Skip to main content

Recent Developments in the Adoption of Capital Controls in Emerging Economies: Theory and Practice

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Global Financial Flows in the Pre- and Post-global Crisis Periods

Abstract

After the global financial crisis, policymakers and researchers have begun to discuss capital control policies—an option that attracted little attention in the past—as a real policy alternative for emerging economies looking to regulate capital flows properly. In this chapter, we first introduce the recent trends in theoretical research on capital control policies. Recent developments in theoretical analyses suggest that capital controls have greater potential for emerging economies as a regular policy instrument than previously thought. Next, we outline how emerging economies use these policies to regulate international capital flows. Recently created indicators of capital control provide a better understanding of changes in capital control policies that are difficult to capture with earlier indicators. The analysis using these new indicators suggests that emerging countries deploy capital control policies more intensively than previously assumed. We also find that significant heterogeneity exists even among emerging countries classified in the same subcategory of “wall,” “gate,” or “open” in terms of capital control policies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    For details, see Ostry et al. [53, 54].

  2. 2.

    Nispi Landi and Schiavone [52] show that capital controls are generally effective and controls on portfolio inflows are more effective for emerging economies.

  3. 3.

    For the capital inflow problem, see, for example, Agénor [1] and Agénor and Montiel [3].

  4. 4.

    Data source: IMF, World Economic Outlook (April 2018), GDP based on PPP, share of world (Percent of World).

  5. 5.

    Capital controls are not a new policy instrument, however. Even before the recent financial crisis, they have been discussed both theoretically and empirically. For the earlier literature on capital controls, see Kitano [42].

  6. 6.

    Theoretical analyses of capital controls have mainly been related to the issue of currency crises and the capital inflow problem (e.g., Wyplosz [61], Park and Sachs [55], Auernheimer [6], Bacchetta [7], Dellas and Stockman [18], and Bartolini and Drazen [8], Kitano [40], and Kitano [41]).

  7. 7.

    Harberger [33] also argues that externalities accompany foreign borrowing, and policymakers can internalize them through a corrective tax on foreign borrowing.

  8. 8.

    Chang et al. [13] show that there exists a trade-off between inflation and sterilization costs under capital controls and pegs.

  9. 9.

    In the aftermath of the financial crisis, the role of macroprudential regulation has also been discussed (Unsal [60], Ghilardi and Peiris [31], Engel [23], and Nispi Landi [51]). For details, see Kitano and Takaku [46].

  10. 10.

    Shin [59] argues that “a tax on non-core liabilities has many advantages as a prudential tool in dampening the procyclicality of the financial system, especially for emerging economies” (p. 1).

  11. 11.

    Eichengreen and Hausmann [20] refer to this incompleteness in financial markets as the “original sin.”

  12. 12.

    While Kitano and Takaku [44] investigate the role of capital controls as a credit policy tool, Mimir et al. [50] investigate the role of reserve requirements as a credit policy tool.

  13. 13.

    In this sense, our model is close to those presented by Céspedes et al. [12], Devereux et al. [19], and Elekdag and Tchakarov [22].

  14. 14.

    Quinn et al. [56] review numerous indicators of financial openness in detail.

  15. 15.

    Ahmed et al. [4]’s data are available on their website: https://faculty.darden.virginia.edu/warnockf/research.htm.

  16. 16.

    Chen and Qian [14] also compose a new measure that counts changes during specific time intervals by checking the AREAER data. Their data are specific to China, and are available on their website.

  17. 17.

    By using Ahmed et al. [4]’s index, Ghosh et al. [32] show that emerging economies actually respond to capital inflows, whereas Eichengreen and Rose [21] and Fernández et al. [26] argue that capital controls are acyclical and that emerging economies do not respond to economic and financial cycles.

  18. 18.

    See, for example, Alfaro et al. [5].

  19. 19.

    Although Colombia has an overall inflow restrictions index average above 0.70, it is still classified as a “gate” country. This is because Colombia has two years (i.e., 2011 and 2012) when the index is 0.50, which is below the critical level of 0.60.

References

  1. Agénor, P. R. (2004). The Economics of Adjustment and Growth (2nd ed.). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Agénor, P. R., & Jia, P. (2015). Capital Controls and Welfare with Cross-Border Bank Capital Flows. Centre for Growth and Business Cycle Research Discussion Paper Series 212, Economics, The University of Manchester.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Agénor, P. R., & Montiel, P. J. (2008). Development Macroeconomics: Third Edition. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Ahmed, S., Curcuru, S. E., Warnock, F. E., & Zlate, A. (2016). Decomposing International Portfolio Flows. September, SUERF/PSE/CEPII Conference, Dataset on capital controls (2002Q1–2012Q4, 19 countries). https://faculty.darden.virginia.edu/warnockf/research.htm.

  5. Alfaro, L., Chari, A., & Kanczuk, F. (2017). The real effects of capital controls: Firm-level evidence from a policy experiment. Journal of International Economics, 108, 191–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Auernheimer, L. (1987). On the outcome of inconsistent programs under exchange rate and monetary rules: Allowing the market to compensate for government mistakes. Journal of Monetary Economics, 19(2), 279–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Bacchetta, P. (1990). Temporary capital controls in a balance-of- payments crisis. Journal of International Money and Finance, 9(3), 246–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Bartolini, L., & Drazen, A. (1997). Capital-account liberalization as a signal. The American Economic Review, 87(1), 138–154.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Bernanke, B. S., Gertler, M., & Gilchrist, S. (1999). The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework. In J. B. Taylor, & M. Woodford (Eds.), Handbook of macroeconomics, Vol. 1 of Handbook of Macroeconomics, Chap. 21, pp. 1341–1393. Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Bianchi, J. (2011). Overborrowing and systemic externalities in the business cycle. American Economic Review, 101(7), 3400–3426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Brunnermeier, M. K., & Sannikov, Y. (2015). International credit flows and pecuniary externalities. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 7(1), 297–338.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Céspedes, L. F., Chang, R., & Velasco, A. (2004). Balance sheets and exchange rate policy. American Economic Review, 94(4), 1183–1193.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Chang, C., Liu, Z., & Spiegel, M. M. (2015). Capital controls and optimal chinese monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 74, 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Chen, J., & Qian, X. (2016). Measuring on-going changes in China’s capital controls: A de jure and a hybrid index data set. China Economic Review, 38, 167–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Chinn, M. D., & Ito, H. (2006). What matters for financial development? Capital controls, institutions, and interactions. Journal of Development Economics, 81(1), 163–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Davis, J. S., & Presno, I. (2017). Capital controls and monetary policy autonomy in a small open economy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 85(C), 114–130.

    Google Scholar 

  17. De Paoli, B., & Lipinska, A. (2013) Capital Controls: A Normative Analysis. staff reports, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Dellas, H., & Stockman, A. (1993). Self-fulfilling expectations, speculative attack, and capital controls. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 25(4), 721–730.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Devereux, M. B., Lane, P. R., & Xu, J. (2006) Exchange rates and monetary policy in emerging market economies. The Economic Journal, 116(511), 478–506.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Eichengreen, B., & Hausmann, R. (1999). Exchange rates and financial fragility. Working Paper 7418, National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Eichengreen, B., & Rose, A. (2014). Capital controls in the 21st Century. Journal of International Money and Finance, 48, 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Elekdag, S., & Tchakarov, I. (2007). Balance sheets, exchange rate policy, and welfare. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 31(12), 3986–4015.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Engel, C. (2016). Macroprudential policy under high capital mobility: policy implications from an academic perspective. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 42, 162–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Faia, E., & Monacelli, T. (2008). Optimal monetary policy in a small open economy with home bias. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 40(4), 721–750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Farhi, E., & Werning, I. (2012). Dealing with the trilemma: Optimal capital controls with fixed exchange rates (Working Paper 18199). National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Fernández, A., Rebucci, A., Uribe, M. (2015). Are capital controls countercyclical? Journal of Monetary Economics, 76, 1–14.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Fernández, A., Klein, M. W., Rebucci, A., Schindler, M., & Uribe, M. (2016) Capital control measures: a new dataset. IMF Economic Review, 64(3), 548–574.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Jordi, G., & Monacelli, T (2005) Monetary policy and exchange rate volatility in a small open economy. The Review of Economic Studies, 72(3), 707–734.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Gertler, M., & Karadi, P. (2011). A model of unconventional monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 58(1), 17–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Gertler, M., & Kiyotaki, N. (2010). Chapter 11-financial intermediation and credit policy in business cycle analysis. In Friedman, B. M. & Woodford, M. (Eds.), Handbook of monetary economics (Vol. 3, pp. 547–599). Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Ghilardi, M. F., & Peiris, S. J. (2016). Capital flows, financial intermediation and macroprudential policies. Open Economies Review, 27(4), 721–746.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Ghosh, A. R., Ostry, J. D., Qureshi, M. S., (2017). Managing the tide; how do emerging markets respond to capital flows? (IMF Working Papers 17/69). International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Harberger, A. C. (1986). Welfare consequences of capital inflows. In Choksi, A. M. & Papageorgiou, D. (Eds.), Economic liberalization in developing countries (pp. 157–178). Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  34. IMF (2021) Global financial stability report.

    Google Scholar 

  35. IMF (various years) Annual report on exchange arrangements and exchange restrictions (AREAER). Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  36. Ishi, K. o., Stone, M. R., Yehoue, E. B. (2009). Unconventional Central bank measures for emerging economies. IMF working papers, 1–42.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Jeanne, O., & Korinek, A. (2010). Excessive volatility in capital flows: a pigouvian taxation approach. American Economic Review, 100(2), 403–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Jeanne, O., Subramanian, A., Williamson, J. (2012). Who needs to open the capital account? Peterson Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Jongwanich, J., & Kohpaiboon, A. (2012). Effectiveness of capital controls: evidence from Thailand. Asian Development Review, 29(2), 50–93.

    Google Scholar 

  40. Kitano, S. (2004). Macroeconomic effect of capital controls as a safeguard against the capital inflow problem. Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, 13(3), 233–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Kitano, S. (2007). Capital controls, public debt and currency crises. Journal of Economics, 90(2), 117–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Kitano, S. (2011). Capital controls and welfare. Journal of Macroeconomics, 33(4), 700–710.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Kitano, S., & Takaku, K. (2017). Capital controls and financial frictions in a small open economy. Open Economies Review, 28(4), 761–793.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Kitano, S., & Takaku, K. (2018a). Capital controls as a credit policy tool in a small open economy. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, 18(1), 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  45. Kitano, S., & Takaku, K. (2018b). Capital controls, monetary policy, and balance sheets in a small open economy. Economic Inquiry, 56(2), 859–874.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  46. Kitano, S., & Takaku, K. (2020). Capital controls, macroprudential regulation, and the bank balance sheet channel. Journal of Macroeconomics, 63, 103161.

    Google Scholar 

  47. Klein, M. W. (2012). Capital controls: gates versus walls. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 43(2), 317–367.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Korinek, A., & Sandri, D. (2016). Capital controls or macroprudential regulation? Journal of International Economics, vol 99. Supplement, 1, S27–S42.

    Google Scholar 

  49. Liu, Z., & Spiegel, M. M. (2015). Optimal monetary policy and capital account restrictions in a small open economy. IMF Economic Review, 63(2), 298–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. Mimir, Y., Sunel, E., & Taskin, T. (2013). Required reserves as a credit policy tool. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, 13(1), 823–880.

    Google Scholar 

  51. Nispi Landi, V. (2017). Capital controls, macroprudential measures and monetary policy interactions in an emerging economy. Temi di discussione (Economic working papers) 1154, Bank of Italy, Economic Research and International Relations Area

    Google Scholar 

  52. Nispi Landi, V., Schiavone, A. (2021). The effectiveness of capital controls. Open Economies Review, 32(1), 183–211.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Ostry, J. D., Qureshi, M. S., Habermeier, K., Bernhard, D., Reinhardt, S., Chamon, M., & Ghosh, A. (2010). Capital inflows: the role of controls. IMF Staff Position Notes 2010/04, International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Ostry, J., Ghosh, A., Korinek, A. (2012). Multilateral aspects of managing the capital account. IMF Staff Discussion Notes 12/10, International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  55. Park, D., Sachs, J. (1987). Capital controls and the timing of exchange regime collapse (Working Paper 2250). National Bureau of Economic Research

    Google Scholar 

  56. Quinn, D., Schindler, M., Maria Toyoda, A. (2011). Assessing measures of financial openness and integration. IMF Economic Review, 59(3), 488–522.

    Google Scholar 

  57. Schindler, M. (2009). Measuring financial integration: a new data set. IMF Staff Papers, 56(1), 222–238.

    Google Scholar 

  58. Schmitt-Grohé, S., Uribe, M. (2016). Downward nominal wage rigidity, currency pegs, and involuntary unemployment. Journal of Political Economy, 124(5), 1466–1514.

    Google Scholar 

  59. Shin, H. S. (2010). Non-core liabilities tax as a tool for prudential regulation. Policy Memo. http://online.wsj.com/public/resources/documents/NonCoreLiabilitiesTax.pdf

  60. Unsal, D. F. (2013). Capital flows and financial stability: monetary policy and macroprudential responses. International Journal of Central Banking, 9(1), 233–285.

    Google Scholar 

  61. Wyplosz, C. (1986). Capital controls and balance of payments crises. Journal of International Money and Finance, 5(2), 167–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This work was supported by KAKENHI (20K01744, 20H05633).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shigeto Kitano .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

Ahmed et al. [ 4 ]’s capital control measures for the remaining countries

In Figs. 9.11, 9.13 and 9.15 in the main text, we show Ahmed et al. [4]’s capital control indicators for India, Brazil, and Thailand. In this appendix, we present those for the other 16 sample countries (Malaysia, the Philippines, Poland, Argentina, Taiwan, Indonesia, Korea, Turkey, Colombia, Romania, Chile, Czech Republic, Hungary, Mexico, South Africa, and Israel).

Fig. 9.19
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in Malaysia. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from minus 20 to 4. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F.

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

Malaysia. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Fig. 9.20
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in the Philippines. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from minus 5 to 2. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F. Line remain stable for equity.

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

Philippines. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Fig. 9.21
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in Poland. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from minus 6 to 1. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F.

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

Poland. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Fig. 9.22
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in Argentina. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from minus 12 to 12. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F.

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

Argentina. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Fig. 9.23
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in Taiwan. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from minus 3 to 4. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F.

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

Taiwan. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Fig. 9.24
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in Indonesia. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from minus 2 to 7. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F. Line remains stable for equity.

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

Indonesia. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Fig. 9.25
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in Korea. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from minus 4 to 10. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F. Line remains stable for equity.

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

Korea. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Fig. 9.26
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in Turkey. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from minus 4 to 6. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F. Lines remain stable for equity and bond.

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

Turkey. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Fig. 9.27
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in Columbia. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from minus 9 to 9. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F.

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

Colombia. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Fig. 9.28
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in Romania. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from minus 2 to 6. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F. Line remains stable for equity and bond.

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

Romania. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Fig. 9.29
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in Chile. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from minus 1 to 1. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F. The lines remain stable for all four graphs.

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

Chile. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Fig. 9.30
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in the Czech Republic. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from minus 2 to 1. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F. The lines remain stable for equity, bond, and bank.

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

Czech Republic. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Fig. 9.31
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in Hungary. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from minus 2 to 1. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F. The lines remain stable for equity and bond

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

Hungary. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Fig. 9.32
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in Mexico. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from minus 4 to 2. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F. The lines remain stable for equity and bond.

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

Mexico. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Fig. 9.33
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in South Africa. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from minus 3 to 1. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F. Line remain stable for equity and bond.

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

South Africa. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Fig. 9.34
Four graphs depict the evolution of capital control measures in Israel. The graphs are named Total, Equity, Bond, and Bank. The horizontal axis ranges from 02 to 12 whereas the vertical axis ranges from 0 to 4. The two curves of the graph denote CUM and D I F.

Data Source Ahmed et al. [4]

Israel. Note “CUM” denotes the cumulative number of capital control measures on inflows in each category. “DIF” denotes the first difference of the cumulative series, which indicates the number of new measures introduced in each quarter.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Kitano, S., Takaku, K. (2022). Recent Developments in the Adoption of Capital Controls in Emerging Economies: Theory and Practice. In: Matsubayashi, Y., Kitano, S. (eds) Global Financial Flows in the Pre- and Post-global Crisis Periods. Kobe University Monograph Series in Social Science Research. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-19-3613-5_9

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-19-3613-5_9

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-19-3612-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-19-3613-5

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics