Skip to main content

Data Envelopment Analysis: A Nonparametric Method of Production Analysis

  • Living reference work entry
  • First Online:
Handbook of Production Economics

Abstract

In the Operations Research/Management Science literature, the nonparametric method of Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) has gained wide popularity as a valid analytical format for efficiency evaluation. In economics, however, its reception has been far less enthusiastic. Yet, the intellectual roots of DEA go back to the seminal contributions to nonparametric analysis of production by Debreu, Shephard, Farrell, Afriat, and others. Over the past four decades, DEA has matured into a full blown non-parametric methodology for measuring productive efficiency that serves as an alternative to parametric Stochastic Frontier Analysis (SFA). Both grounded into the neoclassical theory of production, DEA and SFA provide the researcher alternative ways to calibrate testable relations between inputs, outputs, costs, revenue, and profit.

Staring from the central concept of the Production Possibility set, this chapter provides a broad overview of the literature on DEA methodology for radial and non-radial measurement of technical efficiency from input and output quantity data under alternative returns to scale assumptions. This is followed by models for performance evaluation in the presence of market prices through cost, revenue, and overall profit efficiency- both in the long run when all inputs are variable and in the short run, when some inputs are fixed. DEA models for physical measures of the capacity output in the short run and economic measures of capacity in the long run are discussed. Alternative ways to incorporate the production of ‘bad’ or undesirable outputs collaterally with the ‘good’ or intended output in DEA models for efficiency measurement are presented. Finally, the role of contextual or environmental variables that affect efficiency is also discussed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    By contrast, the earlier models in DEA and activity analysis assumed CRS (e.g., CCR [20]) and generalization to the VRS technology was a subsequent development [10].

  2. 2.

    In this chapter, vectors are denoted by superscripts and scalars by subscripts.

  3. 3.

    The more popular alternative is Stochastic frontier analysis (SFA) introduced by Aigner, Lovell, and Schmidt [2] where one uses the maximum likelihood procedure to estimate a parametrically specified frontier production function incorporating a one-sided error term representing inefficiency and another two-sided error term representing random noise. See Kumbhakar and Lovell [47] for a detailed discussion of Stochastic frontier analysis (SFA).

  4. 4.

    If the transformation function is differentiable, weak disposability of inputs and outputs will imply \( \frac{\partial F}{\partial {x}_i}\le 0 \) for each input i and \( \frac{\partial F}{\partial {y}_r}\ge 0 \) for each output r. In a later section in this chapter and in much greater details in the chapter on “Bad Outputs” by Murty and Russell in this volume of the Handbook, free or strong disposability is contrasted with weak disposability where an output cannot be decreased (or an input increased) unilaterally but simultaneous reduction in multiple outputs or increase in multiple inputs may be feasible.

  5. 5.

    In the DEA literature, this is often described as minimum extrapolation. It should be noted that this is a criterion for estimation rather than a property of the technology.

  6. 6.

    When (x0,?y0) is not one of the observed bundles, non-negativity of the ?s and the outputs will ensure that f will never be negative even if it is lower than 1. However, if any individual input in the bundle x0 is smaller than the smallest value of the corresponding input across all observations in the data set \( \mathbf{\mathcal{D}} \), (23) will not have a feasible solution.

  7. 7.

    The true maximum may actually be considerably higher than f*y0. But we cannot infer that on the basis of the observed input-output bundles without making additional assumptions about the technology. However, it cannot be any smaller than f*y0 if the assumptions (A1)–(A4) hold.

  8. 8.

    The case of k = 0 corresponds to inaction when no input is used and no output is produced.

  9. 9.

    Note the absence of the restriction that the ?s add up to unity. Under convexity only, \( \left(\overline{x}=\sum \limits_{j=1}^N{\lambda}_j{x}^j,\overline{y}=\sum \limits_{j=1}^N{\lambda}_j{y}^j\right) \) is feasible so long as \( \sum \limits_{j=1}^N{\lambda}_j=1 \) and no ?j is negative. With the added assumption of CRS, \( \left(k\overline{x},k\overline{y}\right) \) is also feasible for any k = 0. CRS implies that for \( {\mu}_j=k{\lambda}_j,k\ge 0,\left(\sum \limits_{j=1}^N{\mu}_j{x}^j,\sum \limits_{j=1}^N{\mu}_j{y}^j\right) \) is feasible. But \( \sum \limits_{j=1}^N{\mu}_j=k \) need not be equal to 1.

  10. 10.

    These shadow prices or multipliers are uniquely designed for the unit under evaluation.

  11. 11.

    If (x0,?y0) ? T but ?G, then there will exist either some ß < 1 such that (ßx0,?y0) ? T or some a > 1 such that (x0,?ay0) ? T. In the former case, one gets \( \frac{\alpha }{\beta }>1 \) for a = 1. In the latter case, \( \frac{\alpha }{\beta }>1 \) for ß = 1.

  12. 12.

    The more interested reader may see Ray [58] for detailed treatment of all these three approaches.

  13. 13.

    See also the earlier paper by Seiford and Zhu [72].

  14. 14.

    See Färe, Grosskopf, Lovell, and Pasurka [34].

  15. 15.

    Rumor has it that when Färe raised this point at a conference in Austin TX, Charnes was so irritated that he excluded the former from his guest list to a barbecue!

  16. 16.

    Portela and Thanassoulis [55] use the measure \( \frac{{\left(\Pi {\theta}_i\right)}^{\frac{1}{n}}}{{\left(\Pi {\varphi}^r\right)}^{\frac{1}{m}}} \) and called it the geometric distance function.

  17. 17.

    See also the range-adjusted measure (RAM) introduced by Cooper, Park, and Pastor [24].

  18. 18.

    An exception is when there is any slack in the technically efficient input bundle.

  19. 19.

    See the discussion in Ray and Mukherjee [65].

  20. 20.

    See, for an example, Tone [76].

  21. 21.

    This problem assumes homogeneous technology across all locations. RCM also consider the case where the technology varies across locations see Ray [61].

  22. 22.

    Also see Afriat [1] and Hanoch and Rothschild [43]. Banker and Maindiratta [6] further extended Varian [77] to construct upper and lower bounds on technical, allocative efficiency, and overall profit efficiencies.

  23. 23.

    See, for example, Färe, Grosskopf, Lovell, and Pasurka [34]; Färe, Grosskopf, Lovell, and Yaisawarng [35]; and Färe, Grosskopf, Noh, and Weber [37] among many others.

  24. 24.

    See their chapter (24) by Squires and Segerson on “Bad Outputs” in this volume of the Handbook.

  25. 25.

    MRL [52] also consider another model including pollution abatement as a separate desired output produced by diverting resources from the production of the desired output g. An example would be treatment of polluted waste water before discharging into the stream.

  26. 26.

    The joint disposability of the bad output and the polluting input is comparable to the two materials balance postulates MB1 and MB2 in Dakpo et al. ([28], p. 352).

  27. 27.

    Ayres and Kneese [4] introduced the question of materials balance in economics. In a number of subsequent papers, it has been extensively discussed in the context of production efficiency by a number of authors including Pethig [54]; Coelli, Lauwers, and Van Huylenbroeck [22]; Chambers and Melkonyan [15]; Hampf [42]; Rodseth [69, 70]; and Forsund (2016) among others. See, in particular, Dapko, Jenneauxe, and Latruffe [28].

  28. 28.

    Chapters 20 by Ray and 21 by Kumbhakar in this volume of the Handbook cover non-parametric DEA and parametric SFA approaches to measuring productivity growth and technical change.

  29. 29.

    For a detailed discussion of non-convexity in general, refer to the chapter 18 by Briec, Kerstens, and Van de SWoestyne in this volume of the Handbook.

  30. 30.

    For detailed discussion of DEA from an OR/MS perspective, the reader should refer to Zhu [78] and Cooper, Seiford, and Tone (25). Fare, Grosskopf, and Lovell [36] and Ray [58] explain the economic theory behind DEA.

References

  1. Afriat S (1972) Efficiency estimation of production functions. Int Econ Rev 13(3):568–598

    Google Scholar 

  2. Aigner DJ, Lovell CAK, Schmidt P (1977) Formulation and estimation of stochastic frontier production function models. J Econ 6(1):21–37

    Google Scholar 

  3. Aparicio J, Pastor JT, Ray SC (2013) An overall measure of technical inefficiency at the firm and at the industry level: the ‘lost profit on outlay’. Eur J Oper Res 226(1):154–162

    Google Scholar 

  4. Ayres RU, Kneese AV (1969) Production, consumption, and externalities. Am Econ Rev 59:282–297

    Google Scholar 

  5. Banker RD (1984) Estimating the most productive scale size using data envelopment analysis. Eur J Oper Res 17(1):35–44

    Google Scholar 

  6. Banker RD, Maindiratta A (1988) Nonparametric analysis of technical and allocative efficiencies in production. Econometrica 56(5):1315–1332

    Google Scholar 

  7. Banker RD, Morey RC (1986) Efficiency analysis for exogenously fixed inputs and outputs. Oper Res 34(4):513–521

    Google Scholar 

  8. Banker RD, Thrall RM (1992) Estimating most productive scale size using data envelopment analysis. Eur J Oper Res 62:74–84

    Google Scholar 

  9. Banker RD, Charnes A, Cooper WW (1984) Some models for estimating technical and scale inefficiencies in data envelopment analysis. Manage Sci 30(9):1078–1092

    Google Scholar 

  10. Banker RD, Chang H, Natarajan R (2007) Estimating DEA technical and allocative inefficiency using aggregate cost or revenue data. J Prod Anal 27:115–121

    Google Scholar 

  11. Baumol WJ, Panzar JC, Willig RD (1982) Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure. New York: Harcourt, Brace, Jovanovich.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Baumol WJ, Oates WE (1988) The theory of environmental policy, 2nd edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  13. Cassell JM (1937) Excess capacity and monopolistic competition. Q J Econ 51(3):426–443

    Google Scholar 

  14. Chambers RG, Melkonyan T (2012) Production technologies, material balance, and the income-environmental quality trade-off. University of Exeter working paper

    Google Scholar 

  15. Chambers RG, Chung Y, Färe R (1996) Benefit and distance functions. J Econ Theory 70:407–419

    Google Scholar 

  16. Chambers RG, Chung Y, Färe R (1998) Profit, directional distance functions, and nerlovian efficiency. J Optim Theory Appl 98:351–364

    Google Scholar 

  17. Charnes A, Cooper WW (1968) Programming with linear fractional functionals. Nav Res Logist Q 15:517–522

    Google Scholar 

  18. Charnes AC, Cooper WW, Mellon B (1952) Blending aviation gasolines – a study in programming interdependent activities in an integrated oil company. Econometrica 20(2):135–159

    Google Scholar 

  19. Charnes A, Cooper WW, Rhodes E (1978) Measuring the efficiency of decision making units. Eur J Oper Res 2(6):429–444

    Google Scholar 

  20. Charnes A, Cooper WW, Rhodes E (1979) Short communication: measuring the efficiency of decision making units. Eur J Oper Res 3(4):339

    Google Scholar 

  21. Coelli T, Lauwers L, Van Huylenbroeck GV (2007) Environmental efficiency measurement and the materials balance condition. J Prod Anal 28:3–12

    Google Scholar 

  22. Cooper WW, Thompson RG, Thrall RM (1996) Introduction: extensions and new developments in DEA. Ann Oper Res 66:3–45

    Google Scholar 

  23. Cooper WW, Park SK, Pastor JT (1999) RAM: a range adjusted measure of inefficiency for use with additive models, and relations to other models and measures in DEA. J Prod Anal 11:5–42

    Google Scholar 

  24. Cooper WW, Seiford L, Tone K (2002) Data envelopment analysis: a comprehensive text with uses, example applications, references and DEA-solver software. Kluwer, Norwell

    Google Scholar 

  25. Cropper ML, Oates WE (1992) Environmental economics: a survey. J Econ Lit 30:675–740

    Google Scholar 

  26. Dantzig GB (1951) Maximization of a linear function of variables subject to linear inequalities. In: Koopmans TC (ed) Activity analysis of production and allocation. Wiley, New York, pp 339–347

    Google Scholar 

  27. Dapko KH, Jeanneauxe P, Latruffe L (2016) Modeling pollution generating technologies in performance benchmarking: recent developments, limits, and future prospects in the non-parametric framework. Eur J Oper Res 250:347–359

    Google Scholar 

  28. Debreu G (1951) The coefficient of resource utilization. Econometrica 19(3):273–292

    Google Scholar 

  29. Färe R, Grosskopf S (2003) Nonparametric productivity analysis with undesirable outputs: comment. Am J Agric Econ 85:1070–1074

    Google Scholar 

  30. Färe R, Lovell CAK (1978) Measuring the technical efficiency of production. J Econ Theory 19(1):150–162

    Google Scholar 

  31. Färe R, Grosskopf S, Lovell CAK (1985) The measurement of efficiency of production. Kluwer-Nijhoff, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  32. Färe R, Grosskopf S, Kokkelenberg EC (1989) Measuring plant capacity, utilization and technical change: a nonparametric approach. Int Econ Rev 30(3):655–666

    Google Scholar 

  33. Färe R, Grosskopf S, Lovell CAK, Pasurka C (1989) Multilateral productivity comparisons when some outputs are undesirable: a non-parametric approach. Rev Econ Stat 71(1):90–98

    Google Scholar 

  34. Färe R, Grosskopf S, Lovell CAK, Yaisawarng S (1993) Derivation of shadow prices for undesirable outputs: a distance function approach. Rev Econ Stat 75:374–380

    Google Scholar 

  35. Färe R, Grosskopf S, Lovell CAK (1994) Production frontiers. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  36. Färe R, Grosskopf S, Noh DW, Weber W (2005) Characteristics of a polluting technology: theory and practice. J Econ 126:469–492

    Google Scholar 

  37. Farrell MJ (1957) The measurement of technical efficiency. J R Stat Soc Ser A Gen 120(Part 3):253–281

    Google Scholar 

  38. Førsund F (2009) Good modelling of bad outputs: pollution and multiple-output production. Int Rev Environ Resour Econ 3(1):1–38

    Google Scholar 

  39. Førsund F (2018) Multi-equation modeling of desirable and undesirable outputs satisfying the material balance. Empir Econ, online 54(1):67–99

    Google Scholar 

  40. Frisch R (1965) Theory of production. Rand McNally and Company, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  41. Hampf B (2014) Separating environmental efficiency into production and abatement efficiency: a nonparametric model with application to US power plants. J Prod Anal 41:457–473

    Google Scholar 

  42. Hanoch G, Rothschild M (1972) Testing the assumptions of production theory: a nonparametric approach. J Polit Econ 80(2):256–275

    Google Scholar 

  43. Johansen L (1968) Production functions and the concept of capacity. Reprinted in Førsund FR (ed) Collected works of Leif Johansen, vol 1. North Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  44. Koopmans TJ (1951) Analysis of production as an efficient combination of activities. In: Koopmans TJ (ed) Activity analysis of production and allocation. Wiley, New York, pp 33–97

    Google Scholar 

  45. Koopmans TJ (1957) Three essays on the state of economic science. McGraw Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  46. Kumbhakar S, Lovell CAK (2000) Stochastic frontier analysis. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  47. Leleu H, Briec W (2009) A DEA estimation of a lower bound for firms’ allocative efficiency without information on price data. Int J Prod Econ 121:203–211

    Google Scholar 

  48. Lozano SC (2015) A joint-inputs network DEA approach to production and pollution-generating technologies. Expert Syst Appl 42:7960–7968

    Google Scholar 

  49. Luenberger DG (1992) Benefit functions and duality. J Math Econ 21:115–145

    Google Scholar 

  50. Murty S, Russell RR (2016) Modeling emission-generating technologies: reconciliation of axiomatic and by-production approaches. Empir Econ 54(1):7–30

    Google Scholar 

  51. Murty S, Russell R, Levkoff SB (2012) On modeling pollution-generating technologies. J Environ Econ Manag 64:117–135

    Google Scholar 

  52. Pastor JT, Louis JL, Sirvent I (1999) An enhanced DEA Russell-graph efficiency measure. Eur J Oper Res 115:596–607

    Google Scholar 

  53. Pethig R (2006) Non-linear production, abatement, pollution and materials balance reconsidered. J Environ Econ Manag 51:185–204

    Google Scholar 

  54. Portela MCAS, Thanassoulis E (2005) Profitability of a sample of Portuguese bank branches and its decomposition into technical and allocative components. Eur J Oper Res 162(3):850–866

    Google Scholar 

  55. Ray SC (1988) Data envelopment analysis, non-discretionary inputs and efficiency: an alternative interpretation. Socio Econ Plan Sci 22(4):167–176

    Google Scholar 

  56. Ray SC (1991) Resource-use efficiency in public schools: a study of Connecticut data. Manag Sci 37(12):1620–1628

    Google Scholar 

  57. Ray SC (2004) Data envelopment analysis: theory and techniques for economics and operations research. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  58. Ray SC (2007) Shadow profit maximization and a measure of overall inefficiency. J Prod Anal 27:231–236

    Google Scholar 

  59. Ray SC (2009) Are Indian firms too small? A nonparametric analysis of cost efficiency and the optimal organization of industry in Indian manufacturing. Indian Econ Rev XXXXVI(1):49–67

    Google Scholar 

  60. Ray SC (2010) A one-step procedure for returns to scale classification of decision making units in data envelopment analysis. University of Connecticut Economics working paper 2010-07

    Google Scholar 

  61. Ray SC (2015) Nonparametric measures of scale economies and capacity utilization: an application to U.S. manufacturing. Eur J Oper Res 245:602–611

    Google Scholar 

  62. Ray SC, Ghose A (2014) Production efficiency in Indian agriculture: an assessment of the post green revolution years. Omega 44:58–69

    Google Scholar 

  63. Ray SC, Jeon Y (2009) Reputation and efficiency: a non-parametric assessment of America’s top-rated MBA programs. Eur J Oper Res 189(2008):245–268

    Google Scholar 

  64. Ray SC, Mukherjee K (2016) Data envelopment analysis with aggregated inputs and a test of allocative efficiency when input prices vary across firms. Data Envel Anal J 2(2):141–161

    Google Scholar 

  65. Ray SC, Chen L, Mukherjee K (2008) Input price variation across locations and a generalized measure of cost efficiency. Int J Prod Econ 116:208–218

    Google Scholar 

  66. Ray SC, Mukherjee K, Venkatesh A (2018) Nonparametric measures of efficiency in the presence of undesirable outputs: a by-production approach with weak disposability. Empir Econ 54(1):31–65

    Google Scholar 

  67. Ray SC, Walden J, Chen L (2018) Economic Measures of Capacity Utilization: A Nonparametric Cost Function Analysis. Working Paper 2018--02, University of Connecticut, Department of Economics

    Google Scholar 

  68. Rodseth KL (2015) Axioms of a polluting technology: a materials balance approach. Environ Res Econ 67(1):1–22. Online October 2015

    Google Scholar 

  69. Rodseth KL (2016) Environmental efficiency measurement and the materials balance condition reconsidered. Eur J Oper Res 250:342–346

    Google Scholar 

  70. Ruggiero J (1998) Non-discretionary inputs in data envelopment analysis. Eur J Oper Res 111:461–469

    Google Scholar 

  71. Seiford L, Zhu J (1999) An investigation of returns to scale in data envelopment analysis. Omega Int J Manag Sci 27:1–11

    Google Scholar 

  72. Shephard RW (1953) Cost and production functions. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  73. Shephard RW (1970) Theory of cost and production functions. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  74. Tone K (2001) A slacks-based measure of efficiency in data envelopment analysis. Eur J Oper Res 130:498–509

    Google Scholar 

  75. Tone K (2002) A strange case of the cost and allocative efficiencies in DEA. J Oper Res Soc 53:1225–1231

    Google Scholar 

  76. Varian HR (1984) The nonparametric approach to production analysis. Econometrica 52(3):579–597

    Google Scholar 

  77. Zhu J (2003) Quantitative models for performance evaluation and benchmarking: data envelopment analysis with spreadsheets and DEA excel solver. Kluwer Academic, Boston

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Subhash C. Ray .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this entry

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this entry

Ray, S.C. (2020). Data Envelopment Analysis: A Nonparametric Method of Production Analysis. In: Ray, S., Chambers, R., Kumbhakar, S. (eds) Handbook of Production Economics. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-3450-3_24-1

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-3450-3_24-1

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-10-3450-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-10-3450-3

  • eBook Packages: Springer Reference Economics and FinanceReference Module Humanities and Social SciencesReference Module Business, Economics and Social Sciences

Publish with us

Policies and ethics