Skip to main content

Distance Functions in Production Economics

  • Reference work entry
  • First Online:
Handbook of Production Economics
  • 1394 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter treats distance functions used in production economics and operations research. The economic intuition behind the different notions of distance functions is discussed to set the stage for a more formal analysis. A minimal set of regularity conditions needed to ensure the existence of well-behaved distance functions are presented, distance functions are defined, and the uses of distance functions in a variety of settings are surveyed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 339.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 899.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Distinguishing between inputs and outputs is unnecessary and often arbitrary because what are perceived as outputs in one context can be inputs in another. For example, milk produced from cows can be converted by the producer into cream, cheese, and other milk products. A more general representation, which is especially common in general-equilibrium models, is obtained by using the concept of a netput which allows commodities to play either role. When a commodity acts as an input in a particular process, it enters with a negative sign, and when it acts as an output, it enters with positive sign. In that case, the technology is written

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \mathcal{T}=\left\{ z\in \mathbb{R} ^{N+M}:z\text{ is technically feasible}\right\} . \end{aligned}$$

    Although this level of generality is possible, throughout our presentation we maintain the artificial distinction between inputs and outputs because of its familiarity and its continuing prevalence in applied production analysis.

  2. 2.

    Subject to suitable regularity conditions that we will discuss below.

  3. 3.

    One can also write this problem as determining the maximal expansion of y possible given x. Mathematically,

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{array}{rcl} \hat{o}\left( y,x\right) & =&\displaystyle \max \left\{ \hat{\beta}:\left( x,y+\hat{\beta} \right) \in T\right\} \\ & =&\displaystyle \max \left\{ y+\hat{\beta}:\left( x,y+\hat{\beta}\right) \in T\right\} \\ & =&\displaystyle f\left( x\right) -y \\ & =&\displaystyle -o\left( y,x\right) , \end{array} \end{aligned} $$

    so that apart from the sign difference, identical results will be obtained. A similar argument shows that \(i\left ( x,y\right ) \) can also be recast as a minimization problem without changing its true nature.

  4. 4.

    Notationally, \(A\rightrightarrows B\) denotes a point-to-set mapping from a point in set A to a set in B. Some writers use A → 2B, where 2B is the power set of B to denote the same correspondence. It is to be distinguished from A → B that denotes a point-to-point mapping.

  5. 5.

    If one operated in terms of netputs,

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \mathcal{T}=\left\{ z\in \mathbb{R} ^{N+M}:z\text{ is technically feasible}\right\} , \end{aligned}$$

    and a numeraire \(\gamma \in \mathbb {R} _{+}^{N+M}\backslash \left \{ 0\right \} \), the parallel notion of goodness in the netput numeraire (GNN) would require that

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} z\in \mathcal{T}\Rightarrow z-\varepsilon \gamma \in \mathcal{T} \end{aligned}$$

    for all ε > 0.

  6. 6.

    One, but not the only, for example, one can always define what’s known as an indicator function for T as follows

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \delta \left( x,y\right) =\left\{ \begin{array}{cc} 0 & \left( x,y\right) \in T \\ \infty & \infty \text{ otherwise} \end{array} \right. . \end{aligned}$$

    Indicator functions are an essential part of modern variational analysis and convex analysis. However, in practical settings, they can prove quite difficult to use.

  7. 7.

    Slices, in fact, have a precise mathematical definition with which we need not concern ourselves here. The intuitive idea is straightforward. Imagine T in say three-dimensional space with one dimension representing output and the other two representing inputs. Now mark off a particular level of y and imagine taking a knife and slicing through T at this point parallel to the input axes. That’s the slice that you project onto the input axes to get the isoquant. If you can represent T via a production function, the equivalent operation is to obtain its upper contour set for a particular y.

  8. 8.

    The visual intuition for the input-oriented distance function is similar with \(V\left ( y\right ) \) replacing \(Y\left ( x\right ) \) and x replacing y.

  9. 9.

    In formal terms, this is equivalent to \(I^{\iota }\left ( x,y\right ) \) being Gateaûx differentiable in the direction of x for all \(\left (x,y\right )\).

  10. 10.

    g Y is also often called a gauge function or a Minkowski functional for the set Y .

  11. 11.

    Using the netput representation,

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \mathcal{T}=\left\{ z\in \mathbb{R} ^{N+M}:z\text{ is technically feasible}\right\} , \end{aligned}$$

    one can also define a netput-distance function as

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} N^{\gamma }\left( z\right) =\min \left\{ \psi \in \mathbb{R} :z-\psi \gamma \in \mathcal{T}\right\} \end{aligned}$$

    if there exists \(\psi \in \mathbb {R} \) such that \(z-\psi \gamma \in \mathcal {T}\) and otherwise that satisfies appropriate versions of Indication, Translation, and Normalization under GNN in the direction γ.

  12. 12.

    Good reasons exist to believe that this is not always true. In other words, FDO might be too strong a restriction (hence our insistence upon the presence of GON). Perhaps the best example is given by pollutants that have complementary relationships with many outputs. The Chapter 12, “Bad Outputs” discusses such concerns in detail.

  13. 13.

    This is another way of saying that location, first-order, and second-order conditions can be met without truly identifying the true optimum. Note that at C second-order conditions for an interior optimum are satisfied, but C remains non-optimal.

  14. 14.

    Here and elsewhere p for \(p\in \mathbb {R} ^{M}\) denotes the transpose of an M-dimensional column vector, and p y for p, y denotes the standard inner product.

  15. 15.

    The “sub” terminology arises from \(\left ( y,O^{\omega }\left ( y,x\right ) \right ) \) falling in the half-space lying above the affine hyperplane

    $$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \left\{ \left( y,O\right) \in \mathbb{R} ^{M+1}:O=O^{\omega }\left( y^{E},x\right) +p^{\prime }\left( y-y^{E}\right) \text{ for all }y\in \mathbb{R} ^{M}.\right\} \end{aligned}$$
  16. 16.

    In the sense of minimization

  17. 17.

    More formally, the modified set is the convex hull of \(Y\left ( x\right ) \).

  18. 18.

    Subdifferentiability of − I i in x is equivalent to superdifferentiability of I i in x.

  19. 19.

    We attribute this Professor Shawna Grosskopf, and even if it is bit imprecise because primal also contains items such as coal, it nicely conveys the general idea.

  20. 20.

    Please see Chapter 3 of Volume 1 of this Handbook for a thorough discussion of duality theory.

  21. 21.

    Recall the superdifferential of c is the subdifferential of − c.

  22. 22.

    Konüs [15] is a translation of a paper originally published by Konü s in Russian in 1924.

  23. 23.

    Other ways exist. For example, one could simply choose an arbitrary y that is neither y o nor y 1 as the reference. That resolves the dilemma of choosing either o or 1 as the basis, but it does not resolve its arbitrariness.

  24. 24.

    The “indicator” terminology appears due to Diewert (1993).

  25. 25.

    See, for example, the chapter in this volume by Färe Primont, and Weber.

  26. 26.

    Chambers [5] appears to be the first to have considered a version of this form, which he referred to as logarithmic-transcendental.

References

  1. Allais M (1943) Traité d’Économie pure, vol 3. Imprimerie Nationale, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  2. Blackorby C, Donaldson D (1980) A theoretical treatment of indices of absolute inequality. Int Econ Rev 21(1):107–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Caves DW, Christensen LR, Diewert WE (1982) Multilateral comparisons of output, input, and productivity using superlative indexes. Econ J 92:73–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Chambers RG (1996) Computable profit as a superlative technical change, input, output, and productivity measure. Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, The University of Maryland, College Park, pp 96–01

    Google Scholar 

  5. Chambers RG (1998) Input and output indicators. In: Färe R, Grosskopf S, Russell RR (eds) Essays in honor of Sten Malmquist. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  6. Chambers RG (2002) Exact nonradial input, output, and productivity measurement. Econ Theory 20:751–767

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Chambers RG (2020, forthcoming) Competitive agents in certain and uncertain. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  8. Chambers RG, Chung Y, Färe R (1996) Benefit and distance functions. J Econ Theory 70: 407–419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Chambers RG, Chung Y, Färe R (1998) Profit, directional distance functions, and nerlovian efficiency. J Optim Theory Appl 98:351–364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Debreu G (1951) The coefficient of resource utilization. Econometrica 19(3):273–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Debreu G (1959) The theory of value. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  12. Färe R, Lovell CAK (1978) The structure of technical efficiency. J Econ Theory 19:150–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Färe R, Lundberg A (2006) mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  14. Farrell MJ (1957) The measurement of productive efficiency. J R Stat Soc 129A:253–281

    Google Scholar 

  15. Konüs AA (1939) The problem of the true index of the cost of living. Econometrica 7:10–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Luenberger DG (1992a) Benefit functions and duality. J Math Econ 21:461–481

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Luenberger DG (1992b) New optimality principles for economic efficiency and equilibrium. J Optim Theory Appl 75(2):221–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Malmquist S (1953) Index numbers and indifference surfaces. Trabajos De Estadistica 4: 209–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. McFadden D (1978) Cost, revenue, and profit functions. In: McFadden D, Fuss M (eds) Production economics: a dual approach to theory and applications. North Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  20. Rockafellar RT (1970) Convex analysis. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  21. Shephard RW (1953) Cost and production functions. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  22. Shephard RW (1970) Theory of cost and production functions. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert G. Chambers .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this entry

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this entry

Chambers, R.G., Färe, R. (2022). Distance Functions in Production Economics. In: Ray, S.C., Chambers, R.G., Kumbhakar, S.C. (eds) Handbook of Production Economics. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-3455-8_14

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics