Skip to main content

Which Side of the Economy Is Affected More by Oil Prices: Supply or Demand?

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Monetary Policy and the Oil Market

Abstract

This chapter develops a New Keynesian model to examine a theoretical global economy with two basic macroeconomic components: an energy producer and an energy consumer. (From now on in this chapter whenever we refer to the “energy” or “energy prices”, we refer to “crude oil” and “crude oil price”, which is the main source of energy.) This simple economy uses these two components to evaluate how oil prices affect the consumer economy’s gross domestic product and inflation from 1960 to 2011. This model assumes that changes in the oil price transfer to macro variables through either supply (aggregate supply curve) or demand channels (aggregate demand curve). In order to examine the effects of this transfer, an IS curve is used to look at the demand side and a Phillips curve is used to analyze inflationary effects from the supply side. The empirical analysis concludes that movements in the oil price mainly affect the economy through the demand side (shifting the aggregate demand curve) by affecting household expenditures and energy consumption. This analysis provides several additional findings, among which is that easy monetary policies amplify energy demand more than supply, resulting in skyrocketing crude oil prices, which inhibit economic growth.

An earlier version of this chapter first appeared as F. Taghizadeh-Hesary and N. Yoshino. 2013. Which side of the economy is affected more by oil prices: Supply or demand? USAEE Research Paper No. 13-139. Reused with permission from the United States Association for Energy Economics.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In 2010, the US consumed over 19 million barrels per day, which was more than 20 % of global consumption. Despite the growth in crude oil consumption in the People’s Republic of China, the Russian Federation, Latin America, and the Middle East, the US remains by far the largest user of oil. In our research since we have to use one country as the consumer of crude oil, the US is the best choice because of its high oil consumption.

  2. 2.

    By cost minimization of the representative household, we obtain the following demand condition. As in Dixit and Stiglitz (1977), Clarida et al. (2002), and Yoshino et al. (2012), the purchase of each good satisfies the following:

    $$ {C}_t^{NG}=A{C}_t{\left(\frac{P_t^{NG}}{P_t^C}\right)}^{-1} $$
    (3.1)
    $$ {C}_t^G=\left(1-A\right){C}_t{\left(\frac{P_t^G}{P_t^C}\right)}^{-1} $$
    (3.2)
  3. 3.

    Substituting (1) and (2) of footnote 22 into Eq. (3.1) of the main text, the consumption price index (CPI) yields:

    $$ {P}_t^C={\left(\frac{A}{P_t^{NG}}\right)}^{-A}{\left(\frac{1-A}{P_t^G}\right)}^{A-1} $$
    (3.2)
  4. 4.

    Euler equation:

    $$ \frac{{\left({C}_t\right)}^{-\eta }}{P_t^C}=\beta {E}_t\left[\frac{{\left({C}_{t+1}\right)}^{-\eta }}{P_{t+1}^C}\left(1+{i}_t\right)\right] $$
    (3.1)

    Where i is the interest rate or nominal yields of bonds in time t, but since the representative household’s utility is indifferent with bonds and their yields, here our Euler equation is different from the one above.

  5. 5.

    Crude oil prices, in US$ per barrel.

  6. 6.

    We assumed that the total output Y t in this economy consists of two subsectors, industrial output Q t and service output, which is assumed to have been determined out of our model. (\( {Y}_t={Q}_t+ \) service sector output)

  7. 7.

    ε t obtained from the following equation:

    $$ {\varepsilon}_t=\xi \left\lfloor \left(\omega +{\sigma}^{-1}\right)\left({\widehat{Y}}_t-{\widehat{Y}}_t^n\right)+\iota \omega \left({p}_t^G-\iota {p}_t^{NG}\right)\right\rfloor -\xi {E}_t\left\lfloor \left(\omega +{\sigma}^{-1}\right)\left({\widehat{Y}}_t-{\widehat{Y}}_t^n\right)+\iota \omega \left({p}_t^G-\iota {p}_t^{NG}\right)\right\rfloor $$
    (3.1)
  8. 8.

    Since oil is expected to be depleted at time T, it must be that \( {E}_{T-1}\left({q}_T^s\right)={E}_{T-1}\left({R}_{T-1}-{R}_T\right) \) and \( {E}_T\left({q}_{T+1}^s\right)=0 \) . That is, in the period after the last barrel of oil is extracted, extraction of oil must be equal to zero. β is a function of the interest rate, so the resulting implicit function for crude oil supply is: \( {q}_t^S=n\left({P}_t^G,{i}_t,{e}_t,{R}_{t-1}\right) \); where i t is the interest rate at time t.

  9. 9.

    The Asian Development Bank refers to China by the name People’s Republic of China.

References

  • Alterman, J. 1985. A historical perspective on changes in US energy-output ratios, Final Report EA-3997. Palo Alto: Electric Power Research Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B.S. 2006. Energy and the economy. Speech to the Economic Club of Chicago, 15 June.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B.S., M. Gertler, and M. Watson. 1997. Systematic monetary policy and the effects of oil price shocks. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 28(1): 91–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O., and C.M. Kahn. 1980. The solution of linear difference models under rational expectations. Econometrica 48: 1305–1313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bohi, D.R. 1991. On the macroeconomic effects of energy price shocks. Resource and Energy 13(2): 145–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruno, M. 1984. Raw materials, profits, and the productivity slowdown. Quarterly Journal of Economics 99(1): 1–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, G.A. 1983. Staggered prices in utility-maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 383–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarida, R., J. Galí, and M. Gertler. 2002. A simple framework for international monetary policy analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics 49: 879–904.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cunado, J., and F. Perez de Gracia. 2003. Do oil price shocks matter? Evidence for some European countries. Energy Economics 25: 137–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DePratto, B., C.D. Resende, and P. Maier. 2009. How changes in oil prices affect the macroeconomy? Bank of Canada Working Papers No. 2009-33. Ottawa: Bank of Canada.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A.K., and J.E. Stiglitz. 1977. Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. American Economic Review 67(3): 297–308.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farzin, Y.H. 1992. The time path of scarcity rent in the theory of exhaustible resources. Economic Journal 102(413): 813–830.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Favero, C.A., M.H. Pesaran, and S. Sharma. 1994. A duration model of irreversible oil investment: Theory and empirical evidence. Journal of Applied Econometrics 9: S95–S112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gately, D., and H.G. Huntington. 2002. The asymmetric effects of changes in price and income on energy and oil demand. Energy Journal 23(1): 19–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, J.D. 1983. Oil and the macroeconomy since World War II. Journal of Political Economics 91(2): 228–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, J.D. 1988. Are the macroeconomic effects of oil-price changes symmetric? A comment. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 28(1): 369–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, J.D., and A.M. Herrera. 2004. Oil shocks and aggregate macroeconomic behavior: The role of monetary policy: Comment. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 36(2): 265–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, J.A., W.K. Newey, and W.E. Taylor. 1987. Efficient estimation and identification of simultaneous equation models with covariance restrictions. Econometrica 55: 849–874.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. 1931. The economics of exhaustible resources. Journal of Political Economics 39(2): 137–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Javier, F.M. 1993. Oil prices and economic activity: Is the relationship symmetric? International Association for Energy Economics 14(4): 151–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kormilitsina, A. 2011. Oil price shocks and the optimality of monetary policy. Review of Economic Dynamics 14(1): 199–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krichene, N. 2006. World crude oil markets: Monetary policy and the recent oil shock, IMF Working Papers 06/62. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leduc, S., and K. Sill. 2004. A quantitative analysis of oil-price shocks, systematic monetary policy, and economic downturns. Journal of Monetary Economics 51(4): 781–808.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, K., and S. Ni. 2002. On the dynamic effects of oil price shocks: A study using industry level data. Journal of Monetary Economics 49(4): 823–852.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Livernois, J.R., and R.S. Uhler. 1987. Extraction costs and the economics of nonrenewable resources. Journal of Political Economy 95(1): 195–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCallum, B.T. 1976. Rational expectations and the natural rate hypothesis: Some consistent estimates. Econometrica 44: 43–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mohaddes, K. 2013. Econometric modelling of world oil supplies: Terminal price and the time to depletion. OPEC Energy Review 37: 162–193.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rasche, R.H., and J.A. Tatom. 1977. Energy resources and potential GNP. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 59(June): 10–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Revankar, N.S., and N. Yoshino. 1990. An “expanded equation” approach to weak-exogeneity tests in structural systems and a monetary application. Review of Economics and Statistics 72(1): 173–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taghizadeh-Hesary, F., and N. Yoshino. 2013. Which side of the economy is affected more by oil prices: Supply or demand? United States Association for Energy Economics Research Paper, No. 13-139. Ohio: United States Association for Energy Economics Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taghizadeh-Hesary, F., and N. Yoshino. 2014. Monetary policies and oil price determination: An empirical analysis. OPEC Energy Review 38(1): 1–20. doi:10.1111/opec.1202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taghizadeh-Hesary, F., N. Yoshino, G. Abdoli, and A. Farzinvash. 2013. An estimation of the impact of oil shocks on crude oil exporting economies and their trade partners. Frontiers of Economics in China 8(4): 571–591. doi:10.3868/s060-002-013-0029-3.Footnote

    The Asian Development Bank refers to China by the name People’s Republic of China.

  • Tatom, J.A. 1981. Energy prices and short-run economic performance. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, January 3–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodford, M. 2003. Interest and prices, foundations of a theory of monetary policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yoshino, N., and F. Taghizadeh-Hesary. 2014. Monetary policies and oil price fluctuations following the subprime mortgage crisis. International Journal of Monetary Economics and Finance 7(3): 157–174. doi:10.1504/IJMEF.2014.066482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yoshino, N., S. Kaji, and T. Asonuma. 2012. Choices of optimal monetary policy instruments under the floating and the basket-peg regimes. The Singapore Economic Review 57(4): 1250024-1–1250024-31. doi:10.1142/S0217590812500245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Farhad Taghizadeh-Hesary .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

3.1.1 (a) Euler, Money Demand , Labor Supply Equations (Log-Linearized Version)

The log-linearized versions of Eqs. (3.5, 3.6, and 3.7) are shown as:

$$ \begin{array}{ll}{c}_t=-\frac{b}{\eta }+{E}_t{c}_{t+1}+\frac{1}{\eta }{E}_t{\pi}_{t+1};\hfill & b= Log\beta, {E}_t{\pi}_{t+1}={E}_t{p}_{t+1}^c-{p}_t^c\hfill \end{array} $$
(3.38)
$$ \begin{array}{ll}{m}_t=\frac{1}{\sigma }{p}_t^c+\frac{\eta }{\sigma }{c}_t+\frac{v}{\sigma };\hfill & v= Log\chi \hfill \end{array} $$
(3.39)
$$ {l}_t=\frac{1}{\kappa}\left({w}_t-{p}_t^c-\eta {C}_t\right) $$
(3.40)

The lowercase letters denote the logarithms of the corresponding upper case variables. By solving these three equations for c t which is consumption in logarithmic form, the consumption equation yields:

$$ {c}_t=\frac{-b+v}{\eta }+{E}_t{c}_{t+1}+\frac{1}{\eta }{E}_t{\pi}_{t+1}-\frac{\sigma }{\eta }{m}_t+\frac{1}{\eta }{w}_t-\frac{\kappa }{\eta }{l}_t $$
(3.41)

3.1.2 (b) Household Energy Consumption

Since earlier in Eq. (3.38) of Sect. a of the Appendix we had written \( {E}_t{\pi}_{t+1}={E}_t\left({p}_{t+1}^c\right)-{p}_t^c \), here we convert it back, and substitute the right hand side of it in Eq. (3.41) of Sect a of the Appendix in order to release energy prices and non-energy prices from p c t . We log linearize the CPI equation (Eq. 3.39) as follows:

$$ \begin{array}{ll}{p}_t^c=\varepsilon -A\left(a-{p}_t^{NG}\right)+\left(A-1\right)\;\left(z-{p}_t^G\right);\hfill & \varepsilon = Log\lambda, a= Log A,z= Log\left(1-A\right)\hfill \end{array} $$
(3.42)

By substituting it and the expected value of Eq. (3.39) of Sect. a of the Appendix for t + 1 in Eq. (3.41) of Sect. a of the Appendix, the logarithmic form of the household consumption equation yields:

$$ {c}_t=\frac{-b-\varepsilon -\left(A-1\right)z+ Aa}{\eta }-\frac{A}{\eta }{p}_t^{NG}+\frac{\left(A-1\right)}{\eta }{p}_t^G+\frac{\sigma }{\eta }{E}_t{m}_{t+1}-\frac{\sigma }{\eta }{m}_t+\frac{1}{\eta }{w}_t-\frac{\kappa }{\eta }{l}_t $$
(3.43)

Substituting the anti-log of Eq. (3.43) of Sect. b of the Appendix into Eq. (2) of footnote 22, gives the demand of representative household for energy yields.

3.1.3 (c) Phillips Curve (Part 1)

Real marginal cost is written as follows:

$$ {s}_t=\left(\phi {W}_t+\varpi {P}_t^G\right) $$
(3.44)

Following Woodford’s (2003) analysis, we write the equation below, which shows the relationship between marginal cost of supply and output levels:

$$ {\widehat{s}}_t=\omega {\widehat{Q}}_t+{\sigma}^{-1}{\widehat{Y}}_t-\left(\omega +{\sigma}^{-1}\right){\widehat{Y}}_t^n $$
(3.45)

Where \( \omega >0 \) and \( \sigma >0 \). Letting \( \overline{Y} \) be the constant level of output in a steady state, and be level of output in full employment, we define \( {\widehat{Q}}_t= \log \left({Q}_t/\overline{Y}\right) \), \( {\widehat{Y}}_t= \log \left({Y}_t/\overline{Y}\right) \), \( {\widehat{Y}}_t^n= \log \left({Y}_t^n/\overline{Y}\right) \), and \( {\widehat{s}}_t= \log \left(\mu {s}_t\right) \), where \( \mu =\theta /\left(\theta -1\right)>1 \) is the seller’s desired markup. Substituting Eq. (3.45) in Sect. c of the Appendix in the following inflation equation from Calvo (1983) produces the following results:

$$ {\pi}_t=\xi {\widehat{s}}_t+\psi {E}_t{\pi}_{t+1} $$
(3.46)
$$ {\pi}_t\left\lfloor \omega {\widehat{Q}}_t+{\sigma}^{-1}{\widehat{Y}}_t-\left(\omega +{\sigma}^{-1}\right){\widehat{Y}}_t^n\right\rfloor \xi +\psi {E}_t{\pi}_{t+1} $$
(3.47)

Dividing Eq. (3.15) by \( \overline{Y} \) and obtaining the Log-linearization of this equation results in the following :

$$ {\widehat{Q}}_t= \log \left[\frac{Y_t}{\overline{Y}}\left(\frac{P_t^c}{P_t^{NG}}\right)\right]={\widehat{Y}}_t+{p}_t^c-{p}_t^{NG} $$
(3.48)

The corresponding log-linear approximation to the aggregate price index is as follows:

$$ {p}_t^c=\iota {p}_t^G+\left(1+\iota \right){p}_t^{NG} $$
(3.49)

Substituting the log linear aggregate price index (Eq. (3.49) of Sect. c of the Appendix) along with Eq. (3.48) of Sect. c of the Appendix into Eq. (3.47) of Sect. c of the Appendix yields a New-Keynesian Phillips curve:

$$ {\pi}_t=\xi \left\lfloor \left(\omega +{\sigma}^{-1}\right)\left({\widehat{Y}}_t-{\widehat{Y}}_t^n\right)+\omega \left(\iota {p}_t^G-\iota {p}_t^{NG}\right)\right\rfloor +\psi {E}_t{\pi}_{t+1} $$
(3.50)

We followed the Blanchard and Kahn (1980) method for rational expectations:

$$ {E}_t{\pi}_{t+1}=\frac{1}{\psi }{\pi}_t-\frac{\xi }{\psi}\left[\left(\omega +{\sigma}^{-1}\right)\left({\widehat{Y}}_t-{\widehat{Y}}_t^n\right)+\omega \left(\iota {p}_t^G-\iota {p}_t^{NG}\right)\right] $$
(3.51)

Then for the previous period we have:

$$ {E}_{t-1}{\pi}_t=\frac{1}{\psi }{\pi}_{t-1}-\frac{\xi }{\psi}\left[\left(\omega +{\sigma}^{-1}\right)\left({\widehat{Y}}_{t-1}-{\widehat{Y}}_{t-1}^n\right)+\omega \left(\iota {p}_{t-1}^G-\iota {p}_{t-1}^{NG}\right)\right] $$
(3.52)

This obtains the \( {E}_{t-1} \) value of Eq. (3.50) of Sect. c of the Appendix, which we can write in for the \( {E}_t{\pi}_{t+1} \) results :

$$ {E}_t{\pi}_{t+1}=\frac{1}{\psi }{E}_{t-1}{\pi}_t-\frac{\xi }{\psi }{E}_{t-1}\left[\left(\omega +{\sigma}^{-1}\right)\left({\widehat{Y}}_t-{\widehat{Y}}_t^n\right)+\omega \left(\iota {p}_t^G-\iota {p}_t^{NG}\right)\right] $$
(3.53)

After substituting \( {E}_{t-1}{\pi}_t \) from Eq. (3.52) of Sect. c of the Appendix with Eq. (3.53) of Sect. c of the Appendix and then setting Eq. (3.51) of Sect. c of the Appendix and Eq. (3.53) of Sect. c of the Appendix as equal the Phillips curve yields, however, it becomes apparent that this is not the final version of it and we need to do some more work on it.

3.1.4 (d) Phillips Curve (Part 2)

Initial version of Phillips curve:

$$ {\pi}_t=\frac{1}{\psi }{\pi}_{t-1}-\frac{\xi }{\psi}\left[\left(\omega +{\sigma}^{-1}\right)\left[{\widehat{Y}}_{t-1}-{\widehat{Y}}_{t-1}^n\right]+\omega \left(\iota {p}_{t-1}^G-\iota {p}_{t-1}^{NG}\right)\right]+{\varepsilon}_t $$
(3.54)

From Eq. (3.49) of Sect. c of the Appendix, we write the inflation rate in t-1 and substitute it in Eq. (3.54) of Sect. d of the Appendix, making it so that the final Phillips curve yields the results in Eq. (3.17).

3.1.5 (e) Equation 20 Derivations

Considering the initial version of our Phillips curve (Eq. (3.54) of Sect. d of the Appendix) by solving for \( {E}_t{\pi}_{t+1}-{E}_{t-1}{\pi}_t \):

$$ {E}_t{\pi}_{t+1}-{E}_{t-1}{\pi}_t=\frac{1}{\psi}\left({\pi}_t-{\pi}_{t-1}\right)-\frac{\xi }{\psi}\left(\begin{array}{l}\left[\left(\omega +{\sigma}^{-1}\right)\kern0.5em \left({\widehat{Y}}_t-{\widehat{Y}}_t^n\right)+\iota \omega \left({p}_t^G-\iota {p}_t^{NG}\right)\right]-\hfill \\ {}\left[\left(\omega +{\sigma}^{-1}\right)\left({\widehat{Y}}_{t-1}-{\widehat{Y}}_{t-1}^n\right)-\iota \omega \left({p}_{t-1}^G-\iota {p}_{t-1}^{NG}\right)\right]\hfill \end{array}\right) $$
(3.55)

We assume the equation:

$$ \left\lfloor \left(\omega +{\sigma}^{-1}\right)\left({\widehat{Y}}_t-{\widehat{Y}}_t^n\right)+\iota \omega \left({p}_t^G-\iota {p}_t^{NG}\right)\right\rfloor ={\vartheta}_t $$
(3.56)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Asian Development Bank Institute

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Taghizadeh-Hesary, F., Yoshino, N. (2016). Which Side of the Economy Is Affected More by Oil Prices: Supply or Demand?. In: Yoshino, N., Taghizadeh-Hesary, F. (eds) Monetary Policy and the Oil Market. ADB Institute Series on Development Economics. Springer, Tokyo. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-55797-5_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics