Skip to main content
Log in

Markup and efficiency of Indian banks: an input distance function approach

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines market power and efficiency in Indian banking using a unified theoretical framework based on the primal approach. Empirical results show that due to high level of concentration, large banks hold the capacity to impose higher prices, particularly on advances, and enjoy significant market power. Indian banks, particularly Indian private and foreign banks, are operating below their efficient scale and cost savings can be obtained by increasing their size of operations. The impact of financial deregulation led to a decline in average markup of banks initially, but this trend got reversed in 2002. The increasing trend of market power is mostly determined by bank size. Large banks enjoy greater market power due to either cost advantages or to their capacity to impose higher prices. Lower marginal cost and higher return of the so-called efficient structure have helped the large banks to maintain higher efficiency level. Finally, higher market power was also reflected in higher profit.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14
Fig. 15
Fig. 16
Fig. 17
Fig. 18
Fig. 19

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. What we call the “Schumpeterian” hypothesis is of course a simplification of Schumpeter’s theory. In fact, he did not claim that monopolies are preferable to perfect competition. Instead he suggested a deeper analysis of the dynamic aspect of competition as economic development might benefit from some degree of monopoly power.

  2. Kutlu and Sickles (2012) consider a dynamic competition model in which market power is modeled via the conduct parameter.

  3. The UK’s Independent Commission on Banking was set up in 2010 to consider reforms to promote financial stability and competition. Comments and criticism on the Commission’s interim report released in May 2011 are available at http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/6509.

  4. The All-India Rural Survey Committee (Reserve Bank of India 1954) observed that out of the total borrowings of Rs.7500 million for the cultivators in 1951–1952, agriculturalist money lenders and professional money lenders accounted for 24.9 and 44.8 %, respectively.

  5. Since the departure from the optimality condition can occur not only due to non-competitive behavior but also due to regulatory constraints, it is not guaranteed that markup will be always positive.

  6. We show this explicitly in Appendix 1 under profit maximization behavioral assumption.

  7. If the monopoly pricing rule (\(\hbox {MR} = \hbox {MC} \Rightarrow {P} > \hbox {MC} \Rightarrow {R/C} > E_{cy} \Rightarrow {L}>0\)) is not imposed in estimation, there is no guarantee that the computed values of L from above will be positive for all producers.

  8. This concept is used to measure returns to scale (RTS) which for a single output is \(1/\frac{\partial \ln C}{\partial \ln y}\) and for multiple output case \(RTS=(\mathop \sum \nolimits _m \frac{\partial \ln C}{\partial \ln y_m })^{-1}=(\mathop \sum \nolimits _m Ecy_m)^{-1}=Ec_y ^{-1}\).

  9. It is worth noting that even if one assumes that producers are monopolists and they maximize profit, it is not guaranteed that \(p_m >\hbox {MC}_m \) for all m, especially if there are cross-subsidizations (see Appendix 1). Thus, it is not guaranteed that \(\mathop \sum \nolimits _m E_{cy_m } =E_{cy} <R/C \quad \Rightarrow {L}>0.\) Note that here we are not explicitly assuming monopoly output markets and imposing profit maximizing behavior on the producers. Thus, markups in our case, at least in some output markets might not be positive. It is also possible that L is not positive, at least for some banks.

  10. Financial year for Indian banks runs from April 1 to March 31.

  11. Unlike the consumer price-based inflation measure used in most countries, inflation in India based on wholesale price index is closely monitored and is largely used for policy making.

  12. It worth noting that estimated markup might also reflect regulatory constraints, especially for state-owned banks. If state-owned banks are not allowed to charge a price that equates \(\hbox {MR}=\hbox {MC}\), the markup will be less than optimal. Given that markup for state-owned banks are consistently lower, we cannot rule out the possibility that the markups for at least state-owned banks are not true markups. Furthermore, if the regulated price is set too low, it might show up as negative markup which is not possible theoretically. Note that any loss by the state-owned banks is borne by the government and therefore low or even negative markup cannot be regarded as something odd.

  13. The average markup in investments is estimated to be negative (marginally below zero) over the years. For reasons of parsimony, the same is not reported here.

  14. It is possible to estimate efficiency from \(E[\exp (-u_{it}|e_it)]\) which is bounded between 0 and 1.

  15. This nonparametric test for equality of multivariate densities comprised continuous and categorical data. Here categorical data consist of ownerships: SOBs, private and foreign. This test was performed using the npdeneqtest function of np package in R (Racine 2012). Under the null of equality, the test statistic \({T}_{{n}} \sim \) N(0, 1).

References

  • Allen F, Gale D (2004) Competition and financial stability. J Money Credit Bank 36:453–480

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angelini P, Cetorelli N (2003) The effects of regulatory reform on competition in the banking industry. J Money Credit Bank 35:663–684

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger AN (1995) The profit-structure relationship in banking—tests of market power and efficient-structure hypotheses. J Money Credit Bank 27:404–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger AN, Hannan TH (1998) The efficiency cost of market power in the banking industry: a test of the quiet life and related hypothesis. Rev Econ Stat 80:454–465

  • Berger AN, Klapper LF, Ariss RT (2009) Bank competition and financial stability. J Financ Serv Res 35:99–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya K, Das A (2003) Dynamics of market structure and competitiveness of the banking sector in India and its impact on output and prices of banking services. Reserve Bank India Occas Pap 24:123–159

    Google Scholar 

  • Bikker JA, Groeneveld J (2000) Competition and concentration in the EU banking industry. Kredit Kap 33:62–98

    Google Scholar 

  • Bikker JA, Haaf K (2002) Competition, concentration and their relationship: an empirical analysis of the banking industry. J Bank Finance 26:2191–2214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd JH, De Nicolo G (2005) The theory of bank risk taking and competition revisited. J Finance 60:1329–1343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bresnahan T (1982) The oligopoly solution concept is identified. Econ Lett 10:87–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carbó VS, Humphrey D, Maudos J, Molyneux P (2009) Cross-country comparisons of competition and pricing power in European banking. J Int Money Finance 28:115–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casu B, Girardone C (2008) Does competition lead to efficiency? The case of EU commercial banks. Centre for Banking Research, Cass Business School, City University London Working Paper Series, 01/09

  • Cetorelli N (1999) Competitive analysis in banking: appraisal of the methodologies. Econ Perspect 23:2–15

  • Claessens S, Laeven L (2004) What drives bank competition? Some international evidence. J Money Credit Bank 36:563–583

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coccorese P (1998) Assessing the competitive conditions in the Italian banking system: some empirical evidence. BNL Q Rev 205:171–191

    Google Scholar 

  • Das A, Ghosh S (2006) Financial deregulation and efficiency: an empirical analysis of Indian banks during the post reform period. Rev Financ Econ 15:193–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Das A, Kumbhakar SC (2012) Productivity and efficiency dynamics in Indian banking: an input distance function approach incorporating quality of inputs and outputs. J Appl Econom 27:205–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeBandt O, Davis EP (2000) Competition, contestability and market structure in European banking sectors on the eve of EMU. J Bank Finance 24:1045–1066

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Guevara JF, Maudos J, Pérez F (2005) Market power in European banking sectors. J Financ Serv Res 27:109–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiordelisi F, Marques-Ibanez David, Molyneux P (2010) Efficiency and risk in European banking. European Central Bank, working paper series, No. 1211

  • Fischer K-H, Hempell HS (2006) Regional markets, oligopoly, and market power in banking. Deutsche Bundesbank Research Center Discussion Paper

  • Fujii H, Managi S, Matousek R (2014) Indian bank efficiency and productivity changes with undesirable outputs: a disaggregated approach. J Bank Finance 38:41–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldberg L, Rai A (1996) The structure-performance relationship for European banking. J Bank Finance 21:589–611

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart Charles AE (2011) Not far enough: recommendations of the UK’s Independent Commission on Banking. http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/6509

  • Hempell A (2002) Testing for competition among German banks. Deutsche Bundesbank discussion paper series 2: banking and financial studies (04/2002)

  • Jondrow J, Lovell CAK, Materov IS, Schmidt P (1982) On the estimation of technical inefficiency in the stochastic production function model. J Econom 19:233–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koetter M, Poghosyan T (2009) The identification of technology regimes in banking: implications for the market power-fragility nexus. J Bank Finance 33:1413–1422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar S, Gulati R (2011) Impact of non-traditional activities on the efficiency of Indian banks: a non-parametric approach. Macroecon Finance Emerg Mark Econ 4:125–166

    Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar SC, Sarkar S (2003) Deregulation, ownership and productivity growth in the banking industry: evidence from India. J Money Credit Bank 35:403–414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar SC, Sarkar S (2005) Deregulation, ownership and efficiency change in Indian banking: an application of stochastic frontier analysis. In: Ghosh R, Neogi C (eds) Theory and application of productivity and efficiency, econometric and DEA approach. Macmillan, India

    Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar SC (2012) Specification and estimation of primal production models. Eur J Oper Res 217:509–518

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar SC, Wang H-J (2006) Pitfalls in the estimation of cost function ignoring allocative inefficiency: a Monte Carlo analysis. J Econom 134:317–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L, Sickles RC (2012) Estimation of market power in the presence of firm level inefficiencies. J Econom 168:141–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lau L (1982) On identifying the degree of competitiveness from industry price and output data. Econ Lett 10:93–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li Q, Maasoumi E, Racine JS (2009) A nonparametric test for equality of distributions with mixed categorical and continuous data. J Econom 148:186–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Molyneux P, Lloyd-Williams DM, Thornton J (1994) Competitive conditions in European banking. J Bank Finance 18:445–459

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nathan A, Neave EH (1989) Competition and contestability in Canada’s financial system: empirical results. Can J Econ 22:576–594

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panzar JC, Rosse JN (1987) Testing for monopoly equilibrium. J Ind Econ 35:443–456

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Punt LW, van Rooij MCJ (2001) The profit-structure relationship and mergers in the European banking industry: an empirical assessment. DeNederlandsche Bank Staff Reports No. 58

  • Racine JS (2012) Entropy-based inference using R and the np package: a primer. McMaster University, Hamilton

    Google Scholar 

  • Ray SC, Das A (2010) Distribution of cost and profit efficiency: evidence from Indian banking. Eur J Oper Res 201:297–307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaffer S (1982) Non-structural test for competition in financial markets. In: Bank structure and competition, conference proceedings, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, pp 225–230

  • Shaffer S (1985) Competition, economies of scale, and diversity of firm sizes. Appl Econ 17:467–476

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tzeremes NG (2015) Efficiency dynamics in Indian banking: a conditional directional distance approach. Eur J Oper Res 240:807–818

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tabak B, Tecles P (2010) Estimating a Bayesian stochastic frontier for the Indian banking system. Int J Prod Econ 125:96–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vesala J (1995) Testing for competition in banking: behavioral evidence from Finland. Bank of Finland Studies, working paper

  • Weill L (2004) On the relationship between competition and efficiency in the EU banking sector. Kredit Kap 37:329–352

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Abhiman Das.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Monopoly pricing

In a single output case, under monopoly, \(P>\hbox {MC}\). However, if there are multiple outputs, \(p_m >\hbox {MC}_m \) might not hold for all m, even under monopoly especially if there is cross-subsidization. To see it formally, assume that \(y_1 ({p_1, p_2 }),y_2 ({p_1, p_2 })\) are the demand functions for outputs \(y_1 \hbox { and }y_2\). Define profit as \(\pi =p_1 \times y_1 \left( {p_1, p_2 } \right) +p_2 \times y_2 \left( {p_1, p_2 } \right) -C\left( {w, y_1, y_2 } \right) \), where \(C\left( {w,y_1 ,y_2 } \right) \) is the cost function. The first-order conditions are:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi }{\partial p_1 }= & {} 0\hbox { gives }p_1 \frac{\partial y_1 }{\partial p_1 }+y_1 +\frac{\partial y_2 }{\partial p_1 }\nonumber \\= & {} \frac{\partial C}{\partial y_1 }\frac{\partial y_1 }{\partial p_1 }+\frac{\partial C}{\partial y_2 }\frac{\partial y_2 }{\partial p_1 }=\hbox {MC}_1 \frac{\partial y_1 }{\partial p_1 }+\hbox {MC}_2 \frac{\partial y_2 }{\partial p_1 } \end{aligned}$$
(1)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi }{\partial p_2 }= & {} 0\hbox { gives }p_1 \frac{\partial y_1 }{\partial p_2 }+y_2 +\frac{\partial y_2 }{\partial p_2 }\nonumber \\= & {} \frac{\partial C}{\partial y_1 }\frac{\partial y_1 }{\partial p_2 }+\frac{\partial C}{\partial y_2 }\frac{\partial y_2 }{\partial p_2 }=\hbox {MC}_1 \frac{\partial y_1 }{\partial p_2 }+\hbox {MC}_2 \frac{\partial y_2 }{\partial p_2 } \end{aligned}$$
(2)

From (i) \((P_1 -\hbox {MC}_1) \frac{\partial y_1 }{\partial p_1 }=-y_1 -\left( {p_2 -\hbox {MC}_2 } \right) \frac{\partial y_2 }{\partial p_1 }\)

$$\begin{aligned} \Rightarrow \frac{(P_1 -\hbox {MC}_1)}{p_1 }=\frac{1}{\eta _1 }+\frac{(P_2 -\hbox {MC}_2)}{p_1 }\frac{\partial y_2 }{\partial p_1 }\div \left( {-\frac{\partial y_1 }{\partial p_1}} \right) \end{aligned}$$
(3)

where \(\eta _1 =-\frac{\partial y_1 }{\partial p_1 }\frac{p_1 }{y_1 }>0\) is the price elasticity of demand. If outputs \(y_1\) and \(y_2\) are complements then \(\frac{\partial y_2 }{\partial p_1 }<0.\) Thus, even if markup in \(y_2\) is positive, i.e., \((P_2 -\hbox {MC}_2)>0,\) markup in \(y_1\) can be negative if the complementarity is strong (i.e., \(\frac{\partial y_2 }{\partial p_1 }\) is a large negative number). Similarly, \(P_2 -\hbox {MC}_2 \gtrless 0.\)

Appendix 2

See Table 5.

Table 5 Estimated parameters of input distance functions)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Das, A., Kumbhakar, S.C. Markup and efficiency of Indian banks: an input distance function approach. Empir Econ 51, 1689–1719 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-015-1062-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-015-1062-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation