Skip to main content

Delineating Metropolitan Areas: Measuring Spatial Labour Market Networks Through Commuting Patterns

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Economics of Interfirm Networks

Part of the book series: Advances in Japanese Business and Economics ((AJBE,volume 4))

Abstract

This chapter first discusses the necessity of defining metropolitan areas and current practice in several countries. It argues for the use of a simple algorithm that exploits cross-municipality commuting patterns. Municipalities are aggregated iteratively provided they send a share of their commuters above a given threshold to the rest of a metropolitan area. This algorithm is implemented on Colombian data and its robustness is assessed. Finally, the properties of the resulting spatial labour market networks are explored.

Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 3620 Locust Walk, Philadelphia, PA 19104, USA (e-mail: duranton@wharton.upenn.edu; website: https://real-estate.wharton.upenn.edu/profile/21470/). Also affiliated with the Centre for Economic Policy Research, the Rimini Centre for Economic Analysis, and the Spatial Economic Centre at the London School of Economics. I am grateful to Rafael Cubillos for giving me data without which this project would have been impossible. James Bernard, Matthew Degagne, and Hongmou Zhang provided very able research assistance. I also thank Paul Cheshire and Yoshi Kanemoto for very useful conversations and for getting me interested in this subject many years ago. Feedback from Alvaro Pachon, Rafael Cubillos, José Salazar and other seminar participants at Departamento Nacional de Planeación (DNP) is also gratefully acknowledged. This research was conducted when the author was working for the urban division of DNP. The collaboration of the entire division, Alejandro Bayonna, and Carolina Barco was greatly appreciated.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The French government defines ‘statistical’ metropolitan areas though its statistical institute (INSEE). At the same time, there are many ‘urban communities’ which are voluntary unions of neighbouring municipalities, i.e{.}, political metropolitan areas. The two differ, sometimes considerably, but coexist to serve extremely different purposes.

  2. 2.

    See for instance the well known ‘Modifiable Areal Unit Problem’ (MAUP). See Cressie (1993) for a presentation and a discussion.

  3. 3.

    For instance, it is obvious that policies that allocate money to ‘places’ need discrete spatial units.

  4. 4.

    This phenomenon is not unique to the coffee region. The same is observed in the region of the Caribbean coast where three of the main cities: Barranquilla, Cartagena and Santa Marta do not merge even for a low commuting threshold of 1 %.

  5. 5.

    This region is technically contiguous with the Valledupar-La Guajira region to its north-east. However, this contiguity is minimal and the Sierra Nevada mountain separates these two regions which are probably best treated as separate. Going from Santa Marta to ‘neighbouring’ Valledupar is a 5 h drive. Should these two regions be treated as one, they would form a region with 5.3 million inhabitants over 50 municipalities.

  6. 6.

    We also start seeing satellite municipalities which are not geographically adjacent to the rest of their metropolitan areas. There are two such cases. The first is the Satanderian municipality of Sucre which get attached to Bucaramanga which is more than 200 km far. Given that this municipality is not negligibly small and sends about 7 % of its commuters to Bucaramanga, this corresponds to real flows, perhaps mostly students which are counted together with workers. The other case is Guacamayas, a tiny municipality at the North of the Boyacá region which gets attached to Bogotá which is nearly 400 km away. Given that this case is driven by only 17 ‘commuters’, this may be a statistical glitch.

  7. 7.

    While in general municipalities that get aggregated to a core for a given threshold are also aggregated to this core or to a larger one for a lower threshold, this need not always be the case. Although exceptional, the municipality of Sutatausa provides an interesting illustration which shows the potential pitfalls of iterative aggregation. This small municipality located to the north of Bogotá sends 6 % of its workforce to San Diego de Ubaté to its north, 5 % to Tausa, 4 % to Nemocón, and 1 % to Bogotá to the south. At a 10 % threshold, Sutatausa gets aggregated to Bogotá after Tausa and Nemocón get aggregated to Bogotá. However, with a 5 % threshold, Sutatausa gets immediately aggregated to San Diego de Ubaté. Since the latter is much larger and barely sends any worker to its south, it remains an independent core with Sutatausa as satellite. This municipality of 5000 inhabitants is the only case of a satellite of Bogotá at a 10 % threshold which disappears with a 5 % threshold.

  8. 8.

    First, because the dependent variable is computed directly from the explanatory variable, measurement error on the ‘true’ population also affects the rank and thus leads to a downward bias for the standard errors with OLS. Gabaix and Ibragimov (2011) show that the standard error on ξ is asymptotically \(\sqrt{2/n}\;\xi\) where n is the number of observations. With our data, this implies a standard error of 0.14. The values of the standard errors for the other estimates of ξ reported here are of the same magnitude.

References

  • Alonso, W. (1964). Location and land use; toward a general theory of land rent. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach, F. (1913). Das Gesetz der Bevölkerungskonzentration. Petermanns Geographische Mitteilungen, 59, 73–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry, B. J. L. (1960). The impact of expanding metropolitan communities upon the central place hierarchy. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 50(2), 112–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry, B., Lobley, J., Goheen, P. G., & Goldstein, H. (1969). Metropolitan area definition: A re-evaluation of concept and statistical practice. Washington, DC: US Bureau of the Census.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bode, E. (2008). Delineating metropolitan areas using land prices. Journal of Regional Science, 48(1), 131–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Briant, A., Combes, P.-P., & Lafourcade, M. (2010). Does the size and shape of geographical units jeopardize economic geography estimations? Journal of Urban Economics, 67(3), 287–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charlot, S., & Duranton, G. (2004). Communication externalities in cities. Journal of Urban Economics, 56(3), 581–613.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheshire, P. C., & Hay, D. (1989). Urban problems in Western Europe: An economic analysis. London: Unwin Hyman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cörvers, F., Hensen, M., & Bongaerts, D. (2009). Delimitation and coherence of functional and administrative regions. Regional Studies, 43(1), 19–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cressie, N. A. C. (1993). Statistics for spatial data. New York: John Wiley.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Duranton, G., & Overman, H. G. (2005). Testing for localization using micro-geographic data. Review of Economic Studies, 72(4), 1077–1106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duranton, G., & Puga, D. (2014). The growth of cities. In P. Aghion & S. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of economic growth (Vol. 2, pp. 781–853). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox, K. A., & Kumar, T. K. (1965). The functional economic area: Delineation and implications for economic analysis and policy. Papers of the Regional Science Association, 15(1), 57–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabaix, X., & Ibragimov, R. (2011). Rank-1/2: A simple way to improve the OLS estimation of tail exponents. Journal of Business Economics and Statistics, 29(1), 24–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E. L., & Kahn, M. (2001). Decentralized employment and the transformation of the American city. Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs, 1–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, P. G., & Hay, D. (1980). Growth centres in the European urban system. London: Heinemann Educational Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Handbury, J. H., & Weinstein, D. E. (2010). Is new economic geography right? Evidence from price data. Processed, Columbia University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmes, T. J. (1999). Localisation of industry and vertical disintegration. Review of Economics and Statistics, 81(2):314–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kanemoto, Y., & Kurima, R. (2005). Urban employment areas: Defining Japanese metropolitan areas and constructing the statistical database for them. In A. Okabe (Ed.), GIS-based studies in the humanities and social sciences (pp. 85–97). Boca Raton: Taylor & Francis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. R. (1991). Geography and trade. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1890). Principles of economics. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mills, E. S. (1967). An aggregative model of resource allocation in a metropolitan area. American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings), 57(2), 197–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Molina, H. (2001). Análisis del Sistema Nacional de Ciudades. Aportes para una nueva regionalización del territorio colombiano. New York: UNDP and Ministerio de Desarrollo Económico.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muth, R. F. (1969). Cities and housing. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pérez, G. J. (2008). Población y Ley de Zipf en Colombia y la Costa Caribe, 1912–1993. Documentos de trabajo sobre econom ía regional 71, Banco de la República.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, K., & Resnick, M. (1980). The size distribution of cities: An examination of the pareto law and primacy. Journal of Urban Economics, 8(2):165–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rozenfeld, H. D., Rybski, D., Gabaix, X., & Makse, H. A. (2011). The area and population of cities: New insights from a different perspective on cities. American Economic Review, 101(5):2205–2225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Senado de la República. (2012). Informe de ponencia para secondo debate al proyecto de Ley número 141 de 2011. Gaceta del Congreso, 137 (21), 1-16.

    Google Scholar 

  • US Office of Management and Budget. (2010). 2010 standards for delineating metropolitan and micropolitan statistical areas; notice. Washington, DC: Federal Register.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zipf, G. K. (1949). Human behavior and the principle of least effort: An introduction to human ecology. Cambridge: Addison Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gilles Duranton .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer Japan

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Duranton, G. (2015). Delineating Metropolitan Areas: Measuring Spatial Labour Market Networks Through Commuting Patterns. In: Watanabe, T., Uesugi, I., Ono, A. (eds) The Economics of Interfirm Networks. Advances in Japanese Business and Economics, vol 4. Springer, Tokyo. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-55390-8_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics