Skip to main content

Japan and China in a Two-Hub Formation of Regional Integration in East Asia

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Initiatives of Regional Integration in Asia in Comparative Perspective

Part of the book series: United Nations University Series on Regionalism ((UNSR,volume 14))

Abstract

East Asian countries are looking for an institutional scheme to deepen the initial market-led regional integration. This chapter measures the existing bilateral trade relations among East Asian countries by calculating BTR index (de facto Bilateral Trade Relation), economic distance and HM index (Hub-ness index). Based on the comparison of de facto trade preferences among East Asian countries, it investigates East Asian regionalism in a two-hub formation (an ‘East Asian Bicycle’), of which Japan and China might be the two potential hub candidates. The ASEAN-China free trade zone may spur regional integration in East Asia by motivating other East Asian nations to join the ASEAN-China FTA early and at the same time liberalize trade amongst each other.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The ten member countries of ASEAN cover Brunei Darussalam, Cambodia, Indonesia, Laos, Malaysia, Myanmar, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand and Vietnam.

  2. 2.

    Production sharing can be defined as “the internationalization of a manufacturing process in which several countries participate in different stages of a specific good’s fabrication” (Ng and Yeats 2001).

  3. 3.

    When arranging East Asian “wild geese” into a four-tiered formation one may regard Japan as the lead goose followed by the four Asian Newly Industrialized Economies (NIEs) (the second tier), the four main ASEAN countries (the third tier) and finally other developing economies such as China and Vietnam. International trade and investment are the key linkages among them. For an insightful account of the development of Japan’s postwar economy see inter alia Uchino 1978. On the role of the USA in Japan’s economic development which seems to be somewhat downplayed in Akamatsu’s model see Ozawa 2003. Even today, the regional economy is still highly dependent on the US economy. The share of East Asian economies in the US trade deficit continued to increase until 1992 when it reached the peak at about 48 percent or almost half of the total. It declined gradually afterwards and remained at a level slightly less than 40 percent during the 2000s. The volume of the region’s total trade surplus with the US amounted to more than USD 1 trillion in 2005.

  4. 4.

    On the financial crisis and Asian countries’ reactions see also Loewen in this volume.

  5. 5.

    The Agreement on Trade in Goods took effect in 2010 when China and six ASEAN member states (Brunei, Malaysia, Philippines, Indonesia, Singapore and Thailand) eliminated tariffs on 90 percent of goods. Free trade in goods is planned to be extended to the remaining four ASEAN member states (Cambodia, Laos, Myanmar and Vietnam) by 2015. The Trade in Services Agreement entered into force in 2007. In addition, an Investment Agreement was signed in 2010.

  6. 6.

    ‘ASEAN-plus-Three’ is an informal group whose formation was motivated by the East Asian crisis. It does not have its own secretariat but meets at the invitation of ASEAN. The group came together annually since the first meeting in December 1997. Updates on the ASEAN +3 summits can be found on the website of the ASEAN secretariat at http://www.aseansec.org/.

  7. 7.

    On Hub-and-spoke systems see also Zorob in this volume.

  8. 8.

    See Baldwin (1994), Wonnacott (1996) and Zorob (2008) as well as Zorob in this volume for further discussion on the role of ROOs, hub-and-spoke bilateralism and the problems of overlapping free trade agreements.

  9. 9.

    ASEAN-5 refers to Malaysia, Indonesia, Philippines, Thailand and Vietnam. For reasons of simplification the analysis here ignores the four small ASEAN member states: Brunei, Cambodia, Laos PDR and Myanmar due to the fact that their contribution to regional trade is marginal.

  10. 10.

    Japan negotiated and signed agreements with each individual ASEAN member state. For reasons of simplification these FTA/FTA negotiations are loosely called the Japan-ASEAN FTA/FTA negotiations in the following.

References

  • Akamatsu, K. (1962). A historical pattern of economic growth in developing countries. The Developing Economies, 1(1), 3–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. (1994). Towards an integrated Europe. London: CEPR.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. (2004). The Spoke Trap: Hub and Spoke Bilateralism in East Asia. KIEP Discussion Paper, No. 04–02. Seoul: Korea Institute for International Economic Policy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R., Forslid, R., Martin, P., Ottaviano, G., & Robert-Nicoud, F. (2003). Economic geography and public policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati, J. (1995). U.S. trade policy: The infatuation with free trade areas. In J. Bhagwati & A. O. Krueger (Eds.), The dangerous drift to preferential trade agreements (pp. 1–18). Washington, DC: AEI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergsten, C. F. (2007). Towards a free trade area of the Asia Pacific. Policy Briefs in International Economics, No. PB07–2. Washington, DC: Peter G. Peterson Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, L. (2008). The Market Driven Trade Liberalization and East Asian Regional Integration. HEID Working Paper, No. 12/2008. Geneva: Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drysdale, P., Elek, A., & Soesastro, H. (1998). Open regionalism: The nature of Asia Pacific integration. In P. Drysdale & D. Vines (Eds.), Europe, East Asia and APEC: A shared global agenda? (pp. 103–136). Australia: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita, M. (2005). Regional integration in Asia: How to be further promoted in harmony? Dynamism and Uncertainty in Asia, Speech at The Science Council of Japan Conference on Sustainability 2005. http://www.scj.go.jp/ja/int/kaisai/jizoku/dynamism-asia/program/pdf/o4_masahisa-fujita.pdf. Accessed 7 May 2012.

  • Fujita, M., Krugman, P., & Venables, A. J. (1999). The spatial economy: Cities, regions, and international trade. Cambridge & London: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund. (2012). .World Economic Outlook Database 2012. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/01/weodata. Accessed 7 May 2012.

  • Kawai, M. (2004). Regional economic integration and cooperation in East Asia, Seminar on the ‘Impact and Coherence of OECD Country Policies on Asian Developing Economies’. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, S. (2004). Regionalization and regionalism in East Asia. Journal of East Asian Studies, 4(1), 39–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kotera, A. (2006). What is the “Spaghetti Bowl Phenomenon” of FTAs? RIETI online column No.0149. http://www.rieti.go.jp/en/columns/a01_0193.html. Accessed 2 Feb 2012.

  • Krugman, P. (1993). The hub effect: Or, threeness in interregional trade. In W. J. Ethier, E. Helpman, & J. P. Neary (Eds.), Therory, policy and dynamics in international trade (pp. 29–37). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Kuroda, H. (2006). The statement at the IMF-World Bank seminar on the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) and Pan-Asian Integration, Singapore.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neary, J. P.(2000). Of hype and Hyperbolas: Introducing the New Economic Geography. UCD School of Economics Working Papers, No. 00/19. Dublin: University College of Dublin, School of Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ng, F., & Yeats, A. (2001). Production sharing in East Asia: Who does what for whom, and why? In L. K. Cheng & H. Kierzkowski (Eds.), Global production and trade in East Asia (pp. 63–109). Boston: Kluwer Academic.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ozawa, T. (2003). Pax America-led macro-clustering and flying-geese-style catch-up in East Asia: Mechanism of regionalized endogenous growth. Journal of Asian Economics, 13(6), 699–713.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stubbs, R. (2002). ASEAN plus three: Emerging east Asian regionalism? Asian Survey, 42(3), 440–455.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uchino, T. (1978). Japan’s postwar economy. An Insider’s view of its history and its future. Tokyo: Kodansha International.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watanabe, O. (2006). Economic integration in East Asia and the roles of ASEAN and Japan, seminar on a new stage of East Asian Economic Integration, Singapore.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wonnacott, R. J. (1996). Trade and Investment in a hub-and-Spoke System versus a free trade area. The World Economy, 19(3), 237–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yamazawa, I. (2001). Assessing a Japan-Korea free trade agreement. The Developing Economies, 39(1), 3–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhuang, G., & Wang, W. (2010). Migration and trade: The role of overseas Chinese in economic relations between China and Southeast Asia. International Journal of China Studies, 1(1), 174–193.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zorob, A. (2008). Intraregional economic integration: The cases of GAFTA and MAFTA. In C. Harders & M. Legrenzi (Eds.), Beyond regionalism? Regional cooperation, regionalism and regionalization in the Middle East (pp. 169–183). Aldershot/Burlington: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lurong Chen .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix A: Measuring BTR Index and Economic Distance

Appendix A: Measuring BTR Index and Economic Distance

Chen (2008) generates BTR index and ‘economic distance’ based on the gravity model. The gravity equation simplifies the determinants of bilateral trade between countries (or regions) into two categories: partner countries’ properties, such as GDP, population, GDP per capita, etc. and trade cost of trade between partners, such as transport costs, tariff barriers, quotas, etc.. Lower trade costs will encourage bilateral trade between countries while higher costs will discourage it. Loosely speaking, there are two types of trade costs. One is related to ‘natural frictions’, such as the geographical distance, level of technology, etc., and the other is related to ‘policy frictions’, primarily the degree of bilateral liberalization. Assuming that the marginal effect of either GDP or GDP per capita on bilateral trade is identical over a certain time period, the marginal effect of distance can be magnified or shrunk by individual bilateral trade relations. This can be seen in eq. (2.1):

$$ Trad{e}_{ij}=\frac{{\left( GD{P}_i\cdot GD{P}_j\right)}^{\alpha}\cdot {\left({K}_i\cdot {K}_j\right)}^{\beta }}{Dis{t_{ij}}^{\gamma_{ij}}} $$
(2.1)

where α, β and γ ij represent the marginal effect of GDP, GDP per capita(K) and distance respectively. The coefficients, α and β, are assumed to be identical while the coefficient γ ij may vary for each pair of countries. γ ij is the variable in the equation that contains the country specific propensity. Imagining that policy frictions can affect a country’s bilateral trade flow through their impact on the geographic distance, the economic distance (ED ij ) can be defined as geographic distance (Dist ij ) multiplied by a parameter A ij , which essentially reflects the relative degree of bilateral trade liberalization.

$$ \mathrm{EDij}=\mathrm{Aij}\times \mathrm{Distij} $$
(2.2)

Accordingly a revised version of gravity equation looks like.

$$ {M}_{ij}=\frac{\left({Y_i}^{\beta_1}\cdot {Y_j}^{\beta_2}\right)\cdot \left({y_i}^{\beta_3}\cdot {y_j}^{\beta_4}\right)}{{\left({A}_{ij}\times Dis{t}_{ij}\right)}^{\beta_5}} $$
(2.3)

It transforms into eq. (2.3) by taking in logarithm form.

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\log {\left({M}_{ij}\right)}_{\mathrm{t}}={\beta}_1\times \log {\left({Y}_i\right)}_{\mathrm{t}}+{\beta}_2\times \log {\left({Y}_j\right)}_{\mathrm{t}}+{\beta}_3\times \log {\left({y}_i\right)}_{\mathrm{t}}\\ {}+{\beta}_4\times \log {\left({y}_j\right)}_{\mathrm{t}.}+{\beta}_5\times \log \left( Dis{t}_{ij}\right)+{\beta}_5\times \log \left({\hat{A}}_{ij}\right)\end{array}} $$
(2.4)

We therefore use two-step regressions to estimate the parameters in the equation above based on the fixed-effect regression on panel data.

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}\mathrm{Step}\ \mathrm{one}:\log {\left({M}_{ij}\right)}_{\mathrm{t}}={\hat{\beta}}_1\times \log {\left({Y}_i\right)}_{\mathrm{t}}+{\hat{\beta}}_2\times \log {\left({Y}_j\right)}_{\mathrm{t}}+{\hat{\beta}}_3\times \log {\left({y}_i\right)}_{\mathrm{t}}\\ {}+{\hat{\beta}}_4\times \log {\left({y}_j\right)}_{\mathrm{t}}+F{E}_{ij}+{v}_{ij,t}\end{array}} $$
(2.5)
$$ \mathrm{Step}\ \mathrm{two}:F{E}_{ij}=C+{\hat{\beta}}_5\times \log \left( Dis{t}_{ij}\right)+u $$
(2.6)

where \( {\hat{\beta}}_i \) (i = 1 … 5) denotes the estimated marginal effect of each independent variable, FE ij denotes the fix effect, v ij,t and u are the disturbance terms.

Combining equation (2.5) and (2.6) with the targeted function (2.4), we have\( {\mathrm{BTR}}_{\mathrm{ij}}={\widehat{\mathrm{A}}}_{\mathrm{ij}}=\frac{\exp \left({\mathrm{FE}}_{\mathrm{ij}}/{\widehat{\beta}}_5\right)}{{\mathrm{Dist}}_{\mathrm{ij}}} \) . The smaller value of BTR ij hints the higher degree of market openness of country i to country j. Furthermore, BTR ij <1 can be interpreted as a signal of ‘pro-trade’ effects of bilateral trade policy that encourage country i to import more from country j, while BTR ij >1 is a signal of ‘anti-trade’ effects showing the additional cost of country i’s import from country j due to political frictions.

With further assumption that countries i and j are treating each other reciprocally and therefore the bilateral trade preference between them is symmetric, BTR ij =BTR ji . Accordingly the economic distance is calculated based on the definitionED ij =BTR ij Dist ij . One country’s import from country j is not only affected by its own import policy but also by its trading partner, country j’s export policy. Empirically it would very difficult to distinguish the different effects from these two parties accurately. Holding this assumption, the symmetric BTR index is estimated based on equation (2.7):

$$ {T}_{ij}={T}_{ji}=\left(I{M}_{ij}+I{M}_{ji}\right)=\frac{{\left({Y}_i+{Y}_j\right)}^{\alpha}\cdot {\left({y}_i+{y}_j\right)}^{\beta }}{{\left({A}_{ij}\times Dis{t}_{ij}\right)}^{\gamma }} $$
(2.7)

where T ij and T ji is the overall trade volume between the two countries (aggregate imports plus aggregate exports).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer Science+Business Media B.V.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Chen, L. (2018). Japan and China in a Two-Hub Formation of Regional Integration in East Asia. In: Loewen, H., Zorob, A. (eds) Initiatives of Regional Integration in Asia in Comparative Perspective. United Nations University Series on Regionalism, vol 14. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-024-1211-6_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics