006) Internal promotion versus external recruitment in industrial plants in Spain. Ind Labor Relat Rev 59(3):451–470

    Google Scholar 

  • Bell LA, Freeman RB (2001) The incentive for working hard: explaining hours worked differences in the US and Germany. Labour Econ 8(2):181–202

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson A, Li D, Shue K (2018). Promotions and the Peter principle. NBER working paper no. 24343

  • Bernhardt D (1995) Strategic promotion and compensation. Rev Econ Stud 62(2):315–339

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand M, Schoar A (2003) Managing with style: the effect of managers on firm policies. Q J Econ 118(4):1169–1208

    Google Scholar 

  • Bjerk D (2008) Glass ceilings or sticky floors? Statistical discrimination in a dynamic model of hiring and promotion. Econ J 118(530):961–982

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Bozio A, Laroque G (2011) Labor supply and the extensive margin. Am Econ Rev 101(3):482–486

    Google Scholar 

  • Booth AL, Francesconi M, Frank J (2003) A sticky floors model of promotion, pay and gender. Eur Econ Rev 47(2):295–322

    Google Scholar 

  • Bossler M, Mosthaf A, Schank T (2019) Are female managers more likely to hire more female managers? Evidence from Germany. Ind Labor Relat Rev. https://doi.org/10.1177/0019793919862509

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bratti M, Staffolani S (2007) Effort-based career opportunities and working time. Int J Manpow 28(6):489–512

    Google Scholar 

  • Buis ML (2010) Stata tip 87: interpretation of interactions in non-linear models. Stata J 10(2):305–308

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassidy H, DeVaro J, Kauhanen A (2016) Promotion signaling, gender, and turnover: new theory and evidence. J Econ Behav Organ 126A:140–166

    Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlain G (1984) Panel data. In: Griliches Z, Intriligator MD (eds) Handbook of econometrics 2(22). North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 1247–1318

    Google Scholar 

  • Chan W (1996) External recruitment versus internal promotion. J Labor Econ 14(4):555–570

    Google Scholar 

  • Chan W (2006) External recruitment and intrafirm mobility. Econ Inq 44:169–184

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen K-P (2003) Sabotage in promotion tournaments. J Law Econ Organ 19(1):119–140

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen K-P (2005) External recruitment as an incentive device. J Labour Econ 23(2):259–277

    Google Scholar 

  • DeVaro J, Gürtler O (2015) Strategic shirking in promotion tournaments. J Law Econ Organ 32:620–651

    Google Scholar 

  • DeVaro J, Waldman M (2012) The signaling role of promotions: further theory and empirical evidence. J Labor Econ 30(1):91–147

    Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen TJ (2004) Performance, seniority, and wages: formal salary systems and individual earnings profiles. Labour Econ 11(6):741–763

    Google Scholar 

  • Flabbi L, Ichino A (2001) Productivity, seniority and wages: new evidence from personnel data. Labour Econ 8(3):359–387

    Google Scholar 

  • Francesconi M (2001) Determinants and Consequences of Promotions in Britain. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 63(3):279–310

    Google Scholar 

  • German Statistical Office (2018) Bevölkerung, Erwerbstätige, Erwerbslose, Erwerbspersonen, Nichterwerbspersonen: im Alter von 15 bis unter 65 Jahren, Statistisches Bundesamt (Destatis), Wiesbaden

  • Gibbs M (1995) Incentive compensation in a corporate hierarchy. J Account Econ 19(2–3):247–277

    Google Scholar 

  • Gneezy U, Niederle M, Rustichini A (2003) Performance in competitive environments: gender differences. Q J Econ 118(3):1049–1074

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwald B (1986) Adverse selection in the labour market. Rev Econ Stud 53(3):325–347

    Google Scholar 

  • Kosteas VD (2010) Employment disruptions and supervisors. Ind Relat J Econ Soc 49(1):116–141

    Google Scholar 

  • Kosteas VD (2011) Job satisfaction and promotions. Ind Relat J Econ Soc 50(1):174–194

    Google Scholar 

  • Kunze A (2015) The family gap in career progression. Res Labor Econ 41:115–142

    Google Scholar 

  • Kunze A, Miller AR (2017) Women helping women? Evidence from private sector data on workplace hierarchies. Rev Econ Stat 99(5):769–775

    Google Scholar 

  • Kwon I, Milgrom EM, Hwang S (2010) Cohort effects in promotions and wages evidence from Sweden and the United States. J Hum Resour 45(3):772–808

    Google Scholar 

  • Lazear E, Rosen S (1981) Rank-order tournaments as optimum labor contracts. J Polit Econ 89(5):841–864

    Google Scholar 

  • Lazear E, Shaw K, Stanton C (2015) The value of bosses. J Labor Econ 33(4):823–861

    Google Scholar 

  • Lima F, Pereira P (2003) Careers and wages within large firms: evidence from a matched employer-employee data set. Int J Manpow 24(7):812–835

    Google Scholar 

  • McCue K (1996) Promotions and wage growth. J Labor Econ 14(2):175–209

    Google Scholar 

  • Medoff JL, Abraham KG (1981) Are those paid more really more productive? The case of experience. J Hum Resour 16(2):186–216

    Google Scholar 

  • Mincer J, Polachek S (1974) Family investments in human capital: earnings of women. J Polit Econ 82(2):s76–s108

    Google Scholar 

  • Mosthaf A, Schnabel C, Stephani J (2011) Low-wage careers: are there dead-end firms and dead-end jobs? J Labour Mark Res 43(3):231–249

    Google Scholar 

  • Mundlak Y (1978) On the pooling of time series and cross section data. Econometrica 46(1):69–85

    Google Scholar 

  • Niederle M, Vesterlund L (2007) Do women shy away from competition? Do men compete too much? Q J Econ 122(3):1067–1101

    Google Scholar 

  • Oberschachtsiek D, Scioch P, Seysen C, Heining J (2009) Integrated employment biographies sample IEBS: handbook for the IEBS in the 2008 Version. FDZ Datenreport 03/2009. Institute for Employment Research, Nuremberg, Germany

  • Olivetti C (2006) Changes in women’s hours of market work: the role of returns to experience. Rev Econ Dyn 9(4):557–587

    Google Scholar 

  • Pencavel J (2015) The productivity of working hours. Econ J 125(589):2052–2076

    Google Scholar 

  • Pergamit MR, Veum JR (1999) What is a promotion? Ind Labor Relat Rev 52(4):581–601

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfeifer C (2010) Determinants of promotions in an internal labour market. Schmallenbach Bus Rev 62:342–358

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfeifer C (2011) Handicaps in job assignment: insiders, outsiders and gender. J Labor Res 32(1):1–20

    Google Scholar 

  • Schein VE (1973) The relationship between sex role stereotypes and requisite management characteristics. J Appl Psychol 57(2):95–100

    Google Scholar 

  • Schönberg U, Ludsteck J (2014) Expansions in maternity leave coverage and mothers’ labor market outcomes after childbirth. J Labor Econ 32(3):469–505

    Google Scholar 

  • Waldman M (1984) Job assignments, signalling, and efficiency. Rand J Econ 15(2):255–267

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge JM (2010) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data, 2nd edn. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mario Bossler.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Ethical approval

This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We gratefully acknowledge helpful comments of two anonymous reviewers and the editor. Moreover, we thank Silke Anger, Lutz Bellmann, Christian Pfeifer, and Claus Schnabel as well as participants at the seminars in Nottingham and Nuremberg, the 2015 Colloquium on Personnel Economics, the 2015 Annual Conference of the Scottish Economic Society, and the 2015 Spring Meeting of Young Economists for helpful comments and suggestions. We acknowledge valuable assistance in data provision by the IT Management Department of the Institute for Employment Research. The usual disclaimer applies.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (DOCX 42 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bossler, M., Grunau, P. Asymmetric information in external versus internal promotions. Empir Econ 59, 2977–2998 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-019-01749-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-019-01749-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation