Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Advances in Japanese Business and Economics ((AJBE,volume 8))

Abstract

Consider a principal who sets a budget that the agent allocates among different services. Because the preferences of the agent may differ from those of the principal, the budget the principal sets can be lower or higher than in the first-best solution. When the principal is uncertain about the agent’s preferences, the agent may choose an allocation that signals his type, thereby affecting the size of the budget the principal will set in the following period. The equilibrium may have separation or pooling. In a pooling equilibrium, the agent may mis-represent his preferences, aiming to get a large budget in the future period.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    For a selective review of research on the existence and the effects of prosocial behavior among individuals working in public organizations, see Polidori and Teobaldelli (2013).

  2. 2.

    It follows from the discussion in Sect. 4.2.1 that m A  = 0 should hold in equilibrium.

  3. 3.

    We used the data until 2000 because the definition of some categories changed after that fiscal year. We excluded two categories because: one was subject to changes of definition during the period from 1985 to 1999, and the other is miscellaneous.

  4. 4.

    We thank Nobuo Akai and Takero Doi for this example.

  5. 5.

    The budgets for FY2009 were large, to address the effects of the Lehman shock.

  6. 6.

    The new administration abolished fiscal caps in drawing up the FY2010 budget. It motivated each spending ministry to require increased budgets. Accordingly, fiscal caps were restored next year.

  7. 7.

    Spending for post-disaster recovery projects is excluded.

Abbreviations

p i :

Marginal cost of service i

v(⋅ ):

Utility from consumption of a service

\( \overline{X} \) :

Budget set by the principal

x i :

Quantity of service i provided

\( {x}_{ti}^k \) :

Choice of service i in period t by a type-k agent in the absence of signaling considerations

\( {x}_{ti}^{k\ast } \) :

Optimal choice of service i in period t by an agent of type k when signaling considerations are present

\( {x}_i^P \) :

first-best allocation for the principal of service i

\( {\overline{X}}^{\ast } \) :

first-best level of the budget which the principal would give the agent when their preferences are the same

\( \overline{Y} \) :

Principal’s endowment in each period

α A :

Parameter describing preferences of the agent

α P :

Parameter describing preferences of the principal

π L :

Prior probability that \( {\alpha}_A={\alpha}_L \)

\( {{ ilde }{\pi}}_L \) :

Posterior probability that agent is of type-L, or has \( {\alpha}_A={\alpha}_L \)

\(\tilde{q}_{L}\) :

Posterior probability that \( {p}_2={p}_L \)

References

  • Akai N (2014) Fiscal consolidation and local public finance in Japan: Incentive problems behind Inter-governmental transfers and its political roles. In: Ihori T, Terai K (eds) The political economy of fiscal consolidation in Japan. Springer, Tokyo

    Google Scholar 

  • Aron DJ (1987) Worker reputation and productivity incentives. J Lab Econ 5:87–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1974) A theory of social interactions. J Polit Econ 82:1063–1094

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beniers KJ, Dur R (2007) Politicians’ motivation, political culture, and electoral competition. Int Tax Publ Finance 14:29–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besfamille M, Lockwood B (2008) Bailouts in federations: is a hard budget constraint always best? Int Econ Rev 49:577–593

    Google Scholar 

  • Biglaiser G, Mezzetti C (1997) Politicians’ decision making with re-election concerns. J Publ Econ 66:425–447

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan J (1977) The Samaritan’s dilemma. In: Phelps ES (ed) Altruism, morality and economic theory. Russell Sage Foundation, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Canes-Wrone B, Herron MC, Shotts KW (2001) Leadership and pandering: a theory of executive policymaking. Am J Polit Sci 45:532–550

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter DP (2004) The political economy of FDA drug review: Processing, politics, and lessons for policy. Health Aff 23:52–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crewson PE (1997) Public service motivation: Building empirical evidence of incidence and effect. J Public Admin Res Theory 7:499–518

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fox J (2007) Government transparency and policymaking. Publ Choice 131:23–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Georgellis Y, Iossa E, Tabvuma V (2011) Crowding out intrinsic motivation in the public sector. J Publ Admin Res Theory 21:473–493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons R (1987) Piece-rate incentive schedules. J Lab Econ 5:413–429

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gregg P, Grout PA, Ratcliffe A et al (2011) How important is pro-social behaviour in the delivery of public services? J Publ Econ 95:758–766

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guyot JF (1962) Government bureaucrats are different. Publ Admin Rev 22:195–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hess GD, Orphanides A (1995) War politics—An economic, rational-voter framework. Am Econ Rev 85:828–846

    Google Scholar 

  • Ihori T (2014) Fiscal consolidation in a political economy of Japan. In: Ihori T, Terai K (eds) The political economy of fiscal consolidation in Japan. Springer, Tokyo

    Google Scholar 

  • Kanemoto Y, MacLeod WB (1992) The ratchet effect and the market for secondhand workers. J Lab Econ 10:85–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kessler AS (2010) Communication in federal politics: Universalism, policy uniformity, and the optimal allocation of fiscal authority. CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP7910

    Google Scholar 

  • Lazear E (1986) Salaries and piece rates. J Bus 59:405–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Majumdar S, Mukand SW (2004) Policy gambles. Am Econ Rev 94:1207–1222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maskin E, Tirole J (2004) The politician and the judge: Accountability in government. Am Econ Rev 94:1034–1054

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morris S (2001) Political correctness. J Polit Econ 109:231–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polidori P, Teobaldelli D (2013) Prosocial behavior in the production of publicly provided goods and services: An overview. Int Rev Appl Econ 27:285–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prat A (2005) The wrong kind of transparency. Am Econ Rev 95:862–877

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sato M (2002) Intergovernmental transfers, governance structure and fiscal decentralization. Jpn Econ Rev 53:55–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smart M, Sturm DM (2013) Term limits and electoral accountability. J Publ Econ 107:93–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanaka H (2011) Zaisei kiritsu to yosan seido kaikaku (Fiscal discipline and budget process reform). Nippon Hyoron Sha, Tokyo

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors thank Nobuo Akai, Takero Doi, Keisuke Hattori, Toshihiro Ihori, Shintaro Nakagawa, Shuhei Shiozawa, Shinichi Suda, and the seminar participants at Keio University and at the University of California, Irvine, for helpful comments and suggestions. In particular, comments by Keisuke Hattori on our Figs. 7.1, 7.2, 7.3 were most helpful in revising our graphical presentation. Financial support by the Seimeikai Foundation and a Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research from the Ministry of Education, Culture, Sports, Science and Technology are gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kimiko Terai .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Comment Paper to Chapter 7

Comment Paper to Chapter 7

Keisuke Hattori

Osaka University of Economics, 2-2-8, Osumi, Higashiyodogawa, Osaka, Japanemail: hattori@osaka-ue.ac.jp

This chapter constructs a principal–agent model of delegation, in which a principal sets a budget that an agent then allocates between two different public services (“good” or “bad” services from the principal’s point of view). It investigates (i) how differences in preferences between the principal and agent affect the size of the budget that the principal sets, and (ii) how the agent behaves to obtain a larger budget when the principal is uncertain about the agent’s preferences.

The following results are obtained using plausible assumptions regarding preferences: (i) the more divergent the preferences of the principal and agent, the larger the budget that the principal tends to give the agent, and (ii) the agent has strategic incentives to obtain a large budget. Regarding this latter, it is further determined that in a separating equilibrium, an agent who prefers bad services spends much more on bad services in a manner that an agent preferring good services would not want to mimic. In a pooling equilibrium, however, even an agent who prefers good services mimics the bad agent and inefficiently spends on bad services.

The basic signaling model is extended by incorporating asymmetric information regarding the cost to provide each service. It is shown that, in a pooling equilibrium, an agent who has low (high) marginal costs of good (bad) services will behave as if he/she has high (low) marginal cost of good (bad) services to elicit a larger budget from the principal.

The authors stress the importance of asymmetric information regarding agent’s cost for providing public services for explaining increased government expenditure in Japan, but I believe that it is equally possible that the asymmetric information regarding agent preferences has the same importance as that of agent’s cost. For example, a national government prefers welfare services to road maintenance services but a local government prefers the opposite, which may cause an inefficient allocation of government expenditure. Furthermore, differences in preferences for some public services between national and local governments may be due to positive or negative externalities of local public services (e.g., libraries, sewer systems, parks, and city streets). On this point, the authors can also connect their ideas to the “decentralization theorem” by Wallace Oates. In addition, I would like to know how the national subsidy to local governments for providing good services affects inefficiency in delegation.

I found the analysis very interesting and thought provoking even in the perfect information setting. In addition, I believe that the model can be applied to budget allocation problems within firms, organizations, and families, all of which await future research.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer Japan

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Terai, K., Glazer, A. (2015). Budgets Under Delegation. In: Ihori, T., Terai, K. (eds) The Political Economy of Fiscal Consolidation in Japan. Advances in Japanese Business and Economics, vol 8. Springer, Tokyo. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-55127-0_7

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics