Skip to main content

Dynamic Efficiency Measurement

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Benchmarking for Performance Evaluation

Abstract

A philosophical problem for studies of inefficiency of firms is how to rationalise inefficiency. Since economics do not have any theory for inefficiency, explaining the results of efficiency analyses is notoriously more difficult than carrying out the estimations. The literature points to measures of inputs and management as not including quality dimensions as a reason for measured efficiency differences, indicating that more work needs to be done on data collection. Strategic behaviour in game situations between owners and management and between management and labour may also show up as inefficiencies. Another reason is technology differences. The frontier production function is the key to information on best practice technology. Estimation of efficiency is usually done for units observed during the same time period; thus, in this respect, the measures are static. Interpretations of dynamic efficiency measurement are offered. The vintage model of substitutability between inputs including capital before investment, but no substitution possibilities after investment, and ex post production possibilities characterised by fixed input coefficients, can rationalise inefficiency due to technology differences. Key elements in understanding structural change are the entering of capacity embodying new technology and exiting of capacity no longer able to yield positive quasi-rent. Three crucial production function concepts are identified as follows: the ex ante micro-unit production function as relevant when investing in new capacity, the ex post micro-production function, and the short-run industry production function giving the production possibilities at the industry level. Productivity measurement, taking these types of production functions into consideration, leads to different interpretations of productivity change than traditional approaches not being clear about which production function concept is used.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Cost of adjustment is introduced in Sengupta (1995, 1996). However, it is not so easy to understand how the dynamics of his analyses actually work, cf. comments in Nemoto and Goto (2003, p. 192).

  2. 2.

    The basis of the modelling except the specific adaptation of the DEA model has much in common with the approach in Rubin (1973).

  3. 3.

    If deviation form an optimal path is called waste, confer Stigler (1976, p. 576): “…waste is not a useful economic concept. Waste is error within the framework of modern economic analysis, and it will not become a useful concept until we have a theory of error.”

  4. 4.

    As expressed in Rothschild (1971, p. 605), “Much of the current interest in cost of adjustment functions stems from their ability to provide a rigorous theoretical justification for the use of distributed lags in econometric studies of investment behavior.”

  5. 5.

    As to the Penrose effect of the importance of constrained management resources, Slater (1980, p. 521) remarks that there is no recognition in economists’ models of the role of the management; management has no role to play which bears upon the firm’s performance.

  6. 6.

    In practice merit order is based on costs, therefore the theoretical merit order based on quasi-rent will only be relevant if input prices are equal.

  7. 7.

    In Førsund and Hjalmarsson (1979), introducing this measure, it was called the gross scale efficiency.

References

  • Afriat, S. 1972. Efficiency estimation of production functions. International Economic Review 13(3): 568–598.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aigner, D.J., and S.F. Chu. 1968. On estimating the industry production function. American Economic Review 58(4): 826–839.

    Google Scholar 

  • Battese, G., and P.D.S. Rao. 2002. Technology gap, efficiency, and a stochastic metafrontier function. International Journal of Business and Economics 1(2): 87–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Battese, G., P.D.S. Rao, and C.J. O’Donnell. 2004. A metafrontier production function for estimation of technical efficiencies and technology gaps for firms operating under different technologies. Journal of Productivity Analysis 21: 91–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W.J. 1962. On the theory of expansion of the firm. The American Economic Review 52(5): 1078–1087.

    Google Scholar 

  • Belifante, A. 1978. The identification of technical change in the electricity generating industry. In Production economics: a dual approach to theory and applications, ed. M. Fuss and D. McFadden, vol. 2, Chap. IV.3, pp. 149–186. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berg, S.A., F.R. Førsund, and E. Jansen. 1992. Malmquist indices of productivity growth during the deregulation of Norwegian banking, 1980–1989. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 94: S211–S228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bogetoft, P., and J.L. Hougaard. 2003. Rational inefficiencies. Journal of Productivity Analysis 20: 243–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bye, T., and E. Holmøy. 2010. Removing policy based comparative advantage for energy intensive production: necessary adjustments of the real exchange rate and industry structure. The Energy Journal 31(1): 177–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves, D.W., L.R. Christensen, and W.E. Diewert. 1982. The economic theory of index numbers and the measurement of input, output, and productivity. Econometrica 50: 1393–1414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charnes, A., W.W. Cooper, and E. Rhodes. 1978. Measuring the efficiency of decision making units. European Journal of Operational Research 2: 429–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charnes, A., W.W. Cooper, and E. Rhodes. 1981. Evaluating program and managerial efficiency: an application of data envelopment analysis to program follow through. Management Science 27(6): 668–697.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eide, E. 1976. Do new factories embody potential best practice technology? Empirical Economics 1(2): 119–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eisner, R., and R. Strotz. 1963. Determinants of business investment. In Impacts of monetary policy. Part I. Commission on Money and Credit, pp. 59–233. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe, R., and D. Primont. 1995. Multi-output production and duality: theory and applications. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe, R., and S. Grosskopf. 1996. Intertemporal production frontiers: with dynamic DEA. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe, R., S. Grosskopf, B. Lindgren, and P. Roos. 1994. Productivity developments in Swedish hospitals: a Malmquist output index approach. In Data envelopment analysis: theory, methodology, and applications, ed. A. Charnes, W.W. Cooper, A.Y. Lewin, and L.M. Seiford, 253–272. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, M.J. 1957. The measurement of productive efficiency. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series A (General) 120(III):253–281.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frisch, R. 1965. Theory of production. Dordrecht: D. Reidel.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fuss, M. 1978. Factor substitution in electricity generation: a test of the putty-clay hypothesis. In Production economics: a dual approach to theory and applications, ed. Melvin Fuss and Daniel McFadden, vol. 2, Chap. IV.4, pp. 187–213. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Førsund, F.R., and L. Hjalmarsson. 1974. On the measurement of productive efficiency. Swedish Journal of Economics 76(2): 141–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Førsund, F.R., and L. Hjalmarsson. 1979. Generalised Farrell measures of efficiency: an application to milk processing in Swedish dairy plants. Economic Journal 89: 294–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Førsund, F.R., and L. Hjalmarsson. 1987. Analyses of industrial structure: a putty-clay approach. Industrial Institute for Economic and Social Research. Stockholm: Almqvist and Wicksell International.

    Google Scholar 

  • Førsund, F.R., and E.S. Jansen. 1983. Technical progress and structural change in the Norwegian aluminium industry. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 85: 113–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Førsund, F.R., L. Hjalmarsson, and T. Summa. 1996. The interplay between micro-frontier and sectoral short-run production functions. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 98(3): 365–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gould, J.P. 1968. Adjustment costs in the theory of investment of the firm. Review of Economic Studies 35(1): 47–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gini, C. 1931. On the circular test of index numbers. Metron (International Review of Statistics) 9(2): 3–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grifell-TatjĂ©, E., and C.A.K. Lovell. 1995. A note on the Malmquist productivity index. Economics Letters 47(2): 169–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haavelmo, T. 1960. A Study in the Theory of Investment. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamermesh, D.S., and G.A. Pfann. 1996. Adjustment costs in factor demand. Journal of Economic Literature 34(September): 1264–1292.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haskel, J., and A. Sanchis. 1995. Privatisation and X-inefficiency: a bargaining approach. The Journal of Industrial Economics 43(3): 301–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haskel, J., and A. Sanchis. 2000. A bargaining model of Farrell inefficiency. International Journal of Industrial Organization 18: 5–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayami, Y., and V.W. Ruttan. 1970. Agricultural productivity differences among countries. American Economic Review 60(5): 895–911.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckscher, E. 1918. Svenska produktionsproblem (Swedish production problems). Stockholm: Bonniers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansen, L. 1972. Production functions. An integration of micro and macro, short run and long run aspects. Amsterdam-London: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansen, L., and A. Sørsveen. 1967. Notes on the measurement of real capital in relation to economic planning models. Review of Income and Wealth, Series 13: 175–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D.W. 1966. The embodiment hypothesis. Journal of Political Economy 74(1): 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leibenstein, H. 1966. Allocative efficiency vs. “X-efficiency”. American Economic Review 56(3): 392–415.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewin, A.Y., and J.W. Minton. 1986. Determining organizational effectiveness: another look, and an agenda for research. Management Science 32(5): 514–538.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E. 1967. Adjustment costs and the theory of supply. The Journal of Political Economy 75(4): 321–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. 1890. Principles of economics, 8th edn. (1966). London-Melbourne-Toronto: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maywald, K. 1957. The best and the average in productivity studies and in long-term forecasting. The Productivity Measurement Review 9: 37–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, W.C. 1937. The social sciences and national planning. In Planned society. Yesterday today tomorrow, ed. F. McKenzie. New York: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nemoto, J., and M. Goto. 1999. Dynamic data envelopment analysis: modeling intertemporal behavior of a firm in the presence of productive inefficiencies. Economics Letters 64: 51–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nemoto, J., and M. Goto. 2003. Measurement of dynamic efficiency in production: an application of data envelopment analysis to Japanese electric utilities. Journal of Productivity Analysis 19: 191–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell, C.J., G. Battese, and P.D.S. Rao. 2008. Metafrontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios. Empirical Economics 34: 231–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Penrose, E. 1959. The theory of the growth of the firm. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phelps, E.S. 1963. Substitution, fixed proportions, growth and distribution. International Economic Review 4: 265–288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothschild, M. 1971. On the cost of adjustment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 85(4): 605–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, P.H. 1973. The expansion of firms. Journal of Political Economy 81(4): 936–949.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salter, W.E.G. 1960. Productivity and technical change. London: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sengupta, J.K. 1995. Dynamics of data envelopment analysis. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publisher.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sengupta, J.K. 1996. Dynamic data envelopment analysis. International Journal of Systems Science 27(3): 277–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shen, T.Y. 1970. Economies of scale, Penrose effect, growth of plants, and their size distribution. The Journal of Political Economy 78(4): 702–716.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slater, M. 1980. The managerial limitations to the growth of firms. The Economic Journal 90(September): 520–528.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. 1976. The Xistence of X-efficiency. American Economic Review 66(1): 213–216.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tan, D., and J.T. Mahoney. 2005. Examining the Penrose effect in an international business context: the dynamics of Japanese firm growth in US industries. Managerial and Decision Economics 26: 113–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, F.W. 1911. The principles of scientific management. Harper & Brothers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tran, N.-B., and V.K. Smith. 1983. The role of air and water residuals for steam electric power generation. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 10: 35–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Finn R. Førsund .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer India

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Førsund, F.R. (2015). Dynamic Efficiency Measurement. In: Ray, S., Kumbhakar, S., Dua, P. (eds) Benchmarking for Performance Evaluation. Springer, New Delhi. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-81-322-2253-8_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics